WPS8077


Policy Research Working Paper                        8077




   Does Energy Efficiency Promote Economic
                   Growth?
   Evidence from a Multi-Country and Multi-Sector Panel
                         Data Set

                                Ashish Rajbhandari
                                    Fan Zhang




South Asia Region
Office of the Chief Economist
May 2017
Policy Research Working Paper 8077


  Abstract
 This paper examines the causal relationship between energy                         also finds evidence of long-run bidirectional causality between
 efficiency and economic growth based on panel data for 56                          lower energy intensity and higher economic growth for
 high- and middle-income countries from 1978 to 2012.                               middle-income countries. This finding suggests that beyond
 Using a panel vector autoregression approach, the study finds                      climate benefits, middle-income countries may also earn
 evidence of a long-run Granger causality from economic                             an extra growth dividend from energy efficiency measures.
 growth to lower energy intensity for all countries. The study




  This paper is a product of the Office of the Chief Economist, South Asia Region. It is part of a larger effort by the World
  Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world.
  Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted
  at fzhang1@worldbank.org.




         The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
         issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
         names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
         of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
         its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.


                                                       Produced by the Research Support Team
  Does Energy Efficiency Promote Economic Growth?
   Evidence from a Multi-Country and Multi-Sectoral
                                      Panel Data Set



                                                      ∗
                    Ashish Rajbhandari                         Fan Zhang †
                           Stata                               World Bank




   Keywords: Energy efficiency, energy intensity, economic growth, panel cointegration,
Granger causality, vector autoregressions

   JEL Classification: C32, C33, O13, Q43



   ∗
    Contact: arajbhandari@stata.com
   †
    Contact: World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC, USA. fzhang1@worldbank.org
We thank Uwe Deichmann for help conceptualize the research question. We thank Vivien Foster, Yadviga
Viktorivna Semikolenova, Govinda Timilsina, and Maria Vagliasindi for helpful comments on earlier drafts.
Financial support from the Trade and Competitiveness Multi-Donor Trust Fund is greatly appreciated.
    1    Introduction
    Energy efficiency is commonly seen as a key policy option for climate change mitigation. It
    also has recently been promoted as an industrial policy to boost economic competitiveness.
    For example, the European Union’s 2030 Energy Strategy describes energy efficiency as
    fundamental in the transition toward a more competitive, secure, and sustainable energy
    system.1 And the U.S. government has acknowledged energy efficiency as a key part of its
    strategy to support trade competitiveness.2
        There are several potential channels through which energy efficiency policies could spur
    competitiveness and growth (Deichmann and Zhang, 2013). First, they could encourage
    innovation and technology development. When firms become more productive by using less
    energy per unit of output, they could become more cost-competitive in export markets. Sec-
    ond, these policies could create new demand and new markets for energy efficient technologies
    and products. The ensuing investment could bring new jobs and growth. Third, by enabling
    government to reduce energy-related expenditures, especially in energy-importing countries,
    they could allow greater spending in other priority areas that would benefit growth in the
    long run, such as health and education. Finally, by producing energy savings for households,
    they could boost disposable income and encourage growth-promoting consumption.
        Despite many anecdotal accounts of the relationship between energy efficiency and eco-
    nomic growth, empirical evidence on a causal link is thin. Existing analysis takes a deep
    dive into specific industries to explore productivity benefits of energy efficiency measures,
    such as in iron and steel manufacturing (Worrell et al., 2003), paper and steel manufacturing
    (DOE, 1997), and the glass industry (Boyd and Pang, 2000), At the macro level, numer-
    ous studies have investigated the causal relationship between total energy consumption and
    economic growth (for example Kraft and Kraft 1978 and Costantini and Martini 2010; see
    also Ozturk 2010 for a detailed review). But there has been no broader examination of the
    macroeconomic effect of energy efficiency policies.
        In this paper, we explore the causal relationship between energy efficiency and GDP
    growth based on a panel dataset of 56 countries spanning the period from 1978 to 2012.
    Causality here is confined to Granger causality, in which a variable is said to “Granger-
    cause” another variable if it serves as a useful predictor of future values of that variable
    after controlling for several lags. Energy efficiency is proxied by energy intensity, defined as
    energy use per unit of economic output. Because changes in energy intensity can be driven
    by both efficiency effects (resulted in lower energy use to produce the same amount of a good)
    and structural effects (resulted in the tendency of energy intensity to first rise as a country
    moves from agriculture to industry and then fall as it shifts from industry to services), we
1
     European Commission. “Energy Efficiency and its contribution to energy security and the 2030 Framework
     for climate and energy policy”
2
     http://trade.gov/press/publications/newsletters/ita 1009/energy 1009.asp



