- FX- --Africa Region Working Paper Series Number 36 i J'tterri of Governance in- Africa 13rian- Levy SeptemL2er 2002 The World Bank 4, PATTERNS OF GOVERNANCE IN AFRICA Africa Region Working Paper Series No. 36 September 2002 Abstract This paper outlines a systematic managerial and organizational reforms is framework for considering govemaance appropriate in countries where the comparatively across counltr-ies. The institutions of political governance resulting typology distinguishes among already are quite strong. But where different country starting points adequate political institutions are not yet according to the quality of political and 'locked-in', reforms should focus more administrative governance. The on demand-side, participative initiatives typology is applied across 22 African which foster civic participation countries (usino data from 1996). The (including user participation and paper explores how to fit the design of oversight in service delivery, and system programs of action to strengthen public re-orientation to empower and build the sector performance to divergeent country capacity of local governments). starting points. It concludes that a focus on Author Brian D. Levy Sector Manager Public Sector Reform & Capacity (AFITPR) E-mail: BlevyWworldbank.org The Africa Region Workinlg Papdr Series expedites dissemination of applied researchi and policy stuidies withi potential for improving economic performanlce anid social coniditionzs in Suib-Salarani Afirica. The Series publishes papers at preliminary stages to stimuitilate timiiely discuissioni wLithin thie Region anid anmong clienit couniitries, dontors, and the policy researclh communiiiiiiity. Tlhc editorial boardfor the Series conzsists of representatives firom professional families appoinited by the Regioni's Sector Directors. For additioinal information, please contact Paulla Wh ite, managing editor of the series, (81131), Emlail: pzt?hite2@vorldbank.org or visit the Web site: littp:/hAtonzt.zo-ldbank.org/afrAe'v7s/inzdex.lihtl. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author(s), they do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank Group, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent and should not be attributed to them. PATTERNS OF GOVERNANCE' IN AFRICA Brian Levy September 2002 The term 'governance' tends to be very loosely used, with no consistent definition. A definition consistent with this paper is "the manner in which power is exercised in the management of a country's economic and social resources" (World Bank, Governance and Development, 1992). More broadly, for the purposes of the present paper governance should be interpreted as encompassing both the 'rules of the game' (i.e. institutions), and the players of the game (i.e. bureaucrats and politicians). Indeed, the distinction between the institutional and organizational dimensions of governance is a central theme of the paper. LAcknowledgements am grateful to Paula Donovan, Alan Gelb, Phil Keefer, Brian Ngo and my colleagues in AR's eoPublic Sector Reform and Capacity Building Group (AFIPR) for comyents on earlier versions oof this paper. Remaining er-rors and misinterpretations are, of course, my own. PATTERNS OF GOVERNANCE IN AFRICA Table of Contents 1. Introduction ......................................................1 2. The Governance of African States: Some Empirical Patterns ..........................................2 Assessing the Extent of Formal Rule-Bound Governance ...................................................... 2 Assessing the 'Credibility' of Political Authority ...................... ................................4 Assessing the Quality of Bureaucracy ...........6..........................................6 3. Meeting the Challenge of Governance and Bureaucratic Reform ....................................9 Strengthening governance ..................................................... 10 Improving the Quality of Bureaucracy ..................................................... 13 Institutional options when governance is "weak" ..................................................... 16 Annex 1: Dimensionalizing Governance - Some Antecedents .................................................... 18 Annex 2: Characteristics of the WDR Africa Sample ..................................................... 21 Annex 3: The Robustness of the Governance Indicators ..................................................... 22 Bibliography ..................................................... 26 1. Introduction In recent years, researchers and practitioners have made major strides in understanding some of the key institutional attributes of effective states. While a wide variety of institutional arrangements are workable, well-functioning public institutions are generally thought to have certain important characteristics in common. Decision-making processes and the resulting decisions are in general transparent and predictable. Oversight mechanisms (i.e. checks and balances) guard against arbitrariness and ensure accountability in the use of public resources, but do not eliminate the flexibility and delegation that is needed to respond quickly to changing circumstances. Public officials are committed to the achievement of social goals, and the efficient delivery of public services, and manage the interface between the public and private realms in a streamlined, transactionally efficient way. The political process is broadly viewed as legitimate, and provides an anchor of predictability for business decision-making. Property rights are protected. Underlying much of this work has been the implicit presumption that careful specification of what works will be sufficient to conjure well-developed institutions into being. Yet reality does not play out on some tabula rasa upon which we are free to enact grand designs. On the contrary, reform must contend with pre-existing institutional arrangements, and entrenched, powerful interests in government and civil society. The successful reformer must thus pay close attention to the "initial conditions" of the to-be-reformned environment. Attention to initial conditions complicates the challenge of reform, by requiring the reformer to wrestle with country-specific realities rather than directly transplanting lessons of reform from one country into some different setting. Yet it does not follow that cross-country comparisons are irrelevant. What is needed is a coherent framework for distinguishing among countries, a typology - one that goes beyond simplistic bifurcations between, say, "markets" versus "controls" or "dictatorship" versus "democracy". As Annex 1 summarizes, a very rich literature, across multiple intellectual disciplines, has endeavored to develop more conceptually meaningful distinctions. In line with that literature, this paper aims: first, to lay out a typology for distinguishing among states, anchoring that typology in variables which can be proxied empirically; second, to apply that typology empirically to 22 African countries (as of 1996); and, third, to probe some characteristic patterns of change from different starting points within the typology, and hence some implications for action in individual countries. Put differently, the aim of the paper is, principally, to provide a systematic framework for considering governance comparatively and, secondarily, to examine the relevance of the framework by applying it in a historical and heuristic empirical fashion across African countries. The aim is not to undertake a country-specific benchmarking of governance quality.2 2 An advanced draft of this paper was completed by mid-1999. However, given his professional responsibilities, the author judged that it was prudent to postpone publication for long enough to ensure that the country-specific data would be widely recognized as being of historical and heuristic value - and not be misinterpreted as offering operational indicators of the currently prevailing governance conditions in the 22 included countries. 1 2. The Governance of African States: Some Empirical Patterns The typology developed here is organized around three distinct characteristics of states. The first two comprise key political dimensions of governance: * The extent offormal rule-bound governance; and * The 'credibility' of political authority. The third characteristic focuses on the administrative dimension, namely: * The quality of bureaucracy. The next three subsections of the paper define, in turn, each of these three characteristics, and proxy them empirically for 22 African countries (as of 1996). The data are drawn from a survey conducted for the 1997 World Development Report (WDR), The State in a Changing World. The WDR survey explored the perceptions of over 3,600 entrepreneurs as to the character and quality of the public institutions which underpin market transactions in each of 69 countries -- including 22 in Africa. Annex Table 2 details the characteristics of the WDR African sample. Firms scored their perceptions as to the severity of various institution-related obstacles to doing business on a 1 to 6 scale, with a score of 1 signaling that the relevant constraint was no obstacle, and 6 signaling that it was a very severe obstacle. The survey as a whole comprised 25 questions, many of which had multiple parts. Averaging the responses for all firms within individual countries yields an average country score for each question. Though the results are not strictly comparable across countries,3 they nonetheless provide an initial indicator of different patterns of strength and weakness. Kaufmann, Kraay and Zoido-Lobatan (KKL 1999) assess the robustness of a variety of distinct indicators of governance, including the survey used here. Annex 3 details their results - and highlights some of the potential biases of the WDR data set. (For readers interested in updating the data, Annex 3 also includes some more recent indicators provided in KKL (2001). Assessing the Extent of Formal Rule-Bound Governance Formal rule bound governance (FRBG) is defined here to comprise the explicit transparent rules, processes, and organizations - the formal institutions -- which are intended to govern the relationship between a state and its citizens in ways which restrain arbitrary authority. These institutions include: judiciaries; constitutions and other check and balance mechanisms; plus regulators and other executive agencies responsible for monitoring and enforcement of 3 The data report the perceptions of entrepreneurs, rather than "objective" indicators. Entrepreneurs need not have comparative knowledge of their country relative to others, and may differ in their propensity to claim about their government, so in theory these perceptions need not be correlated with the underlying realities. In practice, as Brunetti, Kisunko and Weder (1997) have shown the results of the WDR perception survey are indeed correlated with investment and performance, although some outliers (for example, the substantially greater dissatisfaction of Zimbabwean entrepreneurs with the quality of public services as compared with, say, their Zambian counterparts) point to the potential limitations of these perceptual measures. 