t9? J3}b) POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 3 03 5 Traffic Fatalities and Economic Growth Elizabeth Kopits Maureen Cropper The World Bank Development Research Group Infrastructure and Environment April 2003 U POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 3035 Abstract Kopits and Cropper examine the impact of income fatalities peaks is approximately $8,600 in 1985 growth on the death rate due to traffic fatalities, as well internationial dollars. This is within the range of income as on fatalities per motor vehicle and on the at which other externalities, such as air and water motorization rate (vehicles/population) using panel data pollution, have been found to peak. from 1963-99 for 88 countries. Specifically, they Projections of future traffic fatalities suggest that the estimate fixed effects models for fatalities/population, global road death toll will grow by approximately 66 vehicles/population, and fatalities/vehicles and use these percent between 2000 and 2020. This number, however, models to project traffic fatalities and the stock of motor reflects divergent rates of change in different parts of the vehicles to 2020. world-a decline in fatalities in high-income countries of The relationship between motor vehicle fatality rate approximately 28 percent versus an increase in fatalities and per capita income at first increases with per capita of almost 92 percent in China and 147 percent in India. income, reaches a peak, and then declines. This is The authors also predict that the fatality rate will rise to because at low income levels the rate of increase in approximately 2 per 10,000 persons in developing motor vehicles outpaces the decline in fatalities per countries by 2020, while it will fall to less than 1 per motor vehicle. At higher income levels, the reverse 10,000 in high-income countries. occurs. The income level at whlich per capita traffic This paper-a product of Infrastructure and Environment, Development Research Group-is part of a larger effort in the group to study the externalities associated with motorization. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Viktor Soukhanov, room MC2-205, telephone 202-473-5721, fax 202-522-3230, email address vsoukhanov@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at kopits@rff.org or mcropper@worldbank.org. April 2003. (42 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Senes disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues An obhective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by the Research Advisory Staff TRAFFIC FATALITIES AND ECONOMIC GROWTH Elizabeth Kopits University of Maryland and Resourcesfor the Future Maureen Cropper World Bank We would like to thank the World Bank Research Board for funding and the Bank's Road Safety Thematic Group for comments and encouragement. We would especially like to thank Zmarak Shalizi for his encouragement during early stages of the project. Paulus Guitink and Hua Wang generously provided data. We would also like to thank the following people for their comments and suggestions: Amy Aeron-Thomas, Roger Betancourt, Bill Evans, Goff Jacobs, Matthijs Koornstra, Seth Sanders, Jeff Smith, V. Kerry Smith, and Jagadish Guria for his careful reading of the paper. We appreciate the comments of seminar participants at Resources for the Future, the University of Maryland, Camp Resources and the International Conference on Vehicle Safety and Reliability in Keszthely, Hungary. Traffic Fatalities and Economic Growth Elizabeth Kopits and Maureen Cropper I. Introduction As countries develop death rates usually fall, especially for diseases that affect the young and result in substantial life-years lost. Deaths due to traffic accidents are a notable exception: the growth in motor vehicles that accompanies economic growth usually brings an increase in road traffic accidents. Indeed, the World Health Organization has predicted that traffic fatalities will be the sixth leading cause of death worldwide and the second leading cause of disability-adjusted life-years lost in developing countries by the year 2020 (Murray and Lopez 1996). Table 1 highlights the increasing importance of the problem in several developing countries. For example, between 1975 and 1998, road traffic deaths per capita increased by 44% in Malaysia and by over 200% in Colombia and Botswana. The situation in high-income countries is quite different. Over the same period, traffic fatalities per person decreased by 60% in Canada and Hong Kong, and by amounts ranging from 25% to 50% in most European countries. This reflects a downward trend in both the fatality rate (deaths/population) and in fatalities per kilometer traveled that began in most OECD countries in the early 1970's and has continued to the present. Table 1. CIsaimge ann Tlrafn IFatifty Rate (DDeaths/10O,O0O IPersonos), 1975-1990 % Chnage 1% Chabnge Country (675-'90) j Counntry (75 -!2 Canada -63.4% alaysia 44.3% on Kong -61.7% diaA 79.3% Finland -59.8% ri Lanka 84.5% ustria -59.1% sotho 192.8% Sweden -58.3% olombia 237.1% [srael -49.7% China 243.0% Belgtum -43.8% Botswana"t 383.8% France -42.6% Italy* -36.7% New Zealand -33.2% Taiwan -32.0% United States -27.2% apan -24.5% *%change ('75-'97), *%/ochange ('76-'98), A%chage ('80-'98). These patterns are not surprising. The traffic fatality rate (fatalities/population) is the product of vehicles per person (V/P) and fatalities per vehicle (FN). How rapidly fatality risk grows depends, by definition, on the rate of growth in motorization (V/P) and the rate of change in fatalities per vehicle (F/V).' In most developing countries over the past 25 years, vehicle ownership grew more rapidly than fatalities per vehicle fell. The experience in industrialized countries, however, was the opposite; vehicles per person grew more slowly than fatalities per vehicle fell. From these observations, two questions emerge: Why did these patterns occur? and What trends can be expected in the future? To answer these questions we examine how the death rate (F/P) associated with traffic accidents and its components-V/P and F/V-change as countries grow. The, topic is of interest for two reasons. For planning purposes it important to forecast the growth in traffic fatalities. Equations relating F/P to per capita income can be used to 'The fatality rate may also be expressed as the product of fatalities per vehicle kilometers traveled (F/VKT) and distance traveled per person (VKT/P). Lack of reliable time-series VKT data, especially. for developing countries, prevents us from using this measure for our analysis. 2 predict traffic fatalities by region. These forecasts should alert policymakers to what is likely to happen if measures are not enacted to reduce traffic accidents. A second motive for our work comes from the literature on Environmental Kuznets Curves (Grossman and Krueger 1995). This literature examines the relationship between environmental externalities, such as air and water pollution, and economic growth. A focus of this literature has been in identifying the income levels at which externalities begin to decline. Road traffic fatalities are, indeed, an externality associated with motorization, especially in developing countries where pedestrians comprise a large share of casualties and motorists are often not insured. It is of interest to examine the income level at which the traffic fatality rate (F/P) historically has begun to decline and to compare this with the pattern observed for other externalities. We investigate these issues by estimating equations for the motor vehicle fatality rate (F/P), the rate of motorization (V/P) and fatalities per vehicle (F/V) using panel data from 1963-99 for 88 countries. We estimate fixed effects models in which the natural logarithm of F/P, V/P and F/V are expressed as (a) a quadratic function of ln(Y) and (b) a spline function of ln(Y), where Y = real per capita GDP (measured in 1985 international prices). Time trends during the period 1963-99 are modeled in four ways: (1) a common linear time trend; (2) a common log-linear time trend; (3) regional, linear time trends; and (4) regional, log-linear time trends. These models are used to project traffic