                                                     2
    combine macro-level analysis with sector-level analysis of industry and agriculture to control
    for change in the sectoral composition of the economy.
        Previous studies using country-level time-series data or multicountry panel data to test
    for Granger causality between total energy consumption and growth have been mostly con-
    fined to a bivariate model with energy use and GDP as the two variables (Ozturk, 2010).
    However, inference form bivariate models must be interpreted with caution because of po-
    tential omitted variable bias (L¨utkepohl, 1982; Zachariadis, 2007). For example, some recent
    studies have underscored the importance of controlling for energy price, as energy price could
    have a causal impact on both energy use and output growth (Lee and Lee, 2010; Costantini
    and Martini, 2010; Belke et al., 2011). In this paper, we specifically control for energy price
    as an endogenous variable so as to allow more conclusive causal inferences.
        We apply a panel vector autoregression (PVAR) approach for the causality analysis. We
    first test for unit roots in the variables using tests proposed by Pesaran (2007) and Deme-
    trescu et al. (2006). Both these tests allow for cross-section dependence between countries.
    After establishing unit roots in the variables of interest, we test whether the variables are
    cointegrated using the panel conintegration test of Pedroni (2004). We find evidence of panel
    cointegration, which leads us to estimate long-run cointegrating parameters based on gener-
    alized methods of moments (GMM). Finally, we use the lagged residuals estimated from the
    cointegrating regression as an exogenous error correction term in a PVAR.
        Our sample covers a diverse set countries of different income levels. Because energy needs
    differ at different stages of development, we categorize countries into three groups: high in-
    come, upper middle income (UMI) and lower middle income (LMI).3 We find evidence of
    unidirectional causality from GDP growth to lower aggregate energy intensity and lower
    industrial energy intensity for high-income countries in the long run. We also find bidi-
    rectional Granger causality between economic growth and lower aggregate energy intensity
    for lower-middle-income countries and between growth and lower industrial energy inten-
    sity for upper-middle-income countries, both in the long run. These findings suggest that
    economic development provides opportunities for countries to become more energy efficient,
    possibly through capital and technology upgrades (Deichmann and Zhang, 2013). Moreover,
    the bidirectional causality for lower-middle-income countries and for the industrial sector of
    upper-middle-income countries implies that energy efficiency could be an instrument for ac-
    celerating growth and productivity. In other words, beyond climate benefits, middle-income
    countries may also earn an extra growth dividend from energy efficiency measures.
        The rest of the paper is organized in the following ways: Section 2 describes the data.
    Section 3 discusses the PVAR approach and presents the results. Section 4 discusses the
    policy implications and concludes the paper.
3
     The analysis excludes low-income countries because energy price data for these countries are not available.




                                                         3
    2     Data and Descriptive Analysis
    We use three types of data for the analysis: data on total final energy consumption and
    the sectoral energy consumption of agriculture and industry from the International Energy
    Agency (IEA) World Energy Statistics and Balances database; data on GDP and value added
    of agriculture, services, and industry from the World Bank World Development Indicators
    (WDI) database; and energy price data from the IEA Energy Prices and Taxes database, the
    Energy Regulators Regional Association (ERRA) Tariff database, and various government
    reports and websites. The IEA reports after-tax industry and household electricity and
    natural gas prices for OECD and selected non-OECD countries. The ERRA database reports
    after-tax prices for residential and non-residential consumers. We use industry or non-
    residential electricity price as a proxy for energy price.4 When electricity price data are not
    available, we use the industry natural gas price as a substitute. All price and value added
    data are converted to 2005 U.S. prices.5 For countries that have gaps in energy price data,
    we linearly interpolate those missing observations using the growth rate in the corresponding
    country’s Consumer Price Index.6 Table A1 reports the countries as well as the years for
    which energy price data are linearly interpolated.
        Our main variable of interest is energy intensity, defined as total final energy consump-
    tion divided by GDP. Sector-specific energy intensity is defined as the total final energy
    consumption of the sector (industry or agriculture) divided by sector value added.
        Our yearly dataset consists of an unbalanced panel of 56 countries spanning the period
    from 1991 to 2012. We categorize the countries as high income, upper middle income, or
    lower middle income based on the World Bank’s income classification and the countries per
    capita gross national income in 2012. Table 1 lists the countries by their income level in
    2012 and by data availability for different measures of energy intensity.
        Table 2 reports the summary statistics. Figures 1, 2, 3, and 4 show the trends in average
    GDP, aggregate and sectoral energy intensity, value added shares, and energy price for each
    income group over the sample period, respectively. GDP and aggregate energy intensity are
    strongly trending in opposite directions since 1990. While GDP has steadily increased, the
    aggregate energy intensity of all income groups has fallen dramatically over the past two
    decades.7 The negative correlation between GDP and aggregate energy intensity is highly
    significant, although it does not indicate causality or the direction of causality. Industrial
4
     We use IEA data on industry electricity prices whenever available. We use ERRA data on non-residential
     electricity prices when IEA data are not available. The same approach applies to natural gas prices data.
5
     GDP data are based on purchasing power parity.
6
     Our main conclusions are robust to the alternative approach by which missing observations of energy prices
     are not interpolated.
7
     There was a significant increase in energy intensity in middle-income countries after 1991. This is because
     many middle-income countries in the sample are transition economies and experienced a sharp contraction
     in output after the end to centrally planned production. Our main conclusions are robust when we restrict
     sample to observations between 1991 and 2012.