2 compliance with formal rules. As discussed later in this paper,4 underlying effective FRBG is a political structure in which citizens participate in governance, in the sense that there exist institutional mechanisms which empower them to monitor and enforce restraints on arbitrary action by political and bureaucratic leaders. Two variables from the WDR survey provide an empirical basis for grouping the 22 African countries according to the extent of FRBG. The first variable measures perceptions of respondents as to the quality of African judicial institutions. Judicial institutions are useful proxies for the quality of FRBG both directly and indirectly - directly in that they play a key role in the enforcement of rules, and indirectly in that judicial institutions can function well only in settings in which executive authority is sufficiently constrained so that judicial independence is respected. The survey posed the following question to firms: "Unpredictability of the judiciary presents a major problem for my business operations. To what degree do you agree with this statement?" (1=disagree; 6=agree) The second measure of FRBG comprises the perceptions of respondents as to the pervasiveness of corruption as a business practice. Why can corruption be viewed as a proxy for the quality of FRBG? Ideally, politicians and bureaucrats at all levels work to pursue social ends -- defined by the political choices of citizens, as translated into action by politicians and successive layers within a bureaucratic hierarchy. In practice, politicians and bureaucrats (like all people) also have personal interests and aspirations. In the absence of appropriate institutional arrangements (both between citizens and politicians, and between politicians and bureaucrats) for resolving these principal-agent problems5, some will choose to act opportunistically - including engaging in corruption, defined as abusing public office in pursuit of private ends. To proxy corruption, the survey probed:6 * "It is common for fims in my line of business to have to pay some irregular 'additional payments' to get things done." [1= never pay; 2=seldom; 3=sometimes; 4=frequently; 5= mostly; 6= always pay] Table 1 reports the 1996 scores and rankings for the 22 African countries for each of the judicial quality and corruption variables. The distribution of the judicial quality scores was similar among the African countries to the 69 country global sample (for which the median score was 4.34); but corruption was perceived to be more severe in Africa than for the sample as a whole: 15 of the 22 African countries scored worse than the global median score of 3.4. The rank correlation for the judicial and corruption measures was 0.65 - providing grounds both for the proposition that both are measures of FRBG, and for the ordering of the countries in Table 1 according to an overall ranking of FRBG (an average of the rankings for each of the two variables). 4 See the discussion of 'strengthening political governance' in Section 3, and also Annex 1. 5 See Sappington (1991) for an overview of these problems. 6 Note that this question focuses on "petty" corruption, the day-to-day bribes that in some countries can be a part of getting anything done. "Grand" corruption - the extraction of very large payoffs from (inevitably less frequent) large initiatives by political leaders - is a different type of problem which the survey does not address. This distinction may be part of the reason for some of the seeming disconnects (e.g. for Nigeria during the Abacha era) between the WDR survey results on the one hand, and common perception (plus the estimates of Kaufmann et. al.) on the other. 3 Table 1: Estimates of FRBG for 22 African countries Corruption Judicial Quality Overall Score Rank Score Rank JIRank Zimbabwe 2.4 2 3.67 3 2.5 Mauritius 2.85 5 3 1 3 Malawi 2.67 3 4.17 7 5 Zambia 2.84 4 4.09 6 5 South Africa 1.93 1 4.43 11 6 Ghana 3.65 10 3.55 2 6 Nigeria 3.20 7 4 5 6 Guinea Bissau 3.07 6 4.25 8 7 Kenya 3.63 9 4.26 9 9 Uganda 3.73 14 3.84 4 9 Togo 3.46 8 4.47 12 10 Mali 3.67 11 4.61 14 12.5 Mozambique 3.68 1 13 4.64 15 14 Tanzania 4.22 18 4.49 13 15.5 Cameroon 4.35 21 4.29 10 15.5 Senegal 3.67 12 5.28 21 16.5 Benin 4.17 17 4.86 16 16.5 Chad 4 15 5.08 19 17 Cote d'Ivoire 4.13 16 5.07 18 17 Madagascar 4.24 19 5.18 20 19.5 Congo 4.36 22 5 I 17 19.5 Guinea 4.35 20 5.56 [ 22 21 Source: WDR 1997 Assessing the 'Credibility' of Political Authority The notion of FRBG has become so much a part of the modem conception of the state, that we tend to ignore that it rests on a prior foundation of political authority; for much of history in much of the world the challenge has been building that prior foundation. This central dimension of govemance is defined here as the 'credibility' of political authority -- the predictability and consistency of the actions of the sovereign authority, and the 'reach' of its power.7 This notion of credibility is evident in the classic definition of states as well-defined territories in which the sovereign authority enjoys a monopoly of coercive authority (in the sense that it is-capable of imposing its will on the people in the relevant territory). Annex 1 examines the intellectual pedigree of this second dimension of political governance. The differences are stark between countries where both FRBG and the credibility of political authority are strong, and those where both are weak. Where both are strong, formal institutions provide a powerful foundation for transparency and accountability, restraining arbitrary authority, and thereby protecting the rights of citizens, and ensuring the credibility of private-to-private contracts. But where both are weak, formal (and informal) institutions are 7. Bomner, Brunetti and Weber (1995) provide an extended discussion of credibility, highlighting its importance for economic development (chapter 2), distinguishing it from other dimensions of governance (chapter 3), and exploring its political foundations. 4 thoroughly dysfunctional. Citizens and firms live in a world rife with both arbitrariness and corruption. Public services are not delivered. Side payments to obstructive officials and politicians are necessary to get anything done, even in the private realm. Yet corruption itself proves insufficient to secure credibility: sometimes recipients of bribes lack the influence to follow through on their promises; sometimes they reverse themselves capriciously; sometimes, before they can follow through, they lose hold entirely of their fragile grip on power. Note that FRBG and the credibility of political authority are analytically (and hence potentially empirically) quite independent of one another. Polities in which FRBG is weak, and consequently which are rife with agency problems and opportunism may nonetheless provide a moderately credible foundation for development, insofar as the informal "rules of the game" remain reasonably predictable (if perhaps inefficient). Key here is the time horizon of politicians. Political leaders with a long-time horizon have an incentive to support economic growth, private investment and hence a stable policy environment, if sometimes in nontransparent and somewhat corrupt ways.8 But if politicians' time horizon is short, their interests might best be served by acting in ways that are destabilizing in the longer term. Firms could be subjected to arbitrary pressures -- and in consequence are likely to refrain from investing. Three questions in the 1996 WDR survey probed a country's credibility: * "Do you regularly have to cope with unexpected changes in rules, laws or policies which materially affect your business"? [1= completely predictable... 6= completely unpredictable] * "Do you expect the government to stick to announced major policies?" [l=always; 6=never] * "How problematic is policy instability as an obstacle to business activity?" [1= no obstacle; etc....] Averaging the answers to these three questions yields a single score for each country of the credibility of state action. Table 2 summarizes the results, and associated country rankings. The distribution of credibility scores was similar for the African countries and for the overall sample (global median = 3.63). The rank correlations between credibility on the one hand, and judicial quality and corruption on the other are 0.16 and 0.02 respectively, supporting the hypothesis that FRBG and credibility are analytically independent of one another. 8 Olson (1991) develops the model of the long-lived, unconstrained leader as a 'stationary bandit' - predatory, but with national wealth creation increasing the present value of the leader's private returns. 