fatalities and the stock of motor vehicles to 2020. Our main results are as follows. The per capita income at which the motor vehicle fatality rate begins to decline is in the range of incomes at which other externalities (specifically the common air pollutants) begin to decline-approximately 3 $6100 (1985 international dollars) when a common time trend is assumed for all countries and $8600 (1985 international dollars) when separate time trends are used for each geographic region. This turning point is driven by the rate of decline in F/V as income rises since V/P, while increasing with income at a decreasing rate, never declines with economic growth. Projections of future traffic fatalities suggest that the global road death toll will grow by approximately 66% over the next twenty years. This number, however, reflects divergent rates of change in different parts of the world: a decline in fatalities in high- income countries of approximately 28% versus an increase in fatalities of almost 92% in China and 147% in India. We also predict that the fatality rate will rise to approximately 2 per 10,000 persons in developing countries by 2020, while it will fall to less than 1 per 10,000 in high-income countries. The paper is organized at follows. Section II presents trends in fatality rates (F/P), motorization rates (VIP), and fatalities per vehicle (Fly) for various countries. Plots of each variable against per capita income motivate our econometric models. Section III describes the econometric models estimated and Section IV presents our projections of road traffic fatalities. Section V concludes. II. How Fatality Risk, Motorization Rates and Fatalities/Vehicle Vary Across (and Within) Countries Death rates (F/P) due to motor vehicle crashes are the product of the motorization rate (V/P) and fatalities per motor vehicle (FN). Before estimating statistical models relating these ratios to per capita income it is useful to examine data showing how these quantities vary with income both within and across countries. 4 It is widely recognized that the motorization rate rises with income (Ingram and Liu (1999), Dargay and Gately (1999), Button et al. (1993)), implying that one should find large differences in vehicles per capita across countries at different stages of development and within countries as per capita incomes grow. Table 2 presents data on motorization rates for various countries in 1999.2 Figure 1 plots the motorization rates for these countries against per capita income, pooling data from all countries and years, while Figure 2 shows how motorization rates have grown with income over time for a sample of countries. Table 2. Motorization Rates, 1999, 60 Countries Vehicles* Vehicles* Country /1,000 Persons Country /1,000 Persons HD] Countries: HD2 Countries: United States 779 Malaysia 451 Luxe ourg 685 Bulgaria 342 Japan 677 Thailand 280 Italy/ 658 Latvia 267 Iceland 629 Mauritius 195 Switzerland 622 Romania 169 Australia3 616 South Africa 144 Austria 612 Panama 112 Canada' 585 Turkey 100 Gen_nany_ 572 Indonesia 81 New Zealand 565 Sri Lanka' 74 Norway 559 Botswana 72 Cyprus 551 Swaziland' 69 Belgium 522 Colombia 67 Spain 499 Benin3 52 Finland 498 Morocco 51 Sweden' 496 Ecuador' 47 Czechoslovakia 440 Philippines' 42 2`The data in Table 2 and Figure I are displayed according to development status. Observations for countries with a UN Human Development Index (HDI) less than 0.8 are denoted as "HD2" and countries with an HDI value greater than 0.8 are labeled as "HD ". 5 United Kingdom' 434 Togo3 39 Netherlands 427 Mongolia 38 Denmark 424 Egyptt 335 portugal2 423 India 34 Bahrain 339 Nigeria3 29 Poland 323 Pakistan 23 Ireland3 312 ena3 14 Israel 301 Senegal 14 Korea, Rep. 296 anglad esh 3.1 Hungary 283 Ethiopia 1.5 Singapore 164 Costa Rica 162 Chile 138 Hong Kong 80 *Including passenger cars, buses, trucks, and motorized two-wheelers. 1- 1998 data,2- 1997 data,3- 1996 data. Figure 1. Motorlzation Rate vs. lincoamie: AIR Counmtries samid Years 8,000 - Ic%5 i�0 0 0 O o 0 c 0 E 6,000- 0 0 O' 4,000 - E oo a � HD2 Obsevtios ; 2,000 0 00000 0 0 0 0 e 0 0 0 0 00c~~0 0~ I I 0 I o I O srain 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 Per Capita GDP, 1985 int'l$ The cross-sectional variation in motorization rates in Table 2 is striking. Vehicles per capita range from a high of 780 per 1,000 persons in the United States to fewer than 30 per 1,000 persons in countries such as Pakistan and Nigeria. High-income countries 6 tend to have more vehicles per capita than lower income countries but there are important exceptions. Low motorization rates in Hong Kong, Singapore, Chile, and Costa Rica are notable outliers. Figure 1, which plots data on V/P for all countries and years in the dataset, suggests that, overall, motorization is strongly correlated with income. The within-group variation in motorization varies from country to country, however, as shown in Figure 2. Growth in vehicle ownership appears to have slowed down (but not declined) in many high-income countries such as Norway, Australia, Hong Kong, and the United States. In countries experiencing lower levels of per capita GDP such as Greece, Malaysia, and Thailand, however, vehicle fleets have continued to expand rapidly with income in recent decades. 7 Figure 2. Motorization Rates vs. I[ncone: Selected Conuiatries 0 Greece a Korea, Rep. of D United States + Hong Kong O Norway o Ausahlia Taiwan, Province of China 8000 7000 - 6000 - 5000 d 4000- VP . 3000 - 2000- 1000 - 0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000 18,000 21,000 Per Capita GDP, 1985 intl$ o Mauritius A Thailand O Turkey + Botswana O Malaysia o Sri Lanka 4500 - 4000 - 3500 - E 3000 - 2500- 2000- *~1500- 0 - 500 2,000 3,500 5,000 6,500 8,000 Per Capita GDP, 1985 inels Fatalities per vehicle, by contrast, appear to decline steadily with income, at least after some low level of income, and then reach a floor. Both Figure 3, which plots the fatality rate (FlV) against income using data for all countries and years, and Figure 4, which shows how F/V has changed with income over time for a sample of countries, 3 attest to this fact. In part, the sharp decline in F/V with income reflects the fact that, as income rises, a higher percentage of travelers are vehicle passengers rather than pedestrians, and thus, are less likely to die in the event of a crash.4 It also may reflect the move to safer vehicles (e.g., from two-wheelers to four-wheelers), safer roads, and/or changing attitudes toward risk as incomes grow. Figure 3. Fatalities/Vehicle vs. Income: All Countries and Years 250 - A 200 - 0 HD I Observations A HD2 Observations 150 o 1100- 50 - .. :. 0 0 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 Per Capita GDP, 1985 int'l$ 3The fatality figures used in Figures 3 and 4 have not been adjusted for underreporting of road deaths. Thus, FN levels in developing countries may be underestimated. 4This point was first publicized by Smeed (1949), who demonstrated that F/V declines as V/P increases. 