                                                        4
energy intensity shows a declining trend for middle-income countries especially after mid
1990s while it remains flat for high-income countries. Agricultural energy intensity shows no
clear time trend. While the value added share of industry have been on a steady decline for
high income countries, the corresponding shares for middle income countries have been in-
creasing until 2010. The value added share of agriculture are declining for all income groups.
Finally, the average energy prices for high-income and upper-middle-income countries have
more than doubled since 2000. For lower-middle-income countries, it fluctuates around 60
U.S. dollars per MWh between 1991 and 2010 and then declined to 40 USD per MWh in
2012.


3     Model and Results
In this section, we describe procedures for and results of three types of tests: panel unit root
test, panel cointegration test and Granger causality test.


3.1    Panel Unit Root Test
Causality tests are very sensitive to the stationarity of the series. Thus we begin by testing
for data stationarity using panel unit root tests proposed by Pesaran (2007) and Deme-
trescu et al. (2006). These tests do not assume that individual time series in the panel are
cross-sectionally independently distributed. Furthermore, they can be applied to unbalanced
panels and are easy to implement with good power and size properties. The test in Pesaran
(2007), the CIPS test, is an extension of the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test in which
the standard ADF test is augmented with first differences of individual series and cross sec-
tional averages of lagged levels. The test proposed in Demetrescu et al. (2006), the DHT
test, is based on combining the p -values obtained from a Dickey-Fuller test performed on
individual panels. This test is similar to those in Maddala and Wu (1999) and Choi (2001),
except that the DHT test uses the modified inverse normal method of Hartung (1999) that
is robust to dependence among cross sections.
    For the CIPS test, we fit the following cross-sectionally augmented Dickey-Fuller regres-
sion:
                                                     ¯t−1 + di ∆¯
                          ∆yit = ai + bi yi,t−1 + ci y          yt + eit                   (1)

where yit is the observation of the ith country at time t, ∆ is the first difference operator,
¯t−1 is the first lag of the dependent variable averaged over all panels, and ∆¯
y                                                                                      yt is the first
difference of the average. ai , bi , ci , di are parameters and eit is the idiosyncratic error. Under
the unit root null hypothesis, there is bi = 0 for all i. The alternative hypothesis corresponds
to some panels being stationary.




                                                 5
   For the DHT test, we fit the following panel version of the augmented Dickey-Fuller test:

                                   ∆yit = ai + bi yi,t−1 + eit                               (2)

where the null hypothesis of unit root is bi = 0 for all i and the alternative hypothesis cor-
responds to all panels being stationary. The individual Dickey-Fuller p-values are combined
to obtain the resulting p-value for the panel unit root test.
    To determine the order of integration, we test both the levels and the first differences of
the variables. All variables are transformed into logarithms before testing. Table 3 presents
the test results applied to the levels of the variables. For all variables (except agricultural
energy intensity), the null hypothesis is a random walk with a possible drift, with the al-
ternative hypothesis being stationary around a linear time trend. For agricultural energy
intensity, because there was no clear time trend in the series, we test the null hypothesis of a
random walk against the alternative of stationary with no time trend. We fail to reject the
null hypothesis of a random walk with a possible drift in almost all series. In some cases,
we get mixed evidence of nonstationarity when one test rejects the null hypothesis while the
other one fails to do so.
    Table 4 reports test results applied to the first difference of all variables. We find that both
tests reject the null hypothesis of a random walk with a possible drift in the first difference
of the variables. The unit root tests provide evidence that all variables are integrated with
order one.