5 Table 2: Policy credibility in 22 African countries -Credibiiity `Credibility Score Rank - Score Rank Cote dlvoire 2.65 1 Togo 3.63 12 Mali 2.97 2 Kenya 3.67 13 Senegal 2.97 3 Mozambique 3.67 14 Mauritius 3.06 4 Cameroon 3.77 15 Guinea 3.08 5 Zambia 3.77 16 Ghana 3.12 6 Congo 3.83 17 Malawi 3.19 7 Guinea Bissau 3.83 18 Benin 3.25 8 Zimbabwe 3.88 19 Uganda 3.34 9 Madagascar 4.14 20 South Africa 3.05 10 Nigeria 4.16 j 21 Chad 3.58 11 Tanzania 4.34 22 Assessing the Quality of Bureaucracy Bureaucracy - the administrative arm of government - comprises the means whereby public decisions are translated into action. Bureaucratic quality comprises the extent to which a bureaucracy delivers high quality services, carries out its regulatory and other control functions (e.g. taxation) at low transactions costs. Bureaucracies do not function in a political vacuum: while at times, they may break loose of political control and pursue independent agendas; the politician-bureaucracy relationship is best interpreted as one of bureaucratic "agents" and political "principals.9 Nonetheless, there is no necessary one-to-one relation between bureaucratic quality and the quality of political governance: * Political authority can be entirely unconstrained, but can invest in a well-functioning bureaucracy as a way of extending its will - either to pursue ideological ends, or for more self-interested goals of political leaders. * Political authority can be effectively constrained, through formal rules, but unable to effect its will in the face of bureaucratic weakness. The internal rule-based, hierarchical system of "Weberian" bureaucratic order may break down (or never adequately have been put into place). Separate bureaucratic fiefdoms may each begin to impose their own sets of rules, with little attention to their overall consistency. Citizens and firms may find themselves trapped in a Kafkaesque morass of non- transparent rules, with little way of knowing which are likely to be enforced at a given point in time. * 'Warlord' politicians might have absolute authority within the domain subject to their direct coercive control, but lack the administrative apparatus needed for them to effect their will for tasks that require more than direct coercion. 9 A seminal article is McCubbins, Noll and Weingast (1987). 6 The WDR survey included questions which explored both the extent of 'red tape' related bureaucratic overload, and the quality of services. The two questions which measured the extent to which bureaucratic overload ('red tape') is a constraint on business activity were: * What percentage of senior management's time is spent on negotiation with officials about changes and interpretations of laws and regulations? [Less than 5% (score = 1); 5-15% (2); 15-25% (3); 25-50% (4); 50-75% (5); more than 75% (score = 6)l * How problematic are entry regulations, price controls, regulations on foreign trade, labor regulations, foreign currency regulations, and safety or environmental regulations as obstacles for doing business? [Firms gave a separate score for each regulation on the 1-6 scale; averaging these scores yields an overall score of the extent to which individual firms perceived regulatory constraints as a problem]. These two metrics of bureaucratic 'red tape' are not strictly commensurate. Consequently, to obtain a single metric, countries were ordered according to their rank correlation in each subscore and the rank correlations were then averaged. The individual scores for each measure, and the resulting composite ranking are reported in Table 3. Table 3: Bureaucratic quality 1: the extent of 'red tape' Bureaucracy: time -Bureaucracy: barriers. --Overll - Score Rank Score Raiik ik-.. Malawi 1.79 3 2.9 3 3 Zimbabwe 1.72 2 3.01 4 3 Zambia 2.26 8 2.6 1 4.5 Mauritius 1.68 1 3.22 9 5 Uganda 2.5 10 2.84 2 6 Ghana 2.26 7 3.05 6 6.5 Cameroon 1.95 5 3.37 13 9 Kenya 2.61 14 3.07 7 10.5 Togo 2.09 6 3.43 15 10.5 Guinea Bissau 2.27 9 3.37 14 11.5 South Africa 1.94 4 3.81 21 12.5 Chad 3 21 3.04 5 13 Mali 2.82 18 3.1 8 13 Benin 2.79 17 3.31 11 14 Senegal 2.51 11 3.48 17 14 Nigeria 2.55 12 3.64 19 15.5 Tanzania 3.13 22 3.27 10 16 Guinea 2.93 20 3.32 12 16 Cote dlvoire 2.68 16 3.43 16 16 Madagascar 2.66 15 3.56 18 16.5 Mozambique 2.56 13 3.71 20 16.5 Congo 2.88 19 3.85 22 20.5 Two questions focused directly on the quality of services. The survey posed the following to firms: * Inadequate supply of infrastructure represents a major obstacle to my business. To what degree do you agree with this statement? (1=disagree; 6=agree) 7 * How would you generally rate the efficiency of government in delivery services? (1=very efficient; 6=very inefficient) Averaging the answers to these two questions (the correlation coefficient of the two scores was 0.65) yields the indicator of service quality reported for the 22 countries in Table 4. Table 4: Bureaucratic quality 2: service delivery -Service quality . Sernice quality -Score Rank -Score.. Rank Cote d'Ivoire 3.51 1 1 Zambia 4.25 T 12 Ghana 3.53 1 2 Guinea 4.26 t 13 Guinea Bissau 3.53 1 3 Nigeria 4.37 7 14 Mali 3.68 4 Mozambique 4.45 ! 15 South Africa 3.71 ! 5 Zimbabwe 4.63 ! 16 Mauritius 3.75 1 6 Madagascar 4.65 T 17 Togo 3.92 7 Malawi 4.79 t 18 Uganda 3.94 l 8 Cameroon 4.82 1 19 Senegal 3.95 j 9 Kenya 4.91 20 Benin 3.97 10 Congo 4.99 21 Chad 4.21 1 1 Tanzania 5.02 22 Table 5 details the rank correlations between the 'red tape' and service quality measures, and between these measures and the measures in Tables 1 and 2 of FRBG and credibility. Three striking patterns are evident: Table 5: Bureaucratic quality and governance: some rank correlations Judicial Corruption, Policy Regulatory :___-___-___:_ quality -_: credibility -quality Service quality 0.12 0.32 0.61 0.21 Regulatory quality 0.72 0.60 0.23 x * the correlation among these two dimensions of bureaucratic quality is low; * the bureaucratic red tape measure has a high correlation with FRBG, but a low correlation with credibility; and * the service quality measure is strongly correlated with credibility, but more weakly correlated with the two measures of FRBG. The next section of the paper endeavors to make sense of these patterns - and their implications as to what might be workable paths of reform in different country settings. 8 3. Meeting the Challenge of Governance and Bureaucratic Reform The typology in Table 6 details the joint distribution of countries as of 1996 among the variables described above. The columns group countries according to whether governance was good (i.e. both strong credibility and strong FRBG), weak (in both dimensions), or mixed (i.e. strong in one governance dimension, but weak in the other). The rows group countries according to whether bureaucratic quality was good, weak or "mixed" (i.e. strong in one bureaucratic dimension but weak in the other). The median is used as the 'cut-off point: for each category, the highest ranking 11 countries are defined as "strong", while the lowest ranking 11 are defined as "weak"'0. Table 6: Governance in sub-Saharan Africa - a Typology 1' WEAK MDiED GOVERNANCE ; GOOD GOVERNANCE Informal, FRBG but GoVERNANCE. but Credible low credibility - WEAK Congo Guinea Nigeria BUREAUCRACY Madagascar Chad Mozambique Tanzania MIXED Cameroon [Zambia Malawi BUREAUCRACY: Zimbabwe weak service; OK Kenya en 'red tape' eaStrong service; Benin South Africa --excess 'red tape' Cote d'Ivoire Senegal GOOD Mali Togo Ghana BUREAUCRACY Guinea Bissau Uganda I__ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __ _M auritius 1/ As footnote 9 details, comparison with KKZL suggests the italicized countries might reasonably be positioned in different governance columns. This section explores how reformers - people committed to changes in the rules of the game in a direction supportive of sustainable development - might proceed in diverse country settings. Reformers may be top political leaders, or ordinary citizens. They may be high-level technocrats, or they may work in lower tiers of the bureaucracy. They may be nationals, or outsiders. Whatever their positions, they must contend with the institutional starting points as 10 The allocation of countries in Table 6 is based on the WDR data set, which as discussed in Annex 3 is subject to a variety of potential biases. As Annex 3 details, using the Kaufmann, Kraak and Zoido-Lobaton (1999) data set Cote d'Ivoire and Senegal would unambiguously be 'promoted' in Table 6 into the 'good governance' column and Madagascar and Tanzania into the 'mixed governance' columns (the former 'informal but credible', the latter 'FRBG but low credibility'). By contrast, Nigeria, Kenya and Chad each would migrate from 'mixed' to 'weak governance'. Any other changes would be 'borderline calls'. Note also that for seven countries - Benin, Ghana, Mali, Mauritius, Mozambique, Togo and Uganda - the KKZL and WDR rankings are virtually identical 9 they find them - and the trajectories of change that are most likely to be associated with these starting points. Based on assessments of these realities, they must then choose from a variety of distinctive approaches to reform. What specific trajectories of change are most likely for the diverse starting points identified in Table 6? And, given the plausible trajectories for each starting point, what reform initiatives are most likely to yield sustainable gains in institutional capability? Specifically, how should the emphasis between governance reforms and reforms to improve bureaucratic performance vary across different country settings? Exploring these questions for each of the sixteen cells - and thus potential starting points - identified in Table 6 is an intractable exercise. Simplifying somewhat (without, as it turns out, losing much by way of analytical richness) the discussion which follows focuses on four groups of countries, corresponding to the four columns in the table: * Group A: the 'good governance' countries (comprising, in the 1996 WDR data, Ghana, Malawi, Mauritius, South Africa and Uganda); * Group B(frbg): the 'mixed governance -strong frbg, but low credibility - subset' (comprising, in the 1996 WDR data, Guinea Bissau, Kenya, Nigeria, Togo, Zambia and Zimbabwe) * Group B(infc): the 'mixed governance - informal, but credible - subset' (comprising, in the 1996 WDR data, Benin, Chad, Cote d'Ivoire, Guinea, Mali and Senegal); and * Group C: the 'weak governance' countries (comprising, in the 1996 WDR data, Cameroon, Congo-Brazzaville, Madagascar, Mozambique and Tanzania) The next sections explore three sets of reforn challenges -- strengthening governance; improving bureaucratic quality; and achieving 'traction' in settings where governance is especially weak. As will become evident, the preferred approaches to reform vary systematically with each of the four groups highlighted above. Strengthening governance The presumption in this section is that the preferred institutional pattern is strong credibility and strong FRBG. And a central conclusion of the section is that, for Group B countries which have not yet 'locked-in' this preferred institutional pattern,1' the key to sustainable improvements in governance comprises a focus on demand-side, participative reforms which foster civic participation. As noted, using the WDR survey, five of the 22 countries - Ghana, Malawi, Mauritius, South Africa and Uganda -- fit in Group A, in the sense that they were perceived to enjoy both strong credibility and strong FRBG. All five are Anglophone, consistent with the emphasis which the British placed on building a foundation of law (even if one that was applied unevenly12) during the period of colonial rule -- and pointing to the powerful influence of history in shaping institutions. To be sure, even these five countries did not emerge in the survey as " Preferred approaches appear different for Group C countries, and are discussed in the final subsection of the paper. 