9 igre 4. lFatalities/Vehiclle v. Ilcome: Selected Coununtries o Grce A United States [ Hong Kong + Norway 0 Australia o Taiwan, Provmce of China 40 - 30 - ,20 320- 10 1-A 0 2,000 8,000 14,000 20,000 Per Capita GDP, 1985 inf 1$ o Bangladesh A Egypt 0 Uganda + Ethiopia C Monjcoc o India Turkey 0 Mauntrus A Mlaysia 0 Komea, Rep. of 250 - 200 - ~ 150 *~100 50 0 0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 10,600 Per Capita GDP, 1985 int?l$ 1 0 The foregoing data suggest that one would expect to see the motor vehicle fatality rate (F/P) first increase and then decrease with income. Figure 5, which plots of F/P versus income for all years and countries in our dataset, supports this inverted U-shaped pattern. As incomes grow and vehicle fleets increase during initial stages of development, traffic fatality rates tend to worsen. At higher income levels, however, as growth in motorization slows and governments and individuals invest more in road safety, the decline in F/V drives the fatality rate (F/P) down. Figure 5. Traffic Fatality Rate vs. Income: All Countries and Years 4 o o 0 o HDI Observations &L 0 0 � � HD2 Observations 3 - 0it ADpO O4F 0 % 00,& * 00ccP:r4So 0~~~ a 00 �o 70 0 0 3 q 0 0 00 0 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~'~0 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 Per Capita GDP, 1985 int'l$ m. Statistical Models of Fatalities, Vehicle Ownership and Economic Growth A. Models of Fatalities per Person In fitting statistical models to the data on fatality risk we employ models of the general form: (1) ln(F/P)it = ai + G(t) + FTln(Yit)] + sit where F/P = Fatalities/10,000 Persons, Y = Real Per Capita GDP (measured in 1985 international prices), as is a country-specific intercept, and G and F are functions. Two specific forms of F are used, a quadratic specification (equation (2)) and a spline (piecewise linear) specification (equation (3)): (2) ln(F/P)it = ai + G(t) + b Inyit + c (lnYi02 + Fit (3) ln(F/P)it = ai + G(t) + b lnYit + Ys [csDs(lnYit - lnYs)] + Sit where D. is a dummy variable = 1 if Yit is in income category s+1, and Y. is the cutoff income value between the s and s+I income group. Following Schmalensee et al. (2000), we divide the observations into 10 income groups with an equal number of observations in each spline segment. Four different forms of G(t) are used: (1) a common linear time trend; (2) a common log-linear time trend (In t); (3) regional, linear time trends; and (4) regional, log- linear (In t) time trends. For purposes of defining time trends, we divide countries into two groups: highly developed countries (HD 1)-i.e., countries that have a Human Development Index in 1999 of 0.8 or greater-and all other countries (HD2).5 In practice, this division of countries (shown in detail in the Appendix) corresponds closely 5 The United Nations Human Development Index measures per capita income, life expectancy and educational achievement. 12 to highly-motorized countries versus other countries. All HD1 countries are treated as a single region for the purposes of computing time trends. HD2 countries, in turn, are classified according to region. Table 3 shows the number of countries in each geographic region, for both HD1 and HD2 countries. Table 3. Regional Distribution of Countries Used in Model Estimation WB Region HD2 HD1 East Asia & Pacific 10 1 E. Europe & Central Asia 5 3 Latin America & Caribbean 5 2 Middle East & North Africa 8 1 South Asia 5 _ Sub-Saharan Africa 20 High-Income Countries 28 Total: 53 35 The inclusion of country-specific intercepts in equation (1) implies that the impact of income on the fatality rate will reflect within- rather than between-country variation in ln(F/P) and ln(Y). This is desirable for two reasons. For the purposes of predicting future trends in F/P it is more desirable to rely on within-country experience rather than on largely cross-sectional variation in income and fatality risk. Using only cross-country variation to predict the future pattern of traffic fatalities is equivalent to saying that once Indonesia reaches the income level of Greece, its road safety record will mirror that of Greece. The second reason is that countries differ in their definition of what constitutes a traffic death and in the percentage of deaths that are reported. (This topic is discussed more fully in Section IV.) To the extent that the degree of under-reporting remains 13 constant over time but varies across countries it will not affect estimates of the impact of economic growth on fatality risk.6 Equations (2) and (3) are estimated using panel data for 88 countries for the period 1963-99. To be included in the dataset a country must have at least 10 years of data on traffic fatalities. Table A. 1 in the Appendix lists the countries used to estimate the models and the number of years of data that are available for each country. The data on traffic fatalities used in this study come primarily from the International Road Federation Yearbooks, which have been supplemented by and cross-checked against various other sources. The sources of traffic fatality and all other data are described in the Appendix. B. Empirical Results Table 4 summarizes the results of estimating the 8 models formed by combining the quadratic and spline functions with 4 methods of treating time trends. (Complete regression results are displayed in Table A.2. in the Appendix.) The table shows the income level at which F/P first begins to decline as well as the time coefficients for each model. To give a more complete picture of the model results, Figures 6 and 7 plot F/P as a function of per capita income.7 Figure 6 shows the quadratic and spline models with a common linear time trend while Figure 7 plots the quadratic and spline models with region-specific log-linear time trends. 6 To illustrate, when equation (2) is estimated using country-specific intercepts, the coefficients b and c reflect within-country variation in fatalities and income. Multiplying country i's fatality rate by a constant to reflect under-reporting would not change the estimates of b and c. 7In both figures, F/P results are displayed using the country intercept for India with the time trend set equal to 1999. 14 Table 4. Reg ession Results from Fatalities/Population Models QuSadratic _S_ine _ _Pot 1 2- 3 4 5 6 7 8 Turing Point $5,385 $4,825 $10,784 $5,738 $6,095 $6,095 $8,592 $8,592 (1985$int'l) 9o% C.I.: [$4977, [$4489, [$8644, [$5141, 95/o%C.I.: $5826] $5186] $13455] $6403] Common time -0.0010 0.0346* 0.0013 0.0555* trend, t: (0.0010) (0.0123) (0.0010) (0.0122) Regional ts: EAP 0.0054 0.2377* 0.0065* 0.2573* (0.0029) (0.0417) (0.0029) (0.0416) ECA . -0.0100* 0.0162 -.0126* -0.0305 (0.0032) (0.0399) (0.0032) (0.0403) India 0.0194* 0.2789* 0.0225* 0.3189* (0.0048) (0.0591) (0.0048) (0.05 79) LAC 0.0145* 0.3100* 0.0120* 0.2639* (0.0032) (0.0625) (0.0032) (0.0615) MNA -0.0093* -0.0301 -.0067* 0.0106 (0.0023) (0.0301) (0.0025) (0.0324) SA -0.0015 0.0361 0.0041 0.0956* (0.0031) (0.0389) (0.0032) (0.0388) SSA 0.0101* 0.1468* 0.0106* 0.1609* (0.0013) (0.0191) (0.0013) (0.0186) High Income -0.0191* -.0783* -.0154* -.0567* (0.0016) (0.0177) (0.0017) (0.0176) Significant at the 95% confidence level. Standard Errors are given in parentheses. 8 Model Specifications: 1. Quadratic, common linear time trend 2. Quadratic, commnon log-linear time trend 3. Quadratic, regional linear time trends 4. Quadratic, regional, log-linear time trends 5. Spline, common linear time trend 6. Spline, common log-linear time trend 7. Spline, regional linear time trends 8. Spline, regional, log-linear time trends Several results are worth emphasizing. The income levels at which the fatality rate first declines are higher when region-specific time trends are included in the models rather than a common-time trend. For example, F/P begins to decline at approximately $8600 in the spline models with region-specific time trends but at approximately $6100 in the spline models with a common time trend. This reflects the fact that, in many 15 developing countries, fatality risk over the period 1963-99 grew faster than could be explained by income growth alone. Because the region-specific time trends are jointly significant, we believe that more emphasis should be placed on these models than on models with a common time trend. Whether the time trend enters the models linearly or in log-linear form, the differences in trends across regions are generally similar. Over the estimation period (1963-99) the fatality rate grew fastest in India and in Latin America (LAC) (holding income constant), and almost as fast in Sub-Saharan Africa as in LAC. By contrast, (holding income constant) F/P declined in high-income countries. Results for other regions are statistically insignificant in at least some specifications. Figure 6. Fatalities/Populadom Results, Commnioim Linear Tlime Tremd 1.8 l Quadratic, 1.6 commonT 1.4 Spline, { 1.2 1 g \' ' commonT 0 1.2 U0.8 ~0.6 0.4 0.2 0 200 4,200 8,200 12,200 16,200 20,200 24,200 28,200 Per Capita GDP (1985 $inf1) 16 Figure 7. Fatalities/Population Results, Log-Linear Regional Time Trends 1.8- 1.8 -Quadratic, 1.6 ln(regionarr) 1.4 - Spine, 1.2 //\i(regionanl) 1.2 0.8 g 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 200 4,200 8,200 12,200 16,200 20,200 24,200 28,200 Per Capita GDP (1985 Sint'l) It is also clear from examining Figures 6 and 7 that the relationship