3.2    Panel Cointegration Test
Having established the nonstationarity of all variables in the previous section, we now test
whether the variables are cointegrated. Specifically, we are interested in testing whether
aggregate and sector-level energy intensity are cointegrated with economic growth after con-
trolling for energy price. The existence of cointegration implies Granger causality.
    We use the residual-based tests developed by Pedroni (1999, 2004) to test for panel cointe-
gration that allows for a heteregenous cointegrating vector. The null hypothesis is that there
is no cointegration among the variables in the individual panels. The alternative hypothesis
is that either the variables are cointegrated in all panels with a common autoregressive pa-
rameter or the variables are cointegrated in all panels with a country-specific autoregressive
parameter. The later case allows for additional heterogeneity among panels.
    We consider the following regression for the test:

                      intensityit = αi + δi t + β1i gdpit + β2i priceit +   it               (3)

where subscript i denotes country and t denotes year. αi is the individual-specific intercepts
or fixed-effects, δi is the coefficient on the time trend t, β1i and β2i are the individual slope


                                                6
coefficients. intensityit is aggregate energy intensity and the energy intensity of industry
and agriculture. gdpit is the GDP, and priceit is energy price. Pedroni (2004) provides two
sets of statistics: within-dimension or panel cointegration statistics and between-dimension
or group mean panel cointegration statistics. These test statistics differ in how they pool
information across panels. In both cases, the residual-based cointegration test involves fitting
the following regression of the estimated residuals:

                                      ˆit = γi ˆit−1 + uit                                 (4)

where ˆit is the estimated residuals after fitting the model in (3).
    The within-dimension statistics are constructed by pooling the autoregressive coefficient
in (4) across different countries. The null hypothesis in this case is H0 : γi = 1 whereas
the alternative hypothesis is Ha : γi = γ < 1. The rejection of the null hypothesis of no
cointegration then implies that the variables in all panels are cointegrated with a common
autoregressive parameter. The null hypothesis for the between-dimension statistics is the
same as that of the within-dimension. However, it differs in the alternative hypothesis which
assume country-specific autoregressive parameter given by Ha : γi < 1. The rejection of the
null hypothesis in this case implies that the variables in all panels are cointegrated with a
country-specific autoregressive parameter. Pedroni (1999) provides seven test statistics for
testing cointegration among the variables in a panel setting. The first four are the within-
dimension statistics: Panel ν , Panel ρ, Panel t (PP), and Panel t(ADF), where PP and ADF
are test statistics of the Phillips-Perron and augmented Dickey Fuller type. The last three
statistics are the between-dimension statistics: Group ρ, Group t(PP), and Group t(ADF).
We apply these tests to the regression in (3).
    Table 5 reports the results of cointegration tests for each of the three country income
groups. Almost all test statistics indicate cointegration between different measures of energy
intensity and economic growth for high- and upper-middle-income countries, while all do so
for lower-middle-income countries.


3.3    Estimation of Long-Run Parameters
The existence of cointegration implies a causal relationship between GDP and energy inten-
sity, but it does not indicate the direction of the causality. Before we proceed with Granger
causality tests, we first estimate the parameters of the long-run relationship described in
equation (3) using dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS) to establish the sign of the corre-
lation between GDP, energy intensity, and energy price. The DOLS estimator for univariate
time series was proposed in Saikkonen (1991) and Stock and Watson (1993) and extended
to a panel setting by Kao and Chiang (2000) and Mark and Sul (2003). Using Monte Carlo
simulation, Kao and Chiang (2000) and Wagner and Hlouskova (2010) show that this estima-
tor performs better than the nonparametric fully-modified ordinary least squares estimator