2 See Mamdani (1995). 10 unequivocal paragons of good governance: Ghana and Uganda, for example, both scored worse for corruption than the global median. Nonetheless, in contrast with the other countries surveyed, their institutional task seems to be more one of consolidation - for which a variety of supply-side technocratic reform initiatives can be helpful13 - than the more fundamental challenge of building a stable governance foundation for economic development. Turning to the Group B countries (both subsets), their governance systems are of a kind generally described by African scholars as 'neopatrimonial' 4. In neopatrimonial settings, though the outward features of institutionalized administrative states are in place, political power is exercised through informal channels, built around relationships of patronage, not through governance systems which are both formal and credible. Within the overall neopatrimonial pattern, there are interesting differences between the two Group B subsets, reflecting perhaps the different post-independence trajectories to neopatrimonialism of Anglophone and Francophone countries. Four of the six Group B(frbg) were Anglophone. By contrast, all of the Group B(infc) countries were Francophone. At independence Anglophone countries inherited strong FRBG institutions - which initially appeared also to enjoy substantial credibility. The post- independence weakening of these institutions in many Anglophone African countries (not just. Kenya, Nigeria, Zambia and Zimbabwe, but also the Group A countries, Ghana and Uganda) suggests that, where the social consensus in favor of FRBG is not deeply embedded in society,'5 the risks are high that a political leader can 'defect' from FRBG, undermining the credibility of pre-existing formal institutions. This Anglophone route to neopatrimonialism may help explain why neopatrimonial Anglophone countries scored lower on credibility than did their Francophone counterparts. In part, the explanation may simply be one of perception - with Anglophone respondents registering their loss of confidence in FRBG, rather than their perceptions as to the (informal) predictability of the system. But the difference in scores may also reflect something more fundamental: As FRBG declined in Anglophone countries, the system of governance may have operated with a "dual logic", with formal and informal systems operating in parallel to one another, rendering each somewhat unpredictable. For all of the possible differences in the paths to neopatrimonialism, the fundamental governance challenge seems similar for the GroupB(frbg) and Group B(infc) countries. Weingast [1993] identifies the key analytical problem, and provides the key insight. The problem is the fundamental paradox of political economy -- namely that credible FRBG depends on states which have a monopoly on coercive authority, but whose political leadership nonetheless abides within formal restraints on the untrammeled use of state power. What, then, restrains the sovereign? Weingast's key insight is that restraints are only credible if they are self- enforcing: those in power need to weigh the gains of breaking restraints (i.e. of "defecting") against the costs of organizing to promote such actions, including the costs of fending off opposition. Ultimately what matters are patterns of civic engagement in the public arena and hence the perceptions of citizens as to the merits of restraining the sovereign. 13 See the discussion below of 'improving service quality'. 14 See Dia (1993) for a detailed discussion of the impact of 'neopatrimonialism' on African public management, and Lewis (1996) for a review of the burgeoning academic literature on neopatrimonialism in Africa. 1 SeeHyden,[19871 Consider three notional starting points. [These do not correspond directly to Groups A- C.] A first starting point is one where FRBG appears to work well, and is broadly perceived to be credible. Where the social consensus in favor of this institutional framework is strong, the self- enforcing conditions highlighted by Weingast as necessary for sustainability will be present. Post-apartheid, and post-Mandela, South Africa provides a hopeful example. By contrast where (as suggested above, may have been the case in many post-independence Anglophone countries) the social consensus in favor of FRBG is not deeply embedded in society the risks of leaders defecting from FRBG are high. Taken together, these divergent examples point to the very high returns of investing in civic engagement as a way of reinforcing the credibility more broadly of 'rule of law' institutions. Now consider the opposite starting point - one where the credibility of FRBG is weak, and political leaders remain committed to absolutist rule. As North, Finer (plus many other historians) have detailed, such a starting point was the reality in monarchical Europe. Civic engagement indeed was central in moving from monarchical absolutism to credible FRBG - but the process evolved over centuries, and took many difficult and violent turns. The third starting point is one where the credibility of FRBG has been eroded, but a political leader with seemingly unrestrained authority commits to an institutional revitalization based on a readiness to abide by formal check and balance mechanisms.'6 The key here is explicit, demand-side investment in civic engagement, for which a wide variety of measures are available. These include: * Constitutional reforms -- decentralization for example -- which aim to deepen participation; * Programs to fight corruption, especially approaches which include efforts to mobilize civic support for clean government; and * (As discussed further below) initiatives to engage citizens in improving the quality of service delivery. In the short-term, the restraints on the arbitrary use of political power implied by measures such as these will necessarily be self-imposed by the political leadership itself. But over time, insofar as the leadership acts in ways which strengthen civic engagement and commitment to the rule of law, the costs to political leaders of defecting from FRBG will rise. What had begun as a discretionary act of political leaders to abide by rules could evolve into a genuinely self-enforcing system. Nurturing civic engagement seems a challenge common to both the Group B(frbg) and Group B(infc) countries. However, the different starting points of Anglophone [predominantly Group B(frbg)] and Francophone [predominantly Group B(infc)] countries do point to some differences in what might plausibly follow. To illustrate, consider the historical experience of two Group A countries -- Ghana and Uganda. Viewed from the vantage point of the mid-1980s, 16 Bruce Ackerman (1996) describes this process as 'constitutionalizing charisma'. His depiction emphasizes the role of charismatic political leaders (such as Nelson Mandela) in giving legitimacy to explicit constitutional conferences, rather than the day-in, day-out decisions of political leaders to refrain from the arbitrary use of their authority. 12 neither would have been considered potential paragons of institutional strength: the former seemed trapped in a cycle of populist politics and military rule; the latter seemed unable to shake loose the legacy of the murderous rule of Idi Amin. Yet the data presented in this paper suggests that less than fifteen years later, both countries had managed to effect a remarkable turnaround. These rapid turnarounds suggest that, for Group B(frbg) countries, pre-existing FRBG forms can rapidly re-assert themselves, even after a long period of decay. Group B (infc) countries, with weaker legacies of FRBG, may need to invest more heavily - both in the formal structures of FRBG, and in civic knowledge as to the potential benefits of such structures. But they also may have more to lose in attempting to effect the transition to credible FRBG. For all of its limitations, credible informality comprises a form of institutional capital: it can provide a basis for both social order and private investment. This institutional capital may not be directly transferable to an FRBG framework. On the contrary, the risk needs to be recognized that externally-initiated, demand-side reform efforts to promote FRBG could undermine a socially-ordered, informal system of discretionary allocation - without being able to establish a credible system in its place. Improving the Quality of Bureaucracy As highlighted earlier, this paper considers two distinct dimensions of bureaucratic quality: the extent to which excessive bureaucratic 'red tape' imposes transactions costs on firms, inhibiting private sector development; and the quality of service delivery. The next subsections consider each in turn. A common theme in both discussions is the inter-relationship between bureaucratic quality and political governance - both the ways in which governance arrangements constrain the options for improving bureaucratic performance, and the ways in which reforms whose proximate purpose is to improve bureaucratic performance can also be supportive of governance reforms more broadly. Reducing bureaucratic excess. Prima facie, reducing bureaucratic excess through deregulation is the simplest of supply-side reforms, in that (except, as discussed in the final section of this paper, in some of the weakest states) it can be achieved by a stroke of the pen. What complicates the challenge is that excess regulation generally is part of a broader system of political governance. Regulatory restrictiveness can confer benefits on specific business, social, and bureaucratic interests: incumbent firms gain where regulations increase the costs of entry, and reduce competition; some social groups gain where regulation protects, say, the environment, or confers benefits on workers employed in the formal sector; and bureaucrats gain where regulation functions as a hurdle to firms which can be overcome with appropriate "side payments". Each of the constituencies which gain from 'red tape' potentially can constrain efforts at reform. The correlations in Table 5, and the corresponding associations for the 'mixed govemance' group in Table 6, highlight the inter-relations between bureaucratic excess and governance. Red tape emerges as a problem for 5 of 6 Group B(infc) countries. This strong correlation raises the possibility that regulatory dysfunction - and its corollary opportunities for rent extraction, for political control, and for informal intervention - is a necessary part of a 'credibly informal' neopatrimonial system of political governance. If so, the implication follows that, in such countries, efforts to tackle bureaucratic excess directly are unlikely to succeed. 