between per capita income and the fatality rate is quite similar (holding the treatment of time constant) whether one uses the quadratic or spline function. When a common time trend is assumed F/P begins to decline at an income of $5,400 using the quadratic specification. and at an income of $6,100 with the spline model. When region-specific, log-linear time trends are included F/P begins to decline at an income of $5,700 in the quadratic model and at an income of $8,600 in the-spline model. In both figures, the two models are almost identical at low levels of income; however, the fatality rate peaks at a higher level of income in the spline model and falls faster than in the quadratic model after it peaks. In the Kuznets Curve literature it is standard practice to focus on the income level at which the externality in question begins to decline. The usual interpretation is that, if a 17 country follows historical trends, the problem in question will eventually lessen once per capita income reaches this turning point. Because the spline is a more flexible functional form, we focus on the spline results in Table 4. The income levels at which fatalities per person peak in the spline models, $6100 and $8600 (1985 international dollars) are within the range of incomes at which Kuznets curves for common air and water pollutants peak (Grossman and Krueger 1995). To better understand why this occurs, in the next sections we examine models similar to those in Table 4 for the two components of fatalities per person-vehicles per person and fatalities per vehicle. C. Models of Vehicles per Person Models for vehicles per person (V/P) are summarized in Table 5 and Figure 8. Table 5 shows how motorization (V/P) varies with income in the both the quadratic and spline models. Our discussion, however, focuses on the spline models. Figure 8 plots the four spline models using the country intercept for India, with the time trend set equal to 1999. Of the four spline models in Table 5, only two (Models 6 and 8) show vehicles per person increasing with per capita income at a decreasing rate for all relevant values of per capita income. This result occurs when time is entered in a log-linear fashion; when it enters the motorization equation linearly, V/P peaks at a value of income observed in the data, and the time trend associated with vehicle ownership is large and positive. The log- linear time trend thus seems to yield more reasonable results than the linear. Of the two models with log-linear time trends, only the model with regional log-linear time trends 18 yields non-negative income elasticities for all levels of income; hence we focus on this model. Figure 8. Vehicles/Population Results, Spline-Model 300 .h(regionarr) __ , . I~~n(ca6umonT) 250 -conunonT regionalT 200- 10 10 , 150 4w100- 50 $200 $4,200 $8,200 $12,200 $16,200 $20,200 S24,200 $28,200 Per Capita GDP (1985 $iit<D Notes for Table 5: Standard Errors are given in parentheses. The constant term reflects the intercept terrn for India. Country fixed effects were included in all regressions but are not displayed here. i Asterisks indicate significance at the 95% confidence level. Model Specifications: 1. Quadratic, common linear time trend 2. Quadratic, common log-linear time trend 3. Quadratic, regional linear time trends 4. Quadratic, regional, log-linear time trends 5. Spline, common linear time trend 6. Spline, common log-linear time trend 7. Spline, regional linear time trends 8. Spline, regional, log-linear time trends '19 -'rable S. Regi iessonm IResults firon VehAcRes/PopunI om Models Independent S__dratic Spline Variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 5.52280 5.0464� 3.0785� 3.0826� LnY (0.2120) (0.2301) (0.2976) (0.3042) -0.28600 -0.2407� -0.1420� -0.1242� (lnYit)2 (0.0129) (0.0138) (0.0182) (0.0183) InY for: 0.8569� 0.95510 0.4247� 0.1899 $1 - $946 (0.1281) (0.1473) (0.1239) (0.1471) $946 - $1,535 1.4314� 1.7748� 0.9087� 1.6752� (0.1Q020) (0.1149) (0.1088) (0.1168) $1,535 - $2,290 0.67480 1.0435� 0.7078� 1.0849� (0.1 027) (0.1157) (0.1139) (0.1258) $2,290 - $3,441 1.3786� 1.50830 0.88250 1.0385� (0.1115) (0.1285) (0.1127) (0.1332) 1.2179� 1.57020 1.1359� 1.5656� $3,441 - $4,682 (0.1347) (0.1524) (0.1250) (0.1426) 0.80520 1.14380 0.8378� 1.18700 $4,682 - $6,911 (0.1025) (0.1156) (0.0955) (0.1081) $6,911 -$9,238 0.56910 0.59490 0.68830 0.82230 (0.1267) (0.1462) (0.1193) (0.1399) $9,238-$11,263 -0.43590 -0.0216 -0.33670 0.1884 .9,238-$1 1,263 (0.1756) (0.1999) (0.1663) (0.1902) $11,263-13,663 -0.71420 0.2125 -0.55040 0.4123� (0.1750) (0.1941) (0.1693) (0.1835) -0.61190 0.0978 .0.5092* 0.1897 >____________ $13,663 _______ (0.1477) (0.1650) (0.1396) (0.1540) Tuming Point $15,587 $35,723 $51,179 $244117 $9,238 $9,238 (1 985$int'l) 95% C.I.: [$12995, ($26690, ($24,687, [$71,420, 9S%___ C.I.:___$18,696] $47,813] $106099] $834411] Common time 0.0281 0 0.2358� 0.03220 0.263 10 trend: t (0.0010) (0.0132) (0.0010) (0.0130) Regional t: 0.05390 0.55870 0.05820 0.59900 EAP (0.002 7) (0.0417) (0.0026) (0.0418) ECA 0.05970 0.54000 0.0559� 0.5046� (0.0031) (0.0389) (0.0030) (0.0400) India 0.06570 0.66190 0.07470 0.73310 (0.0039) (0.0501) (0.003 7) (0.0483) LAC 0.02560 0.21840 0.02340 0.20170 (0.0042) (0.0574) (0.0040) (0.0572) 0.01570 0.04490 0.02010 0.0358 MNA (0.0029) (0.0368) (0.0030) (0.0385) SA 0.03590 0.25470 0.04060 0.24680 (0.0027) (0.0365) (0.0027) (0.0361) SSA 0.02900 0.31190 0.03040 0.35290 (0.0014) (0.0202) (0.0013) (0.0196) 0.02150 0.16040 0.02920 0.19770 High Income _______ (0.0014) (0.0168) (0 0014) (0.0168) F statistic on F8,1791 = F8,1791 = F8,1783 = F8,1783= regional ts: 151.15 80.03 202.95 96.64 -20.6880 -19.6750 -11.3780 -12.8060 -2.28720 -3.10380 -0.0692 0.8421 Constant (0.8645) (0.9430) (1.1 795) (1.2143) (0.8586) (0.9835) (08261) (0.9753) Adjusted R2: 0.9783 0.9742 0.9818 0.9775 0.9820 0.9767 0.9849 0.9799 No. of Countries: 75, No. of observations: 1876 20 In the preferred model, Model 8, the income elasticity of vehicle ownership attains a maximum value of 1.67 in the second spline segment ($946 - $1,535 (1985 intemational dollars)) and decreases to a low of 0.18 in the highest income category. Above the lowest income category, income elasticities in income categories 2 through 5 are significantly higher than income elasticities in income categories 7 to 10.8 These results are broadly consistent with previous studies of motorization, which find that the income elasticity of demand for motor vehicles declines with income (Ingram and Liu (1998), Dargay and Gately (1999), Button et al. (1993)). Figure 8 suggests that the rate of increase in motorization slows down considerably after reaching a per capita income of $9400 (1985 international dollars), the level of income attained by Norway and the United Kingdom in 1974. D. Models for Fatalities per Vehicle Table 6 and Figure 9 confirm that fatalities per vehicle decline sharply with income. Focusing once again on the spline models with log-linear time trends, F/V declines with income for per capita GDP in excess of $1,180 (1985 international dollars) when either common or regional log-linear time trends are used. Figure 9, which plots the four spline models for India (t = 1999) indicates exactly how fast F/V declines as income grows. Fatalities per vehicle decline by a factor of 3 (e.g., from 360 to 120 per 100,000 vehicles for India) as per capita income grows from $1200 to $4400. After reaching a per capita income of $15,200 (1985 international dollars), however, F/V 8Income elasticity estimates generated from a two-segment spline model are statistically different from each other, decreasing from 1.32 (0.05)) to 0.719 (0.052) once per capita income exceeds $4,682 (1985 international dollars). 21 Tab1Re 6. Regressoim IResults froim ]FaUallles/Vehinees ModeRs Independent Quadratic Spline Variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 2.3796� 3.0043� 2.2926� 3.0550� LnY (0.2509) (0.2915) (0.3829) (0.4240) j0.1612� -0.2313� -0.1458� -0.23400 (lnYit)2 (0.0151) (0.0173) (0.023 1) (0.0252) InY for: 0.6190� 0.30240 1.05170 0.6548� $1-$1,179 (0.1167) (0.1372) (0.1268) (0.1551) $1,179-$1,730 -0.2292 -0.9258* -0.50220 -1.52270 (0.1468) (0.1697) (0.1585) (0.1867) $1 ,730-$2,698 0.2538 -0.2607 0.44620 -0.2433 (0.1334) (0.1552) (0.1426) (0.1 71 1) $2,698-$3.813 0.5814� -1.09520 -0.0908 -0.83210 $2,698-$3,813 (0.1485) (0.1 751) (0.1519) (0.1834) $3,8 1 3-$5,39 1 -0.3880� .0.93400 -0.1747 -0.87270 (0.1415) (0.1640) (0.1359) (0.1620) $5,391-$7,532 -0.55500 -1.00290 .0.4913� 1.03570 (0.1447) (0.1686) (0.1391) (0.1668) -0.6347� .0.94440 .0.3684� -0.8750� (0.1745) (0.2075) (0.1697) (0.2083) $9,614-$11,469 -0.28262- .. 