                                               7
in finite samples. Similar to the single-equation DOLS, the panel version adds leads and
lags of the regressors to correct for endogeneity of the regressors and serial correlation in the
residuals.
    Table 6 reports the estimation results. These results show that for all income groups,
GDP growth and a higher energy price are correlated with lower aggregate energy intensity.
The income elasticity is −0.37 for high-income countries, −0.22 for upper-middle-income
countries, and −0.36 for lower-middle-income ones. The price elasticity is −0.10 for high-
income countries, −0.02 upper-middle-income countries, and −0.18 for lower-middle-income
countries. However, the price effect is not statistically significant for upper-middle-income
countries.
    Results at the sector level are similar. GDP growth is correlated with a decrease in both
industrial and agricultural energy intensity for all income groups. The effect is especially
large for agricultural energy intensity in high-income countries, with a 1 percent increase in
GDP associated with a 1.20 percent decline in this measure. In general, income elasticity
of high-income countries is larger that of middle-income countries. For industrial energy
intensity, it is −0.67 for high-income countries, and between −0.14 and −0.50 for middle-
income countries.
    A higher energy price is associated with lower industrial and agricultural energy intensity
for all income groups. Interestingly, sectoral energy intensity is more responsive to energy
price changes in middle-income countries than it is in high-income countries. The price
elasticity of industrial energy intensity ranges from −0.03 for high-income countries to −0.29
for upper-middle-income countries, and −0.27 for lower-middle-income countries. There is
no statistically significant correlation between energy price and agricultural energy intensity
in high-income countries. In middle-income countries, the price elasticity ranges from −0.13
in upper-middle-income countries to −0.06 in lower-middle-income countries.


3.4    Granger Causality Tests
In this section, we test for Granger causality using a vector error correction model (VECM).
The VEC term represents any deviation from the long-run equilibrium between GDP, energy
price and energy intensity described above. Adopting the Engle-Granger method, we use
the first lags of the residuals as a proxy for long-run deviations in a VECM. Specifically, we
consider the following multivariate panel VECM with the first difference of intensity, GDP,
and energy prices as the dependent variables:




                                               8
                             p                         p
    ∆intensity it = θ1i +         θ11,l ∆gdp it−l +         θ12,l ∆price it−l + γ1 ˆit−1 + νit,1           (5)
                            l=1                       l=1
                             p                                 p
          ∆gdp it = θ2i +         θ21,l ∆intensity it−l +           θ22,l ∆price it−l + γ2 ˆit−1 + νit,2   (6)
                            l=1                               l=1
                             p                                 p
        ∆price it = θ3i +         θ31,l ∆intensity it−l +           θ32,l ∆gdp it−l + γ3 ˆit−1 + νit,3     (7)
                            l=1                               l=1


where ∆ is the first difference operator, θki for k = 1, 2, 3 are country-specific fixed effects,
and θkk,l are the coefficients corresponding to the lth lag of the endogenous variables. γk are
the coefficients of the error correction terms and νit,k are idiosyncratic errors.
    Because all variables are nonstationary I(1), we take first differences to make the system
of equations (5)-(7) stable. However, using lagged differences of the dependent variable in
this system introduces a bias, and a standard fixed-effects estimator would be inconsistent
(Arellano and Bond, 1991). To obtain consistent estimators, we estimate panel GMM pro-
posed by Holtz-Eakin et al. (1988); Arellano and Bond (1991). The panel GMM estimator
uses further lagged differences of the dependent variable as instruments to remove endogene-
ity arising from lagged regressors. In our application, we use second and third lags of the
dependent variables as instruments.
    A VECM allows testing for both short- and long-run causality. In the system of equations
(5)-(7), the coefficients θkk,l represent the short-run effect of the endogenous variables. A
standard Wald test on these coefficients can be used to test for short-run Granger causality.
Specifically, we test the null hypothesis H0 : θkk,l = 0 for l = 1, . . . , p. In equation (5),
rejecting the null hypothesis θ11,1 = 0 implies that GDP growth Granger-causes change in
energy intensity in the short run. In other words, the first lag of the GDP growth is a
significant predictor of changes in energy intensity. Similarly, rejecting the null hypothesis
H0 : θ21,1 = 0 in equation(6) implies that GDP is responding to short-term shocks to energy
intensity. The joint significance of the coefficients θ11,1 and θ21,1 implies bidirectional causality
in which the two variables Granger-cause each other in the short run, while the rejection of
only one of the hypotheses implies unidirectional causality.
    We can test for long-run Granger causality between variables in our model by examining
the significance of the coefficient γk , which represents the speed of adjustment to the long-run
equilibrium in response to any shocks to the system. We test the null hypothesis H0 : γk = 0
for k = 1, . . . , 3. The rejection of the null hypothesis implies long-run Granger causality
running from the error- correcting term to the respective dependent variable. For example,
the significance of γ1 in equation (5) implies that changes in energy intensity adjust in the
long run to any temporary deviations from economic growth. Similarly, the significance of
γ2 in equation (6) implies that changes in energy intensity directly drive economic growth