13 By contrast, excess red tape emerges in Table 6 as a problem for just 1 of 6 Group B(frbg) countries. Prima facie, this relationship suggests that strength in FRBG provides a buttress against the accretion of excess red tape (or, conversely, that red tape, for all of its seeming bureaucratic origins, in practice is a means of providing the discretionary authority -- of exceptions - on which informality thrives). Yet for all of the allure of this inference it would be a mistake to conclude that there is a strong central tendency for FRBG and streamlined bureaucracy to be associated with one another. For one thing, 'red tape' was substantially more constraining in the mid-80s than it was in 1996 in virtually all FRBG countries (including those in Group A), with Ghana, Zambia and Zimbabwe especially clear examples. For another, the possibility cannot be ruled out that in some FRBG countries, 'red tape' was indeed an integral part of the pre-adjustment system of governance - and that the loosening of bureaucratic controls may have contributed to the unraveling of a political equilibrium, with an attendant loss of credibility."' Recognizing the inter-relations between bureaucratic 'red-tape' and governance implies that programs of deregulation generally need explicit demand-side strategies for overcoming bureaucratic, political and business interests which gain from regulatory restrictiveness. Initiatives to foster civic empowerment -- specifically inclusive business-government consultative mechanisms -- can help to build a constituency for reform, capable of overcoming the resistance of entrenched interests. Such fora were important in promoting bureaucratic reform in both Ghana and Uganda. The external pressure of conditional reforms linked to donor funding can also be helpful. While in the short-run, these conditions will be viewed by dominant elites as an external imposition, as new entrants become able to participate in the economy, local ownership of liberalizing reforms is likely to grow. Yet, sometimes, domestic consultative processes and external pressures may not be sufficient to eliminate bureaucratic excess. In these circumstances, it may be helpful to begin with roundabout approaches - easy-to-implement mechanisms for insulating export-oriented firms from a difficult local environment, such as export processing zones or bonded warehouse programs. Such initiatives can create "space" for efficient, outward-oriented private firms to emerge without challenging entrenched interests directly. In time, if such initiatives are successful, the constituency for liberalizing reforms of the business environment will grow. A process along these lines played a major role in the early industrial drive of many of Asia's newly industrialized countries, as well as in Mauritius.!8 Improving service quality. Improving the quality of public services was long perceived to be largely a supply-side technocratic problem, which could be adequately addressed by the relevant sectoral specialists: road and bridges by civil engineers; health care by medical experts etc. This 'stovepipe' approach has proven inadequate in a variety of ways. For one thing, it is increasingly being recognized that the constraints to public delivery of services often lie not at the front-line of delivery but in pervasive dysfunctions in public budgeting, personnel and financial control practices; systemic, rather than partial reforms may be needed. For another, new approaches to service provision have moved beyond efforts to improve public hierarchies, 17 Zimbabwe comes to mind as a possible example of such a process. For an elaboration of the argument, see Levy (1997). 18 For a detailed discussion of these mechanisms as roundabout ways of circumventing difficult local environments, see Levy (1991). 14 and have focused increasingly on improving performnance via increases in competition, in private participation and in public voice (notably including moves towards political decentralization and community empowerment).19 Moving from hierarchical delivery to these more pluralistic approaches has brought to the forefront the interface between service delivery and political governance. Public officials and other groups which benefit from hierarchical approaches have resisted change. Further, the institutions necessary for the pluralistic approach to succeed (e.g.: regulatory and judicial mechanisms to resolve disputes with private providers; feedback mechanisms from citizens to higher-level bureaucrats and politicians) often are missing. The data summarized in Tables 4, 5 and 6 suggest some cross-country differences in how to approach the challenges of improving service delivery. Countries in Group A appear to have had a workable platform for moving forward - both in that they were perceived to have workable governance, and in that 4 of the 5 countries (Ghana, Mauritius, South Africa and Uganda) already were perceived to offer adequate services. These countries seemed well positioned to proceed directly with "supply-side" reforms - strengthening the systemic public management underpinnings of service delivery, and experimenting with new approaches, both system-wide and at the level of the services themselves. By contrast, improving service delivery among Group B countries - both Group B(frbg) and Group B(infc) - seems likely to require addressing governance as well as technocratic, "supply-side" constraints.20 The options here parallel those for reforms to reduce bureaucratic excess. As with bureaucratic reforms, "enclaving" the delivery of key services - for example, through quasi-independent delivery mechanisms -- can be a way around governance constraints which cannot be addressed directly. The dilemma, though, is that enclaving specific service delivery initiatives adds to the fragmentation of already dysfunctional public management systems, thereby creating difficulties down the road of improving the overall public management system. More broadly, efforts to improve the quality of public services can be a powerful impetus for systemic changes in governance in Group B countries. While efforts to roll back an overextended bureaucracy often prove controversial politically, there is generally an overwhelming social consensus that public services can and should be improved. Further, the evidence is increasingly compelling that beneficiary participation is a powerful engine of service improvement. Taken together, these features of service delivery may enable reformers to leverage governance reform even in quite difficult environments by initiating a variety of demand-side participatory approaches, including: 9 See Girishankar (1999) for an in-depth discussion of these new approaches to service provision, and their relation to political governance. 20 Some differences in the perceived quality of service delivery among the Group B(frbg) and Group B(infc) are noteworthy: service delivery performance was generally weak in Group B(frbg) countries - but there seemed to be important pockets of strength in Group B(infc) countries. One possible explanation for the latter might be that the provision of adequate infrastructural services to the private sector (who comprised the respondents to the WDR survey) was part of the neopatrimonial "bargain" in these countries. Certainly, it would be mistaken to conclude from the WDR survey that service provision to the full range of Group B(infc) citizenry was of good quality. 15 * Undertaking - and making the results publicly available -- user surveys and other quantitative "scorecards" of the quality of public services; * User participation in service delivery and oversight: empowering parents to participate in the governance of schools; placing user groups at the center of irrigations systems management; involving community groups in the delivery of urban water and waste systems; * Social funds to support efforts by communities and non-governmental organizations themselves to deliver services to, say, the poor; * Bringing government closer to the people by decentralizing responsibility for the delivery of front-line services (or, more broadly, for decisions on the allocation of some portion of scarce public resources) from central to local governments. Where initiatives such as these take hold, the net result can be an increase in both the legitimacy and accountability of states - key steps along the path to credible FRBG. Institutional options when governance is "weak" Table 6 categorized 4 countries as belonging in Group C, the "weak governance" group. This categorization needs to be handled with care. As a comparison with other indices of performance shows,2' the selection of sub-Saharan African countries for the 1996 WDR survey was biased in that it included virtually none of the worst performing third of African countries. Within a more encompassing "weak governance" category, there is thus a spectrum of weakness. At the stronger end of the spectrum are countries whose differences from those with 'mixed governance' are differences of degree, rather than of kind. As of 1996, using the WDR sample (and defining weak as ranking below the median in all four categories scored) these included countries (e.g.: Tanzania) with a prior history of workable FRBG, subsequently eroded, but with evident potential for a turnaround;22 and countries (e.g. Mozambique) which had successfully emerged from civil conflict, and were on the road to rebuilding credibility. At the other end of the spectrum were countries (not in the sample) enmeshed in civil conflict or its fragile aftermath; and, at the limit, geographic entities (e.g. Somalia, also not in the sample) where the formal political order had disintegrated to the point that they were essentially stateless. Even as differences within the "weak" category are recognized, it seems broadly to be the case that there exist a variety of reform options which are plausible for countries with "mixed governance", but which countries with especially weak governance may find difficult to undertake, even with willing political leadership. For example, rolling back an overextended bureaucracy presupposes a capability to impose hierarchical discipline on public officials; weak states may lack the 'reach' to impose such discipline. Along similar lines, whereas active civic engagement can be useful in restraining absolutist political leaders in mixed governance settings, in countries where political control remains very fragile, civic activism may also have the unintended side effect of contributing to continued state weakness. 