19764 0.0859 ;1.14072 (0.242)) (0.2824) (0.2354) (0.2810) $11,469-13,682 -0.4438 -1.8455� 0.0051 -1.79770 (0.2363) (0.2690) (0.2333) (0.2664) >$13,682 -0.2782 -1.2485� 0.0143 -1.2226� >$____________ ,______ ________ (0.1905) (0.2185) (0.1855) (0.2151) Turing Point $1,603 $661 $2,593 $683 $2,698 $1,179 $2,698 $1,179 (1985$int'l) 95% C.Il: [$1,189, [$475, [$1,859, [$440, . $2,161] $920] $3,616] $1,061] Conmon time -0.03700 -0.23350 -0.03860 -0.22850 trend: t (0.0013) (0.0170) (0.0013) (0.0176) Reaional t: 0.05120 -0.26610 -0.0561 0 -0.28260 EAP (0.0034) (0.0540) (0.0034) (0.0560) ECA -0.0671 0 -0.44160 .0.06980 -0.46090 (0.0036) (0.0487) (0.0038) (0.0522) India 0.0445* -0.355 1 �0.0536� .0.44160 Indla (0.0049) (0.0686) (0.0050) (0.0701) LAC .0.01230 -0.0219 -0.0127� -0.0142 (0.0060) (0.1362) (0.0061) (0.138 7) -0.0268� -0.0503 -0.0234� 0.0922 MNA (0.0035) (0.0490) (0.0039) (0.0543) SA -0.0392� .0.19250 �0.03750 -0.1230� (0.0033) (0.0462) (0.0035) (0.04 73) SSA -0.02890 -0.25270 -0.02840 -0.23650 (0.0020) (0.0311) (0.0019) (0.0306) High Income -0.04240 -0.22930 .0.04700 -0.24500 High Incorne (0.0017) (0.0215) (0.0018) (0.0223) F statistic on Fg,1615 = Fs,161s= F8,1607= F8,1607= regional ts: 132.45 29.78 140.67 31.56 -11.1050 .12.1660 .11.0920 -12.0550 -6.58290 -4.51750 -9.24310 -6.32740 Constant (1.0305) (1.2035) (1.5275) (1.7003) (0.7967) (0.9333) (0.8365) (1.0105) Adjusted R2: 0.9532 0.9363 0.9569 0.9377 0.9540 0.9368 0.9588 0.9394 No. of Countries: 70, No. of observations: 1695 22 declines very slowly in absolute terms: from 25 per 100,000 vehicles at an income of $20,000 to 15 per 100,000 vehicles at an income of $30,000. Figure 9. Fatalities/Vehicle Results, Spline Models 400 - In(regionarl) 350 - _ - In(commnT) comnmonT >300 - regionalT 250 - C1200-IN 150- o2 50 50 $200 $4,200 $8,200 $12,200 $16,200 $20,200 $24,200 $28,200 Per Capita Income (1985 $infl) Combining the results of model 8 for F/V and for V/P explains the results for deaths per capita observed in Figure 7. The elasticity of V/P with respect to income exceeds in absolute value the elasticity of F/V with respect to income for incomes up to the $7,000-$9,000 interval, when the two elasticities are approximately equal-the condition for (FNV)*(V/P) to peak.9 At higher incomes, the elasticity of fatalities per vehicle with respect to income exceeds the elasticity of motorization with respect to income. 9 This comparison is approximate since the width of the income intervals differs in Tables 5 and 6. 23 IV. Predictions of Future Traffic Fatalities and Motorization One reason for estimating the preceding models is to predict what will happen to traffic fatalities if historic trends continue. Future traffic fatalities can be predicted directly from equation (1); i.e., by predicting future fatality rates (F/P) and multiplying by estimates of future population, or by predicting vehicle ownership, V, from the V/P equation and multiplying the vehicle stock by fatalities per vehicle. The second method serves as a check on the first since more is known about vehicle ownership. In particular, one can reject models that yield unbelievably high rates of vehicle ownership; e.g., ownership significantly in excess of one vehicle per person in the year 2020. To project future vehicle ownership and traffic fatalities assumptions must be made about income and population growth. The real per capita GDP series is projected to 2020 using the World Bank's forecasts of regional growth rates (2000-2010) (Global Economic Prospects 2002) with the assumption that the average annual 2001-2010 growth rates continue to 2020. (A list of the growth rates is provided in Appendix Table A.3.) Population projections are taken from the U.S. Census International Data Base. In total, the explanatory variables are available for 156 countries (representing 92% of total world population in 2000), including 45 highly developed countries (HD 1) and Ill developing countries (HD2). Table 7 shows the number of countries in each geographic region for which predictions are made. 24 Table 7. Regional Distribution of Countries for Which Predictions are Made WB Region HD2 HD1 East Asia & Pacific 14 1 E. Europe & Central Asia 5 4 Latin America & Caribbean 27 4 Middle East & North Africa 12 1 South Asia 7 Sub-Saharan Africa 46 High-Income Countries 35 Total: 111 45 To calculate the point estimates for the out-of-sample countries, assumptions must be made regarding the country-specific intercept. The coefficient on the country dummy variable for Chile is used to compute the predicted values for the 10 out-of-sample HDI countries.'0 For the HD2 countries, the intercept is set equal to the mean of the country intercepts for the corresponding region. A. Projections of the World Vehicle Fleet to 2020 We begin by examining the implications of the models in Table 5 for future growth in vehicle ownership. Figure 10 displays projections of the vehicle fleet corresponding to all 8 models in Table 5. Not surprisingly, it is the form of the time trend, rather than the choice between the spline and quadratic specifications, that makes the greatest difference in the projections. Both the spline and quadratic models with linear regional time trends yield unbelievably large estimates of the world motor vehicle stock in 2020, as well as estimates of vehicle ownership per capita for certain groups of countries that are well over 1. For this reason we focus on the spline models with log- '� The choice of Chile is motivated by the fact that the most populous out-of-sample HD1 countries for which predictions must be made are Argentina and Uruguay. 25 linear time trends. The model with region-specific log-linear time trends (Model 8) generates forecasts of 1.47 billion vehicles in 2020, whereas the vehicle stock is predicted to be over 1.37 billion vehicles when a common log-linear time trend is used (Model 6)." IFigure 10. World Vehicle leet 1Projecdons Correspoimdalmg to Models iAmD Tlable 5 3,500 - l Model I 3,000 - X b ~~~~~~~-CModel 2 3,000 - Model 3 t < 2< ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~:Model 4 2,500 - Model 5 EB 2,000 - ~~~~~~~~~~~~Model 6 ~32,000- 1,500 - 1,000 -..'"''' 500 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 The predictions of these models agree fairly well with other estimates of vehicle growth in the literature. Dargay and Gately (1999) project that the total vehicle fleet in OECD countries will reach 705 million by 2015 (a 62% increase from 1992 values). The sphne model (with the common time trend or the log-linear regional time trends) yields a 2015 estimate of 687 million vehicles for the same group of countries. l The corresponding quadratic models give almost identical vehicle projections but we continue to focus on the more flexible spline specifications. 