                                                      9
in the long run.
    Tables (7)-(9) report the estimated coefficients of the error correction terms and the chi-
squared statistics for the test of Granger causality. We find evidence of long-run causality
from GDP and energy price to energy intensity for all income groups. For lower-middle-
income countries, we also find evidence of long-run causality from energy intensity and
energy price to GDP growth. This implies that in these countries, GDP in the long run
responds to shocks to energy intensity and energy prices.
    In the short run, we find bidirectional causality between aggregate energy intensity and
economic growth in high-income countries. We find no Granger causality between energy
intensity and economic growth for middle-income countries.
    Tables 7-9 show the results of Granger causality tests at the sector level. For all income
groups, there is long-run causality from GDP and energy price to industrial energy intensity.
We also find Granger causality from industrial energy intensity and energy price to GDP
for upper-middle-income countries in the long run, and for high- and lower-middle-income
countries in the short run. Finally, there is evidence that GDP and energy price Granger-
cause agricultural energy intensity for upper-middle-income countries in the long run.
    As noted, an aggregate analysis at the country level may not reflect variation in sectoral
composition. As a robustness check to control for the effect of structural change on energy
intensity, we include in the system of equations (5)-(7) an additional variable measuring the
ratio of industrial and services value added to GDP. The second panel to the right in Tables
7-9 report corresponding long- and short-run Granger causality test results. Our main con-
clusions on the direction of causality between GDP and energy intensity remain the same
under this alternative specification. This is consistent with findings in the literature on the
decomposition of energy intensity indicating that most of the gains in energy productiv-
ity over the past few decades can be attributed to genuine efficiency improvements while
structural change in the mix of economic activities has had less influence (Zhang, 2013).


4    Conclusion
Energy efficiency is recognized as playing an important part in climate change mitigation.
However, the long-term relationship between energy efficiency and growth has not been fully
understood. Using panel data for 56 countries from 1991 to 2012, this paper presents a
first effort to shed light on this question. We employ panel unit root tests, panel cointegra-
tion analysis, and a multivariate panel vector autoregression framework to investigate the
long- and short-run causal relationship between energy intensity (used as a proxy for energy
efficiency) and GDP for a mix of high and middle-income countries. Because changes in
energy intensity can be driven by both changes in sectoral composition and improvements
in efficiency, we combine macro-level analysis and analysis of the industrial and agricultural
sectors to differentiate the effects of these two processes on energy intensity.

                                             10
    Our main results indicate unidirectional long-run causality running from economic growth
and higher energy prices to lower energy intensity. This conclusion holds for all income
groups and at the sector level. This finding corroborates the intuition that higher energy
prices provide incentives for increasing energy efficiency, while economic development and
demand growth provide opportunities for achieving efficiency gains by replacing old plants
and technologies with new ones.
    More interestingly, we find evidence of bidirectional long-run Granger causality between
energy intensity and economic growth for middle-income countries, implying a feedback
between GDP and energy intensity. This finding suggests that encouraging energy efficiency
could support higher economic growth in the long run. Thus beyond climate benefits, energy
efficiency could also provide long-term economic growth benefits.




                                            11
References
Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo
  evidence and an application to employent equations. The Review of Economic Studies,
  58(2):277–297.

Belke, A., Dobnik, F., and Dreger, C. (2011). Energy consumption and economic growth:
  New insights into the cointegration relationship. Energy Economics, 33:782–789.

Boyd, G. A. and Pang, J. X. (2000). Estimating the linkage between energy efficiency and
  productivity. Energy Policy, 28(5):289–296.

Choi, I. (2001). Unit root tests for panel data. Journal of International Money and Finance,
 20:249–272.

Costantini, V. and Martini, C. (2010). The causality between energy consumption and
  economic growth: a multi-sectoral analysis using non-stationary cointegrated panel data.
  Energy Economics, 32:591–603.

Deichmann, U. and Zhang, F. (2013). Growing Green: The Economic Benefits of Climate
  Action. World Bank Publication, Washington, DC.