21 See Annex 3 22 Tanzania's continuing commitment in recent years to an ambitious program of institutional reform suggests that such a turnaround is underway. 16 What, then, are potentially workable options in countries with weak governance? While a 2002 World Bank taskforce on Low-Income Countries Under Stress has addressed this question directly, two specific insights from the present analysis of 'less-weak' settings may add some value. First, consistent with the worldwide experience noted earlier (and considered further in Annex 1), the immediate task in very weak states may be less. to strengthen the "demand-side" of civic voice, than to build a baseline of political authority. With political authority in place, the process of "constitutionalizing charisma"23 has a chance of proceeding - although, even then, the time horizon of political leaders may be too short for them to be willing to act only within (self- imposed... and externally encouraged...) FRBG restraints. Nonetheless, in the absence of coherent political authority, it is difficult to see how FRBG can take root. Second, 'quick wins' will be key in buttressing the position of political leaders who seek to build legitimacy, and some sense of possibility, among citizens. And these quick wins may best be achieved by enclaving: using social funds to facilitate the provision of basic services even in the absence of any semblance of bureaucratic coherence; using special economic zones to create 'hassle free' spaces within which private economic activity can begin to take hold; and providing special incentives to tax administrators as a way of beginning to generate public revenues. Neither of these approaches offers a direct route to well-functioning public institutions of the kind described in the first paragraph of this paper. But in countries where governance is especially weak, the direct approaches - focusing on check and balance mechanisms, and on comprehensive overhauls of public management systems - are unlikely to bear fruit. 'Goodness of fit' with a country's institutional starting points- not consistency with some a priori notion of 'best practice' - seems key to getting results on the ground. 23 See Ackerman (1996) and footnote 15. 17 Annex 1: Dimensionalizing Governance - Some Antecedents A key feature of this paper is that it considers governance as a multi-dimensional phenomenon - both in its distinction between political governance and bureaucratic quality and, within political governance, in its distinction between credibility and the quality of FRBG. This annex summarizes some other contributions which aim to provide some 'dimensionality' to governance. The intent is simply to place the present paper into a broader context of literature on political development - both to highlight for readers who may be less familiar with that literature the intellectual pedigree of efforts to move beyond a single-variable continuum of governance, and to highlight that there can be a variety of different ways of building dimensionality into the analysis. Immediate antecedents - new institutional analysis. As noted in the text, the most direct antecedent of the present approach is Bomer, Brunetti and Weber (BBW; 1995), who focus in depth on credibility as a distinct feature of political governance. BBW draw on the new institutional economics -- especially the contributions of North (1991) and others who have focused on the role of formal law as a basis for protecting property rights in transactionally efficient ways, and Olson (1991) who draws the distinction between 'stationary' and 'roving' bandits. BBW, though, make explicit in ways that others do not the distinction between credible rules (which can be assured by 'stationary bandits') and efficient rules (which, in complex market economies, require a well-developed legal and judicial system). Note that the distinction between credibility and FRBG has a direct parallel in a classic debate in political philosophy - notably Hobbes depiction of the state as Leviathan, which nonetheless offers a way out of the 'nasty, brutish and short' state of nature, versus Locke's (and Rawls') depiction of the state as a constitutional order reflecting consensual win-win agreements. 'History of Government'. Finer's three volumes, The History of Government (1997) represents the remarkable, twenty-years in the making 'post-retirement' capstone to a career of over fifty years in comparative history and politics. His goal was 'to provide a history of successive forms of government throughout the world from the earliest times to the present day.... to identify similarities and differences between the forms of government described, according to a standard typology' (VI, p.1). Finer draws the following distinctions of special relevance to the present paper: * Between its decision-making personnel/processes and its decision-implementing personnel/processes (pp.35-6); and * Amongst decision-making processes, between governments that are unconstrained by 'man-made restrictions' and governments that are constrained by substantive and/or procedural rules (pp. 74-78). Given the focus in the present paper on the inter-relation between credibility and FRBG, of special relevance is Finer's historical analysis, first, of the emergence in Europe of secularized absolute monarchical states out of medieval, religious feudalism (in the 13th-15w centuries), and then of the process whereby absolute monarchies became progressively constrained, evolving 18 into modem states, governed by law and, increasingly, democratic control. Here, Finer distinguishes usefully between: * 'Palace and palace/nobility polities' (think: 'the divine right of kings'), which dominated much of Europe for much of the 16th-18th centuries, though even in this period their rule was constrained by 'law-boundedness, and the survival (in weak form) of 'intermediate' bodies of aristocrats (pp. 38-43; 1455-1460); * 'Pluralistic palace/forum polities' - authoritarianism - characterized by rule from above, with authority conferred by popular consent (with, in the 19kh and 20th century European context, the consenters comprising the nobility, the church, as well as organized labor and organized capital, acting in their corporatist capacity) (pp. 1567- 1568); * 'Monistic palace/forum polities' - 20th century totalitarianism (p. 1568); and * 'Pluralistic forum polities' -- into which category Finer incorporates (and distinguishes between) liberalism (whose 'hard core of principle [comprises] ring- fencing certain liberties against state intrusion'), constitutionalism ('a fundamental law or set of principles to restrict arbitrary power and ensure limited government'), and 'liberal democracy' ('qualified democracy.. .where the ultimate right of the majority to have its way is conceded....but with institutional devices for the slowing down of the decision-making processes so as to give time for a minority to persuade the majority....') (pp. 1568-1571). As Finer explores - and as was also examined in depth by Barrington Moore (1966) -- which type of polity emerges in a specific country setting will depend in substantial part on the relative strength of different social actors. Viewed from the perspective of the present paper, all four types of polities can be credible, but they differ from one another in their extent of law-boundedness and participation: totalitarian polities may have the form of law but in practice are not law-bounded; palace and palace/nobility polities are implicitly, but not explicitly bounded by law; pluralistic palace/forum and forum polities both are characterized by FRBG, with forum polities more inclusive in their protections of individual rights. 'Political modernization' in developing countries. In the 1960s and 1970s a rich literature emerged on the dynamics of contemporary political modernization. Though it became to be regarded increasingly skeptically in the 1980s (for reasons similar to the debunking of Walt Rostow's narrow and mechanical approach to 'stages of growth') many of its themes continue to influence contemporary thinking on development. Huntington (1968) comprises a seminal contribution that is of particular relevance to the present paper. Citing Parsons, Huntington notes that power not only has to be allocated, but also has to be produced (p.143). Thus, viewed through the rubric of the present paper, Huntington can be interpreted as distinguishing between two dimensions of credibility: whether power is concentrated or dispersed; and whether the amount of power is small or large. Thus, Huntington argues that "the first challenge of modernization to a dispersed, weakly articulated and organized, feudalistic traditional system is to concentrate the power necessary to produce 19 changes in the traditional society and economy. The second problem is then to expand the power in the system... .this challenge is the predominant one in the modernizing world today. At a later stage, the system is confronted with the demands of the participant groups for a greater dispersion of power and for the establishment of reciprocal checks and controls among groups and institutions" (p. 146). Huntington highlights "institutionalization" - both political and bureaucratic (with the former in particular corresponding to FRBG) - as the key way to expand power. Note that, in Huntington's rubric, once such institutionalization has taken place, credibility can be achieved even when power is dispersed. Michael Mann's recent (1995) set of distinctions emerges in this context as a direct descendent of the earlier work by Huntington. Mann distinguishes between "despotic" power and "bureaucratic" power. He notes that in many developing countries, there is no lack of "despotic" power (including corrupt despots), but that society is only weakly embedded in networks of formal and informal institutional arrangements. Following Huntington, Mann argues that, in the absence of bureaucratic power, the reach - even of despots - is weak. Strengthening bureaucratic power is thus the crucial development challenge. 