26 Other studies have made projections of vehicle growth for the automobile fleet only or for passenger cars and commercial vehicles. Since our motor vehicle counts include all buses and two-wheelers, direct comparisons with these studies is difficult. However, our estimates of the total vehicle fleet do exceed their automobile forecasts under all specifications. Under Schafer's (1998) results, the global automobile fleet would more than double from 470 million in 1990 (this includes light trucks for personal travel in the U.S.) to 1.0-1.2 billion automobiles in 2020. This amnounts to a 113%-155% increase in total automobiles. The spline model with log-linear regional time trends generates a 140% increase in the total vehicle fleet during the same period (from 609 million to 1.47 billion total vehicles). Because it yields reasonable predictions of the vehicle fleet, as well as reasonable income elasticity estimates, we focus on the spline model with regional, log-linear time trends. B. Projections of World Traffic Fatalities to 2020 Figure 11 shows predictions of road traffic fatalities for all countries to the year 2020, based on the spline model with log-linear regional time trends. Ninety-five percent confidence levels for our predictions also appear on the graph.12 We emphasize that these figures represent traffic fatalities unadjusted for under-reporting. To compare these figures with fatality rates from other causes of death, it is necessary to adjust for the fact that (a) the definition of what constitutes a traffic fatality differs across countries and (b) the percentage of traffic fatalities reported by the police also varies across countries. '2The model generates point estimates of the log of the fatality rate (ln(Fatalities/10,000 People)). Therefore, the confidence intervals for the predicted values of In(Fatalities/10,000 People) are symmnetric, but the forecast intervals for the total number of fatalities are not. 27 Figure 11. GDobalR oadT lraffi Fatalities, 1Before Adjusdtlg for Uideir-Reportng, 1990-2020 Estimated Number of Traffic Fatalities C: � Lower Bound of 95% Forecast Interval Upper Bound of 95% Forecast Interval 1,400,000 - 1,200,000 - 1,000,000- 800,000 - 600,000 - = = - 400,000- C - 200,000 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 Our under-reporting adjustments follow the conservative factors used by Jacobs, Aeron-Thomas and Astrop (2000).13 To update all point estimates to the 30-day traffic fatality definition, a correction factor of 1. 15 was applied in the developing countries and the standard ECMT correction factors were used for the high-income countries.14 Then the estimates were adjusted to account for general under-reporting of traffic fatalities, by 25% in developing countries and by 2% in highly developed countries.15 With these adjustments, global road deaths are projected to climb to over 1.2 million by 2020 (a 40% adjustment over the base estimate of 864,000 presented in Figure 11). Although this '3Jacobs et al. reviewed numerous underreporting studies and found evidence of underreporting rates ranging from 0-26% in high motorized countries and as high as 351% in less motorized countries. Fatalities in China, for example, were 42% higher in 1994 than reported in official statistics (Liren 1996). 14 High-Income countrnes with ECMT correction factors greater than 1 include: France: 1.057, Italy: 1.07, Portugal: 1.3, Japan: 1.3 (ECMT 1998, 2000,2001). 15 The 25% under-reporting adjustment is applied to 111 HD2 countries and the 2% adjustment is used for 45 HD 1 countries. See Table 7 for regional breakdown of countries. 28 represents a 66% increase over the 2000 world estimate, the trend varies considerably across different regions of the world. Table 8 and Figure 12 indicate that, between 2000 and 2020, fatalities are projected to increase by over 80% in developing countries, but decrease by nearly 30% in high-income countries. Witiin the developing world, the greatest percentage increases in traffic deaths between 2000 and 2020 will occur in South Asia (144% increase), followed by East Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa (both showing an 80�% increase). It is also interesting to note that the number of traffic fatalities per 100,000 persons is predicted to diverge considerably by 2020. By 2020 the fatality rate is predicted to be less than 8 in 100,000 in high-income countries but nearly 20 in 100,000 in low-income countries. Table 8. Predicted Road Traffic Fatalities by Region (OOOs), Adjusted for Under- Repor1ing, 19902020 Fatality Rate (Deaths/100,000 Persons) No. of % change Region* Countries 1990 2000 2010 2020 'O-'20 2000 2020 EAP 15 112 188 278 337 79.8% 10.9 16.8 ECA 9 30 32 36 38 18.2% 19.0 21.2 LAC 31 90 122 154 180 48.1% 26.1 31.0 A 13 41 56 73 94 67.5% 19.2 22.3 A 7 87 135 212 330 143.9% 10.2 18.9 SA 46 59 80 109 144 79.8% 12.3 14.9 Subtotal. 121 419 613 862 1,124 83.3% 13.3 19.0 High Income Countries: 35 123 110 95 80 -27.8% 11.8 7.8 World Total: 156 542 723 957 1,204 66.4% 13.0 17.4 *The results are displayed according to the World Bank regional classifications. 29 FiAgure 12. GilobaD Tlraefc Fatalities, Adjusted for Unideir-Reportnmg, 1990-2020 1,400,000 -Z High Income 1,200,000 - OSSA 1,000,000 - 0 MNA 800,000 - iECA , l O ~~~~EAP 600,000 400,000 ,q,, , 200,000 0 . -l ....... r-''''+_- -' 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 The forecasts presented here are significantly lower than the 1990-2020 estimates of road traffic fatalities presented by the World Health Organization in The Global Burden of Disease (GBD) (Murray and Lopez 1996). WHO estimates that 1.39 million people will die in road traffic accidents in 2000 and that 2.34 million will die in 2020. The reason for the higher figures is that WHO starts from a higher base (999,000 deaths in 1990). In part, the high GBD base estimate for 1990 may be due to severe data limitations in developing regions. For example, 1990 estimates for the entire Sub- Saharan Africa region were based on data from South Africa only (Cooper et al. 1997, Jacobs et al. 2000). South Africa has by far the highest reported fatality rate (F/P) of nearly 20 SSA countries for which we have 1990 data. Even after adjusting predicted values for non-reporting and under-reporting of fatalities, our SSA estimate is 59,150 deaths for 1990 whereas the GBD baseline is 155,000 for the same year. Despite such 30 large differences between our base estimates and theirs, Murray and Lopez predict that global traffic fatalities will grow at approximately the same rate as the present projections. (Fatalities grow by 62% between 2000 and 2020 according to WHO and by 66% according to our estimates (see Table 8).) We believe that Murray and Lopez (1996) have over-estimated road traffic fatalities and stand behind the estimates presented here. One reason for this is that our estimate of fatalities in 2000 (723,439) agrees with the TRL estimate of global road deaths for 1999 (Jacobs et al. 2000), i.e., 745,769 fatalities worldwide (low under- reporting adjustment case). The TRL 1999 estimate is based on published 1996 data from 142 countries updated to 1999 levels and adjusted for non-reporting and under- reporting of fatalities. Since this seems to be the most comprehensive, bottom-up approach to estimating the global road death toll to date, we feel that it is the most appropriate estimate against which to compare our projections. Our prediction of traffic fatalities in 2020 (1.2 million deaths worldwide) also lies within the range suggested by TRL, for 2020 (1 to 1.3 million deaths), although the latter is not based on a statistical model. V. Conclusions The results presented above suggest that, if developing countries follow historic trends, it will take many years for them to achieve the motor vehicle fatality rates of high- income countries. Provided that present policies continue into the future, the traffic fatality rate of India, for example, will not begin to decline until 2042.16 (The projected 16 This assumes the annual real per capita GDP growth rate of 3.87% and India's log-linear time trend (from model 8) will continue into the future. 31 peak corresponds to approximately 24 fatalities per 100,000 persons prior to any adjustment for underreporting but becomes 34 fatalities per 100,000 persons if we maintain the underreporting adjustment factors chosen above.) This is primarily due to the fact that India's per capita income (in 1985 international dollars) was only $2,900 in 2000, whereas F/P peaks at a per capita income of approximately $8,600. Similarly, in Brazil F/P will not peak until 2032, and the model projects over 26 deaths per 100,000 persons as far out as 2050. In other developing countries, the traffic fatality rate will begin to decline before 2020 but F/P rates will still exceed the levels experienced in High-Income countries today (which average about 11 fatalities per 100,000 persons). Malaysia, for exaample, is estimated to have over 20 fatalities per 100,000 persons (after adjusting for underreporting) in 2020. If 5.1% growth continues beyond 2020, F/P will reach 11.1 by 2033 (using the same under-reporting adjustment as above); however, if the growth rate decreases to 2.5% after 2020, F/P will reach 11.0 only in 2049. The predictions in this paper, and the estimates of the income levels at which traffic fatality rates begin to decline, assume the policies that were in place from 1963 through 1999 will continue in the future. Clearly, this may not be the case. In many developing countries fatalities per vehicle could be reduced significantly through interventions that are not reflected in our data. For example, drivers of two-wheelers could be required to wear white helmets, traffic calming measures could be instituted in towns, and measures could be taken to separate pedestrian traffic from vehicular traffic. Whether such measures should be undertaken depends, of course, on their costs and their 32 effectiveness. The purpose of this paper has been to increase awareness of the nature and growing magnitude of the problem. 33 IReferences American Automobile Manufacturers Association. 1993. World Motor Vehicle Data 1993. Washington, D.C.: AAMA. Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics. National Data Bank. http://www.bbsgov.org/ . China Statistical Yearbook. (various years). State Statistical Bureau, People's Republic of China. Cooper, R.S., B. Osotimehim, J. Kaufman, and T. Forrester. 1998. Disease burden in sub- Saharan Africa: what should we conclude in the absence of data? The Lancet 351: 208-210. Cross National Time Series Database (CNTS). Access through Rutgers University Libraries. http://www.scc.rutgers.edu/cnts/about.cfm. Dargay, Joyce, and Dermot Gately. 1999. Income's effect on car and vehicle ownership, worldwide: 1960-2015. Transportation Research A 33:101-138. European Conference of Ministers of Transport. 2001. Statistical Report on Road Accidents 1997-1998. Paris: OECD Publications Service. European Conference of Ministers of Transport. 2000. Statistical Report on Road Accidents 1995-1996. Paris: OECD Publications Service. European Conference of Ministers of Transport. 1998. Statistical Report on Road Accidents 1993-1994. Paris: OECD Publications Service. Grossman, Gene and Alan Krueger. 1995. "Economic Growth and the Environment." Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(2): 675-708 Inter-American Development Bank. 1998. Review of Traffic Safety Latin America and Caribbean Region. Transport Research Laboratory and Ross Silcock. International Road Federation. Various Years. I.R.F. World Road Statistics. Geneva, Switzerland: International Road Federation. International Road Traffic Accident Database (IRTAD). Paris, France: Federal Highway Research Institute (BASt)/OECD Road Transport Research Programme. Israel National Road Safety Authority. 2000. The National Road Safety Authority Structure, Activities, & Responsibilities. State of Israel Ministry of Transport. Ingram, Gregory K., and Zhi Liu. 1998. Vehicles, Roads, and Road Use: Alternative Specifications. Working Paper 2036. World Bank. Jacobs, G, A. Aeron-Thomas, and A. Astrop. 2000. Estimating Global Road Fatalities. TRL Report 445. London, England: Transportation Research Laboratory. 34 Liren, D. 1996. Viewing China Road Traffic Safety and the Countermeasures in Accordance with International Comparison. Beijing Research in Traffic Engineering, Second Conference in Asian Road Safety, 28-31 October 1996. Murray, C. and A. Lopez (eds.). 1996. The Global Burden of Disease. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Press. Road Safety in Latin America and the Caribbean: Analysis of the Road Safety Situation in Nine Countries. Copenhagen, Denmark: Ministry of Transport Road Directorate, 1998. Schmalensee, Richard, Thomas M. Stoker, and Ruth A. Judson. 2000. World Carbon Dioxide Emissions: 1950-2050. Review of Economics and Statistics 80(1):15-27. Schafer, Andreas. 1998. The Global Demand for Motorized Mobility. Transportation Research A 32(6):455-477. Smeed, R. J. 1949. "Some Statistical Aspects of Road Safety Research." Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series A. 112:1-23. Statistical Economic and Social Research and Training Centre for Islamic Countries (SESRTCIC). Basic Socio-Economic Indicators Database (BASEIND). http://www.sesrtcic.orgldefaulteng.shtml. United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific. 1997. Asia- Pacific Road Accident Statistics and Road Safety Inventory. New York: United Nations. U.S. Census Bureau. International Data Base (IDB). http://www.census.gov/ipc/www/idbsprd.html World Bank. Global Development Network Growth Database Macro Time Series. http://www.worldbank.ora/research/lrowth/GDNdata.htm . World Bank. Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries 2002. http://www.worldbank.org/nrospects/gep2002/toc.htm World Resources Institute. 1998-1999. World Resources. Washington, D.C. http://www.wri.org/wr-98-99/autos.htrn. 35 VI. Appendix Data Sources Data on the number of traffic fatalities and vehicle fleet17 composition were taken from various editions of the International Road Federation's (IRF) World Road Statistics (WRS) annual yearbooks, 1968-2000. Since each WRS edition contains data for the previous five years, each series was compared across editions to check for accuracy and to ensure that all revisions were properly recorded. Selected IRF data were also compared to numerous regional and country-specific road safety studies. Supplementary data was added from several sources where appropriate, including studies published by the o Inter-American Development Bank (1998) o Danish Road Directorate (1998) o Transportation Research Laboratory (Jacobs et al. 2000) o United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (1997) o Statistical Bureau of the People's Republic of China o Ministry of Transport of Israel (2000) o European Conference of Ministers of Transport (ECMT) o Global Road Safety Partnership o OECD Intemational Road Traffic Accident Database (IRTAD) o Cross-National Time Series Database (CNTS) o Statistical Economic and Social Research and Training Centre for Islamic Countries (SESRTCIC) o Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics o American Automobile Manufacturers Association 7Vehicle counts include all passenger cars, buses, trucks, and motorized two-wheelers. 36 Population figures came from the U.S. Census Bureau's International Data Base and income data were taken from the World Bank Global Development Network Growth Database Macro Time Series. The income variable most appropriate for this analysis is the Real Per Capita GDP, chain method (1985 international prices) (RGDPCH), since it accounts for differences in purchasing power across countries and allows for comparisons over time.'8 i8This series was created from the Penn World Tables 5.6 RGDPCH variable for 1960-1992 and the 1992- 1999 data was estimated using the 1985 GDP per capita and GDP per capita growth rates from the Global Development Finance and World Development Indicators. 37 Table A.1. Classification of Countries for Which Fatalities Are Projected The number of observations for each country used to estimate the model is given in parentheses after the country name. Re-Rion _u_t_ Regon Countr| South Asia (SA) Latin America &Caribbean (LAC) HD2:Bangladesh (18) HDI:Argentina Bhutan Chile (34) India (27) Costa Rica (14) Maldives Uruguay Nepal (14, HD2:Antigua & Barbuda Pakistan (33) Belize Sri Lanka (34) Bolivia Brazil (16) East Asia & Pacific (EAP) Colombia (27) HDl:Korea, Rep. (29) Dominica HD2:China (22, Dom Republic Fiji (15, Ecuador (13) Indonesia (24, El Salvador Kiribati Grenada Lao PDR Guatemala Malaysia (37, Guyana Mongolia (14, Haiti Papua New Guinea (12, Honduras Philippines (18, Jamaica Samoa (13, Mexico Solomon Islands Nicaragua Thailand (28 Panama (16J Tonga (13) Paraguay Vanuatu Peru (1) Puerto Rico Middle East & N. Africa (MNA) St Kitts & Nevis HDI:Bahrain (12) SL Lucia HD2:Algeria St. Vincent & Grenadines Djibouti Suriname Egypt (I 1 Trinidad & Tobago Iran Venezuela Iaq (11, Jordan (32) Europe & Central Asia (ECA) Morocco (34, HDl:Czech Republic (28) Oman Hungary (33) Saudi Arabia (20, Poland (19) Syria (22, Slovak Republic Tunisia (26, HD2:Bulgaria (18) Yemen (12, Georgia Latvia (11) Romania (13) Turkey (34) Yugoslavia (20) 38 (Table