20 Annex 2: Characteristics of the WDR Africa Sample Country: G B G. G C C C C. K M T N S M M M T M S U Z Z U E B H A 0 H D' E A 0 1 E A 0 A A A 0 G I A I N I A M N A I N L G G N D Z U N L U A M M N I S N E G D V Y 1 0 E E A A R Z A T N B B E N A A R 0 0 A R G G M I A W H D A I A U 0 1 1 A A B T N I A A B A 0 R A L S 1 I 1 F W N E C Q U A R E A U S I R E C I ~~~~A Sample 20 1 47 1181 92 142 146 [13 145 1601 100 11241 90 150 197 1471 48 6 4 103 104 25 32 size (n) I Company Sie(L- -*T-*W 347130 8361 29 less than 50 55 81 [71 137 10 6 1 6 8 7 8 2 0 4 0 8 3 61 2 1 employees ~- - I- >50 and <200 40 1 5 1 2 27 26 26 54 24 30 19 13 49 72 28 23 44 36 2 1 1 9 2 1 484 1 employees ]. 1..l i more than 200 030 21 1 1 1 5 7 32 752 1 1 0 41 30 46 34 7 1 43 14 404 1 employees 1.I........ _I_ Industry () Manufacturing 1601 34 1 2 149 J241 371 3 1 1 571_28] 25 T 481 74 [ 49 132 j 52 521 581 521 41 1881 97 Services 1 40 5 1129 401 52 59~1 621 61 43 341 581 38 1141 28 16014 3 4 250 23 Agiulture I10191 35[8j 191 2 1 0 1201 0 1 321 6 1 14 1121 20 1 2 1 4 1 0133 4 ___ Location of man gIn:(%) Capital city 85 53 24 (70 24 48 100 84 ( 621 45 81 27 9 61 8 56 2 17f 6 45 67 r 31 Largecity 0O 28147 15 60 50 0 7 122 28_ 1 70 0 29 14 110 10 58 t 43 34 21 47 Small city or 10 13 1 12 1 3 12 2 0 7 17 23 0 3 4 8 6 33 8 25 [29 16 13 f22 countr side __ _ _ _j_ _ __ _I ..!.- - Foreign participation (%) yes 140 36 118 57 52 1761 691 22 35 231 391 131 541 54 55 291 461 61 34 23 1481 47 no 155 60 182 42 145 1241 311 731 631 731 561 871 461 45 1451 691 521 391 63 72 1521 50 Exports:(% yes 55 29 112 29 153 1301 461 511 541 281 44 221 721 64 1331 641 451 831 53 19 1831 47 -no 45 71 188 7 11 48 1701 541 491 461 721 56 781 281 36 1671 361 551 1 7 47 8 11 1 7 53 21 Annex 3: The Robustness of the Governance Indicators An important limitation of much empirical research on governance (including the present paper) is that the data are measures of subjective perception. As footnote 1 noted, this generates a variety of different types of measurement "noise" -- for example contamination of the results by the way questions are formulated, subjective judgements in relation to 1-6 scales, and difficulties in making cross-country comparisons. An innovative recent (1999) paper by Kaufmann, Kraak and Zoido-Lobaton (KKZL) addresses this problem of "noise" by combining each of the many instruments (including the WDR survey) and variables which have been devised to measure governance into a single set of six composite 'meta-variables'. For each of their six composite variables, they generate mean country estimates, plus measures of the standard error of each estimate. (Their choice of units is structured so that each variable has a mean estimated value of 0, a standard deviation of 1, and a range for the full set of almost 150 countries from - 2.5 to +2.5.). As compared with the WDR survey, the KKZL indicators have the advantage of greater robustness - both in that the measures come from multiple sources, and in that the KKZL methodology enables them to generate standard errors of mean estimates for individual countries. The disadvantage of the KKZL approach is that the composite nature of their variables blurs to some extent the distinctions among the different governance variables.24 Three of the six KKZL composite variables measure elements of governance similar to those which are the focus of the present paper.25 These are: * Government effectiveness. This variable combines perceptions of the quality of public service provision, the quality of the bureaucracy, the competence of civil servants, the independence of the civil service from political pressures, and the credibility of government's commitment to policies. * Rule of law. This variable includes perceptions of the incidence of both violent and non-violent crime, the effectiveness and predictability of the judiciary, and the enforceability of contracts. * Graft, defined as the exercise of public power for private gain. The particular aspect of corruption measured by the various sources ranges from the frequency of additional payments to 'get things done' to the effects of corruption on the business environment. Annex Table 3-1 reports the mean values, standard errors (and number of instruments for which data was available in the relevant country) for these three variables for each of the 22 African 24 In a cross correlation matrix among the six KKZL variables, none of the variables have correlations below 0.51, with all but one of the cross-correlations falling in the 0.5 - 0.7 range. 5 The other three KKIM variables are "voice and accountability", "political instability and violence", and "regulatory burden". While prima facie the last of these corresponds to the' "bureaucratic quality/red tape" variables used in the body of the paper, in practice KKZL measure something very different: their composite includes "the incidence of market unfriendly policies such as price controls or inadequate banking supervision, as well as perceptions of the burdens posed by excess regulation in areas such as foreign trade and business development". The cross-correlations between the KKZL measure and the three red tape measures in this paper - time, barriers, and overall ranking - are 0.06, 0.36 and 0.25 respectively. 22 countries examined in this sample (as of 1997/8). (Annex Table 3-2 reports updated indicators produced by KKZL using 2000/1 data). Annex Table 3-1: the KKZL indicators for 22 African countries, 1997/8 . Government Effectiveness Rule-of.Law_ _ _ __Graft _ Estimate Standard # Estimate Standard # Estimate Standard Error Indicator Error Indicator Error Indicator Benin -0.066 0.564 1 -0.422 0.450 2 -0.781 0.537 I 1 Cameroon -0.645 0.240 5 -1.015 0.253 6 -1.105 0.211 5 Chad -0.714 0.564 1 -0.827 0.450 2 -0.587 0.537 I Congo -0.580 0.385 3 -1.435 0.371 3 -0.596 0.485 2 Cote -0.180 0.240 5 -0.335 0.253 6 -0.079 0.211 5 d'lvoire . . _ . . Ghana -0.287 0.222 T 6 0.014 , 0.253 6 -0.301 0.211 , 5 Guinea -0.029 0.510 T 2 -0.762 0.371 3 -0.848 0.485 T 2 Guinea- -0.334 0.510 2 -1.615 T 0.371 3 -0.176 0.485 T 2 Bissau : : : ' : : Kenya -0.899 0.222 6 -1.220 0.253 6 -0.651 0.211 5 Madagascar -0.295 0.385 3 -0.825 0.371 3 -0.469 0.485 2 Malawi -0.625 0.239 5 -0.409 0.281 5 -0.195 0.224 4 Mali -0.052 0.510 2 -0.465 0.371 3 -0.476 0.485 2 Mauritius 0.172 0.268 3 1.279 0.311 4 0.336 0.228 3 Mozam- -0.331 0.288 4 -1.046 0.363 4 -0.535 0.311 3 bique . . . ._.__ Nigeria -1.321 0.222 6 -1.097 0.253 6 -0.954 0.202 6 Senegal 0.047 0.286 4 -0.097 0.285 4 -0.235 0.268 3 South -0.010 0.206 8 -0.351 0.206 9 0.299 0.171 9 Africa : : : _ : Tanzania -0.485 0.222 6 0.161 0.253 6 -0.924 0.211 5 Togo -0.374 0.510 2 -0.799 0.371 3 -0.242 0.485 2 Uganda -0.251 0.222 6 -0.013 0.253 6 -0.466 0.211 5 Zambia -0.399 0.222 6 -0.402 0.253 6 -0.614 0.211 5 Zimbabwe -1.129 0.222 6 -0.146 0.233 7 -0.319 0.185 7 The three composite variables described in Annex Table 2-1 correspond to - and are quite highly correlated with -- the WDR measures in the body of this paper of policy credibility, judicial quality, and corruption. The KKZL government effectiveness measure also is quite highly correlated with the WDR measure of the quality of service delivery26. As such, a comparison for each matched pair of the differences in how the 22 countries rank in the WDR and KKZL measures highlights for which countries the WDR estimates can be viewed as reasonably robust, and for which there is a strong reason to treat the WDR scores (and hence the categorization of a specific country in Table 6) with caution. Country rankings differed by 8 or more positions in the following:27 26 For the 22 African countries, the correlation coefficients for the WDR-KKZL pairs are: 0.62 for credibility/government effectiveness; 0.46 for judicial quality/rule of law; 0.62 for corruption/graft; and 0.59 for g7uality of service delivery/government effectiveness. 2'Note that, in addition to measurement error, shocks which occurred only after the 1996 WDR survey (but before some of the other measures incorporated in KKZL) can also account for differences in ranking between the WDR and KKZL data. To cite three examples: by 1998 Zimbabwe was in the throes of a macroeconomic crisis; Guinea 23 * For the graft/corruption matched pair, Cote d'Ivoire and Madagascar emerge in the KKZL data set as less corrupt than in the WDR (ranked 3rd and 1 Ith, rather than 16th and 19th), but Nigeria, Zambia, and Kenya emerge as more corrupt (ranked 21st, 16th, and 17th, rather than 7th, 4th, and 9th). * For the rule of law/judicial quality matched pair, Cote d'Ivoire, Senegal, Guinea and Tanzania emerge as stronger in the KKZL data (ranked 7th, 5th, 13th, and 2nd) than in the WDR data (ranked 18th, 21st, 22nd, and 13th) - although these differences may reflect in part the broader definition of the KKZL variable, and some corresponding 'non-judicial' sources of social stability of the four countries. By contrast, the KKZL data ranks Guinea-Bissau and Nigeria (8th and 22nd) worse than the WDR data (8th and 22nd). * For the government effectiveness/credibility and government effectiveness/service quality matched pairs, the comparison is less straightforward since one KKZL variable maps into two of the WDR variables used in the present study. Even so, Madagascar emerges unambiguously, as stronger in the KKZL data (ranked 10th) than in the WDR data (ranked 20th for credibility and 17th for service quality), and Chad (ranked 19th ini KKZL versus 11th for both WDR variables) as unambiguously weaker.28 Put differently, using the KKZL rankings, Cote d'Ivoire and Senegal would unambiguously be 'promoted' in Table 6 into the 'strong governance' column and Madagascar and Tanzania into the 'mixed governance' columns (the former 'informal but credible', the latter 'FRBG but low credibility'). By contrast, Nigeria, Kenya and Chad each would migrate from 'mixed' to 'weak governance'. Any other changes would be 'borderline calls'. Note also that for seven countries - Benin, Ghana, Mali, Mauritius, Mozambique, Togo and Uganda - the KKZL and WDR rankings are virtually identical for all four matched pairs. Bissau had plunged into civil war; and Zambia had concluded a massive privatization of its copper mine in ways which raised questions over its transparency. 28 Other noteworthy comparisons: Malawi's KKZL ranking (17'h) straddles its two WDR rankings (7th for credibility, and 18"' for service quality, as do Guinea Bussau's (12"' versus 18"' and 3rd). 24 Annex Table 3-2: the KKZL indicators for 22 African countries, 2000/1 Governnent Effectiveness Rule of Law Graft Estimate Standard # Estimate Standard | Estimate Standard Error Indicator Error Indicator Error Indicator Benin 0.12 0.52 1 -0.57 0.43 2 Cameroon -0.40 0.25 5 -1.02 0.25 6 -1.11 0.25 5 Chad -0.86 0.52 1 1 Congo -1.580 0.40 2 -1.11 0.37 3 -0.49 0.39 2 Cote d'Ivoire -0.81 0.25 4 -0.54 0.25 5 -0.71 0.26 4 Ghana -0.06 0.25 5 -0.01 0.25 6 -0.28 0.25 5 Guinea 0.41 0.53 1 -0.59 0.43 2 0.13 0.65 1 Guinea-Bissau -1.48 0.40 2 -1.50 0.37 3 0.10 0.39 2 Kenya -0.76 0.222 6 -1.21 0.24 6 -1.11 0.22 6 Madagascar -0.35 0.37 t 3 -0.68 0.34 4 -0.93 0.32 3 Malawi -0.77 0.26 4 -0.36 0.29 5 0.10 0.26 4 Mali -1.44 0.40 2 -0.66 0.37 3 -0.41 0.39 2 Mauritius 0.76 0.26 3 1.00 0.26 4 0.49 0.26 3 Mozambique -0.49 0.40 4 -0.32 0.37 3 0.10 0.39 2 Nigeria -1.00 0.21 7 -1.13 T 0.20 8 -1.05 0.20 7 Senegal 0.16 0.26 4 -0.13 T 0.29 5 -0.39 0.26 4 South Africa 0.25 0.18 10 -0.05 0.18 10 0.35 0.18 10 Tanzania -0.43 0.23 5 0.16 0.24 6 -0.92 0.23 5 Togo -1.32 0.53 1 -0.82 0.43 2 -0.48 0.65 1 Uganda -0.32 0.23 l 5 -0.65 0.24 6 -0.92 0.23 5 Zambia -0.75 0.23 5 -0.39 0.24 6 -0.87 0.23 5 Zimbabwe -1.03 0.22 l 5 -0.94 0.21 7 -1.08 0.23 5 25 BIBLIOGRAPHY Ackernan, Bruce (1996), "The Rise of Constitutional Democracy" Virginia Law Review Barrington Moore Jr. (1966). The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracv (Boston; Beacon Press) Borner, Silvio, Brunetti, Aymo, and Beatrice Weder, (1995). Political Credibility and Economic Development (new York: St. Martins Press) Brunetti, Aymo, Kisunko, Gregory and Beatrice Weder (1997) "Credibility of rules and economic growth: evidence from a worldwide survey of the private sector", World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, number 1760 Dia, Mamadou (1996) Africa's Management in the 1990s and Beyond: Reconciling Indigenous and Transplanted Institutions, (Washington D.C: World Bank, Directions in Development Series) Finer, S.E. (1997) The HistorEy of Government From the Earliest Times, volumes I-En (New York: Oxford University Press) Girishankar, Navin (1998), "Reforming Institutions for Service Delivery", World Bank Staff Working Paper, Huntington, Samuel P., (1968), Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press) Hyden, Goran, (1987) No Shortcuts to Progress (Berkeley: University of California Press) Kaufimann, Daniel, Aart Kraay and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton (1999) "Governance Matters", World Bank Policy Research Department Working Paper No. 2196 -- (2002) "Governance Matters II: Updated Indicators for 2000/01" unpublished draft Levy, Brian and Pablo T. Spiller (1996) Regulations. Institutions and Commitment (New York: Cambridge University Press Levy, Brian (1997), "Fostering Private Sector Development in Africa: an Institutional Approach", plenary paper presented at inaugural conference of International Society for New Institutional Economics, Washington University 26 -- (1991), 'The design and sequencing of trade and investment policy reform", World Bank Economic Review Lewis, Peter M. (1996) "Economic reform and political transition in Africa: The quest for a politics of development" in World Politics, V.49, no. 1 pp. 92-129 Mamdani, Mahmood (1996) Citizens and Subjects (Princeton: Princeton University Press) Mann, Michael, "The autonomous power of the state: Its origins, mechanisms and results", in JA Hall (ed), States in History (Basil Blackwell, Oxford, 1986). McCubbins, Matthew, Roger Noll and Barry Weingast, "Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control", Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 3 (2), 242- 277 Migdal, Joel (1988) Stron, Societies and Weak States (Princeton: Princeton University Press) North, Douglass (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press) Olson, Mancur (1991) "Autocracy, democracy and Prosperity" in Richard Zeckhauser (ed.), Strategy and Choice (New York: MIT Press) Weingast, Barry R. (1993), "Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets", Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149, pp. 286-311 Williamson, Oliver E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: The Free Press) World Bank (1997) The State in a Changing World: World Development Report 1997 (Oxford University Press for the World Bank) 27 Africa Region Working Paper Series Series # Title - Date Author ARWPS 1 Progress in Public Expenditure Management in Africa: January 1999 Christos Kostopoulos Evidence from World Bank Surveys ARWPS 2 Toward Inclusive and Sustainable Development in the March 1999 Markus Kostner Democratic Republic of the Congo ARWPS 3 Business Taxation in a Low-Revenue Economy: A June 1999 Ritva Reinikka Study on Uganda in Comparison with Neighboring Duanjie Chen Countries ARWPS 4 Pensions and Social Security in Sub-Saharan Africa: October 1999 Luca Barbone Issues and Options Luis-Alvaro Sanchez B. ARWPS 5 Forest Taxes, Government Revenues and the January 2000 Luca Barbone Sustainable Exploitation of Tropical Forests Juan Zalduendo ARWPS 6 The Cost of Doing Business: Firms' Experience with June 2000 Jacob Svensson Corruption in Uganda ARWPS 7 On the Recent Trade Performance of Sub-Saharan August 2000 Francis Ng and African Countries: Cause for Hope or More of the Same Alexander J. Yeats ARWPS 8 Foreign Direct Investment in Africa: Old Tales and New November 2000 Miria Pigato Evidence ARWPS 9 The Macro Implications of HIIV/AIDS in South Africa: November 2000 Channing Arndt A Preliminary Assessment Jeffrey D. Lewis ARWPS 10 Revisiting Growth and Convergence: Is Africa Catching December 2000 C. G. Tsangarides Up? ARWPS 11 Spending on Safety Nets for the Poor: How Much, for January 2001 William James Smith How Many? The Case of Malawi ARWPS 12 Tourism in Africa February 2001 lain T. Christie Doreen E. Crompton ARWPS 13 Conflict Diamonds February 2001 Louis Goreux ARWPS 14 Reform and Opportunity: The Changing Role and March 2001 Jeffrey D. Lewis Patterns of Trade in South Africa and SADC ARWPS 15 The Foreign Direct Investment Environment in Africa March 2001 Miria Pigato ARWPS 16 Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes for Developing April 2001 Fahrettin Yagci Countries 28 Africa Region Working Paper Series Series # Title Date Author ARWPS 17 Export Processing Zones: Has Africa Missed the Boat? May 2001 Peter L. Watson Not yet! ARWPS 18 Rural Infrastructure in Africa: Policy Directions June 2001 Robert Fishbein ARWPS 19 Changes in Poverty in Madagascar: 1993-1999 July 2001 Stefano Paternostro Jean Razafindravonona David Stifel ARWPS 20 Information and Communication Technology, Poverty, August 2001 Miria Pigato and Development in sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia ARWPS 21 Handling Hierarchy in Decentralized Settings: September 2001 Navin Girishankar Governance Underpinnings of School Performance in Abebaw Alemayehu Tikur Inchini, West Shewa Zone, Oromia Region Yusuf Ahmad ARWPS 22 Child Malnutrition in Ethiopia: Can Maternal October 2001 Luc Christiaensen Knowledge Augment The Role of Income? Harold Alderman ARWPS 23 Child Soldiers: Preventing,Demobilizing and November 2001 Beth Verhey Reintegrating ARWPS 24 The Budget and Medium-Term Expenditure Framework December 2001 David L. Bevan in Uganda ARWPS 25 Design and Implementation of Financial Management January 2002 Guenter Heidenhof Systems: An African Perspective Helene Grandvoinnet Daryoush Kianpour Bobak Rezaian ARWPS 26 What Can Africa Expect From Its Traditional Exports? February 2002 Francis Ng Alexander Yeats ARWPS 27 Free Trade Agreements and the SADC Economies February 2002 Jeffrey D. Lewis Sherman Robinson Karen Thierfelder ARWPS 28 Medium Term Expenditure Frameworks: From Concept February 2002 Philippe Le Houerou to Practice. Preliminary Lessons from Africa Robert Taliercio ARWPS 29 The Changing Distribution of Public Education February 2002 Samer Al-Samarrai Expenditure in Malawi Hassan Zaman ARWPS 30 Post-Conflict Recovery in Africa: An Agenda for the April 2002 Serge Michailof Africa Region Markus Kostner Xavier Devictor 29 Africa Region Working Paper Series Series # Title Date Author ARWPS 31 Efficiency of Public Expenditure Distribution and May 2002 Xiao Ye Beyond: A report on Ghana's 2000 Public Expenditure Sudharshan Canagaraja Tracking Survey in the Sectors of Primary Health and Education ARWPS 32 Promoting Growth and Employment in South Africa June 2002 Jeffrey D.Lewis ARWPS 33 Addressing Gender Issues in Demobilization and August 2002 Nathalie de Watteville Reintegration Programs ARWPS 34. Putting Welfare on the Map in Madagascar August 2002 Johan A. Mistiaen Berk Ozler Tiaray Razafimanantena Jean Razafindravonona ARWPS 35 A Review of the Rural Firewood Market Strategy August 2002 Gerald Foley in West Africa Paul Kerkhof Djibrilla Madougou ARWPS 36 Patterns of Governance in Africa September 2002 Brian D. Levy 30 Headquarters 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, USA Telephone: (202) 477-1234 Facsimile: (202) 477-6391 RCA 248423 WORLDBK Cable Addr.: INTBAFRAD WAHINGTONDC Working Paper Series web address: http://www.worldbank.org/afr/wps/index.htm European Office 66, avenue d'lena 75116 Paris, France Telephone: (1) 40.69.30.00 Facsimile: (1) 40.69.30.66 Telex: 640651 Tokyo Office Fukoku Seimei Building, 10th Floor 2-2-2 Uchisaiwai-Cho Chiyoda-Ku, Tokyo 100-0011 Japan Telephone: (81-3) 3597-6650 Facsimile: (81-3) 3597-6695 Telex: 26838