A.l. continued) Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) High-Income OECD HD2:Angola HDI:Australia (31, Benin (23, Austria ( 37) Botswana (31, Belgium (36, Burkina Faso Canada (30, Burundi Denmark (37, Cameroon (17, Finland (37, Cape Verde France (37, Central African Republic Germany (30, Chad Greece (36, Comoros Iceland (35, Congo, Der. Rep. Ireland (31, Congo, Rep. Italy (35, Cote d'Ivoire (17, Japan (37 Equatorial Guinea Luxembourg (34, Ethiopia (30) Netherlands (37, Gabon New Zealand (37, Gambia, The Norway (37) Ghana Portugal (37, Guinea Spain (32, Guinea-Bissau Sweden (35) Kenya (27) Switzerland (36) Lesotho (21) United Kingdom (35, Liberia United States (36, Madagascar Malawi (28, Other High-Income Mali HDI:Bahamas Mauritania Barbados Mauritius (26) Bermuda Mozambique (12) Cyprus (30, Narnibia Hong Kong (36, Niger (24) Israel (32, Nigeria (15, Kuwait Rwanda Malta Sao Tome &Principe Qatar Senegal (19) Singapore (16, Seychelles Taiwan (25, Sierra Leone (17, U.A.E. Somalia South Africa (35) Sudan Swaziland (13) Tanzania Togo (16) Uganda (19) Zambia (13) Zimbabwe .1 (IS,__ Total: 156 Countries, 2,178 Country-year Observations 39 Notes for T1aDbe A.2: Standard Errors are given in parentheses. The constant term reflects the intercept term for India. Country fixed effects were included in all regressions but are not displayed here. Model Specifications: 1. Quadratic, common linear time trend 2. Quadratic, common log-linear time trend 3. Quadratic, regional linear time trends 4. Quadratic, regional, log-linear time trends 5. Spline, common linear time trend 6. Spline, common log-linear time trend 7. Spline, regional linear time trends 8. Spline, regional, log-linear time trends 40 Table A.2. Regression Results from Fatalities/Population Models Independent dratic Spline Variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 7.7500* 7.8146* 5.1714* 6.1926* InY (0.2243) (0.2223) (0.3058) (0.2886) -0.4510* -0.4607* -0.2785* -0.3578* (1nYi2 fo(0.0137) (0.0134) (0.0191) (0.0/ 77) InY for: 1.6837* 1.6067* 1.4445* 1.2526* $1- $938 (0.1432) (0.1434) (0.1400) (0.1439) $938- $1,395 1.1798* 1.1445* 1.1193* 1.0604* (0.1266) (0.1258) (0.1322) (0.1283) $1,395- $2,043 0.5064* 0.4277* 0.5119* 0.3256* (0.1219) (0.1209) (0.1250) (0.1278) $2,043- $3045 0.9199* 0.8177* 0.9757* 0.7651* (0.1304) (0.1302) (0.1299) (0.1345) $3,045- $4,065 0.6995* 0.6221 * 0.9602* 0.7007* (0.1526) (0.1520) (0.1492) (0.1495) $4,065- $6,095 0.3225* 0.2758* 0.6021 * 0.3903* (0.1146) (0.1130) (0.1119) (0.1107) $6,095- $8,592 -0.0477 -0.1119 0.2579* 0.0746 (0.1318) (0.1315) (0.1288) (0.1299) -0.7910* -0.9382* -0.2074 -0.5422* $8,592-$10,894 (0.1645) (0.1658) (0.1633) (0.1668) $10,894-13,234 -1.5720* -1.6733* -0.6682* -1.3381* (0.1952) (0.1904) (0.1999) (0.1886) >$13,234 -1.1509* -1.2061* -0.5216* -0.9964* $__3,234 (0.163 7) (0.1603) (0.163 7) (0.1571) Tuming Point $5,385 $4,825 $10,784 $5,738 $6,095 $6,095 $8,592 $8,592 (I 985$intl) 95% C.I.: [$4977, [$4489, [$8644, [$5141, $58261 $5186] $13455] $6403] Commnon time -0.00 10 0.0346* 0.0013 0.0555* trend: t (0.0010) (0.0123) (0.0010) (0.0122) Regional t: 0.0054* 0.2377* 0.0065* 0.2573* EAP (0.0029) (0.04 17) (0.0029) (0.0416) ECA -0.01 00' 0.0162 -0.0126* -0.0305 (0.0032) (0.0399) (0.0032) (0.0403) India 0.0194* 0.2789* 0.0225* 0.3189* (0.0048) (0.0591) (0.0048) (0.05 79) LAC 0.0145* 0.3100* 0.0120* 0.2639* (0.0032) (0.0625) (0.0032) (0.0615) MNA -0.0093* -0.0301 -0.0067* 0.0106 (0.0023) (0.0301) (0.0025) (0.0324) SA -0.0015 0.0361 0.0041 0.0956* (0.003 1) (0.0389) (0.0032) (0.0388) SSA 0.0101* 0.1468* 0.0106* 0.1609* (0.0013) (0.0191) (0.0013) (0.0186) High Income -0.0191* -0.0783* -0.0154* -0.0567* High Income (0.0016) (0.0177) (0.001 7) (0.01 76) F statistic on F8,2102 = F8,2102= F8,2os4= F8,2094= regional ts: 35.60 19.72 29.50 20.99 -32.948* -33.046* -23.796* -27.427* -12.550* -12.149* -11.359* -10.462* constant (0.9128) (0.9092) (1.1952) (1.1416) (0.9606) (0.9596) (0.9360) (0.9599) Adjusted R2: 0.8455 0.8460 0.8634 0.8557 0.8554 0.8567 0.8695 0.8656 No. of Countries: 88, No. of observations: 2200 41 TsabD A.3. IFoirecasts of Re2a Peir Capift GIDIP Amunuall Girowth Rates (%)9 2000-2020 elioim/Counatry I 2000 I 2001 2002=2020 South Asia 3.0 2.8 3.8 India 3.3 2.8 East Asia and Pacific 6.4 3.6 5.1 China 7.0 6.4 Korea, Rep. 7.9 1.7 Indonesia 3.5 2.1 Europe and Central Asia 6.1 1.9 3.3 Russian Federation 8.6 5.0 Turkey 5.5 -8.7 Poland 4.1 1.4 Latin America and the Caribbean 2.2 -0.7 2.1 Brazil 3.0 0.2 Mexico 5.2 -1.3 Argentina -1.7 -3.2 MidldRe East anmd North Arica 1.9 1.5 1.4 Saudi Arabia 0.7 -1.5 Iran 3.5 2.5 Egypt 3.5 2.7 Sub-Saharan Africa 0.5 0.3 1.3 South Africa 1.4 1.0 Nigeria 0.4 0.3 High-income Economies Industrial G-7 2.7 0.3 2.1 US 3.2 0.3 2.0 Japan 1.5 -0.9 2.0 G-4 Europe 3 1.3 2.3 GerTnany 3.1 0.7 2.1 Euro Area 3.3 1.4 2.5 Non-G7 Industrial 3.5 1.6 2.7 Other High-income 4.7 -0.7 2.8 Asian NEEs (KOR, HKG, SGP) 6.4 -0.7 3.4 Source: World Bank Global Economic Prospects 2002. 42 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS3011 Renegotiation of Concession J Luis Guasch April 2003 J Troncoso Contracts in Latin America Jean-Jacques Laffont 37826 St6phane Straub WPS3012 Just-in-Case lnventories A Cross- J Luis Guasch April 2003 J Troncoso Country Analysis Joseph Kogan 37826 WPS3013 Land Sales and Rental Markets in Klaus Deininger April 2003 M Fernandez Transition Evidence from Rural Songqing Jin 33766 Vietnam WPS3014 Evaluation of Financial Liberalization: Xavier Gine April 2003 K Labrie A General Equilibrium Model with Robert M Townsend 31001 Constrained Occupation Choice WPS3015 Off and Running9 Technology, Trade, Carolina S6nchez-PAramo April 2003 H Sladovich and the Rising Demand for Skilled Norbert Schady 37698 Workers in Latin America WPS3016 Partisan Politics and Stuti Khemani April 2003 H Sladovich Intergovernmental Transfers in India 37698 WPS3017 Why is Unemployment so High Jan Rutkowski April 2003 J Rutkowski in Bulgaria? 84569 WPS3018 Integrating the Least Developed Paul Brenton Apnl 2003 L Tabada Countries into the World Trading 36896 System The Current Impact of EU Preferences under Everything but Arms WPS3019 Foreign Aid, Conditionality, and Ghost Thilak Ranaweera Apnl 2003 P Rathan Raj of the Financing Gap: A Forgotten 33705 Aspect of the Aid Debate WPS3020 Consumption, Health, Gender, Anne Case April 2003 D Ballantyne and Poverty Angus Deaton 87198 WPS3021 Institutional Arrangements for Public Elizabeth Currie April 2003 M Rosenquist Debt Management Jean-Jacques Dethier 82602 Eriko Togo WPS3022 Sending Farmers Back to School Gershon Feder April 2003 P Kokila The Impact of Farmer Field Schools Rinku Murgai 33716 in Indonesia Jaime B Quizon WPS3023 Productivity Growth and Product Douglas M Addison April 2003 D Addison Variety Gains from Imitation and 31188 Education WPS3024 R&D and Development Daniel Lederman April 2003 P Soto William F Maloney 37892 WPS3025 Trade Structure and Growth Daniel Lederman April 2003 P Soto William F Maloney 37892 WPS3026 Strategic Approaches to Science Robert Watson April 2003 R. Watson and Technology in Development Michael Crawford 36965 Sara Farley Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS3027 Financial Intermediation and Growth: Genevieve Boyreau- April 2003 P Sintim-Aboagye Chinese Style Debray 38526 WPS3028 Does a Country Need a Promotion Jacques Morisset April 2003 M. Feghali Agency to Attract Foreign Direct 36177 Investment? A Small Analytical Model Applied to 58 Countries WPS3029 Who Benefits and How Much9 How Alessandro Nicita Apnl 2003 P. Flewitt Gender Affects Welfare Impacts of a Susan Razzaz 32724 Booming Textile Industry WPS3030 The Impact of Bank Regulations, Asli Demirgu,-Kunt April 2003 A. Yaptenco Concentration, and Institutions on Luc Laeven 31823 Bank Margins Ross Levine WPS3031 Imports, Entry, and Competition Law Hiau Looi Kee April 2003 P Flewitt as Market Disciplines Bernard Hoekman 32724 WPS3032 Information Diffusion in International Alejandro lzquierdo April 2003 M. Feghali Markets Jacques Morisset 36177 Marcelo Olarreaga WPS3033 The Role of Occupational Pension Dimitri Vittas Apnl 2003 P. Infante Funds in Mauritius 37642 WPS3034 The Insurance Industry in Dimitri Vittas April 2003 P Infante Mauritius 37642