Demetrescu, M., Hassler, U., and Tarcolea, A. I. (2006). Combining significance of correlated
  statistics with application to panel data. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
  68(5):647–663.

DOE (1997). The relationship between environmental goals, productivity improvement, and
 increased energy efficiency in integrated paper and steel plans. Technical report, U.S.
 Department of Energy, Washington, DC. DOE/PO-0055.

Hartung, J. (1999). A note on combining dependent tests of significance. Biometrical Journal,
  41:849–855.

Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., and Rosen, H. S. (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions
  with panel data. Econometrica, 56:1371–1395.

Kao, C. and Chiang, M. H. (2000). On the estimation and inference of a cointegrated re-
 gression in panel data. In Baltagi, B. H., editor, Nonstationary panels, panel cointegration
 and dynamic panels, volume 15, pages 179–222, Amsterdam. Elseiver.

Kraft, J. and Kraft, A. (1978). On the relationship between energy and gnp. Journal of
  Energy and Development, 3:401–403.

Lee, C. and Lee, J. (2010). A panel data analysis of the demand for total energy and
  electricity in oecd countries. Energy Journal, 31:1–23.

                                             12
 utkepohl, H. (1982). Non-causality due to omitted variables. Journal of Econometrics,
L¨
  19:267–378.

Maddala, G. S. and Wu, S. (1999). A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data
 and a new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61:631–652.

Mark, N. C. and Sul, D. (2003). Cointegration vector estimation by panel dols and long-run
 money demand. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65:655–680.

Ozturk, I. (2010). A literature survey on energy-growth nexus. Energy Policy, 38:340–349.

Pedroni, P. (1999). Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogenous panels with multiple
  regressors. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61:653–670.

Pedroni, P. (2004). Panel cointegration: Asymptotic and finite sample properties of pooled
  time series tests with an application hypothesis. Econometric Theory, 20:597–625.

Pesaran, M. H. (2007). A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross section depen-
  dence. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22:265–312.

Saikkonen, P. (1991). Asymptotically efficient estimation of cointegrating regressions. Econo-
  metric Theory, 7:1–21.

Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (1993). A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors in higher
  order integrated systems. Econometrica, 61:783–820.

Wagner, M. and Hlouskova, J. (2010). The performance of panel cointegration methods:
 Results from a large scale simulation study. Econometric Reviews, 29(2):182–223.

Worrell, E., Laitner, J., Ruth, M., and Finman, H. (2003). Productivity benefits of industrial
 energy efficiency measures. Energy, 28:1081–1098.

Zachariadis, T. (2007). Exploring the relationship between energy use and economic growth
  with bivariate models: New evidence from g-7 countries. Energy Economics, 29(6):1233–
  1253.

Zhang, F. (2013). The energy transition of the transition economies: An empirical analysis.
  Energy Economics, 40:679–686.




                                              13
          50000
             40000
2005 USD PPP
   30000  20000
          10000




                     1980        1990              2000     2010   2020


                                        (a) High income
          12000
          10000
          8000
2005 USD PPP
  6000    4000
          2000




                     1980        1990              2000     2010   2020


                                  (b) Upper middle income
          4000
          3000
2005 USD PPP
    2000  1000
          0




                     1980        1990              2000     2010   2020


                                  (c) Lower middle income

                            Figure 1: Average per capita GDP


                                              14
               .2
toe per thousand 2005 USD PPP
     .12     .14
               .1   .16   .18




                                1980       1990              2000           2010           2020

                                       High income                   Upper middle income
                                       Lower middle income


                                         (a) Aggregate energy intensity
               .8
toe per thousand 2005 USD PPP
     .2        .4
               0        .6




                                1980       1990              2000           2010           2020

                                       High income                   Upper middle income
                                       Lower middle income


                                         (b) Industrial energy intensity
               .2
toe per thousand 2005 USD PPP
    .05        .1
               0        .15




                                1980       1990              2000           2010           2020

                                       High income                   Upper middle income
                                       Lower middle income


                                        (c) Agricultural energy intensity

    Figure 2: Average aggregate and sectoral energy intensities


                                                       15
     40
     30
Percentage
    20
     10
     0




             1980       1990               2000        2010   2020

                                Services           Industry
                                Agriculture


                               (a) High income
     50
     40
Percentage
     30
     20
     10




             1980       1990               2000        2010   2020

                                Services           Industry
                                Agriculture


                        (b) Upper middle income
     50
     40
Percentage
    30
     20
     10




             1980       1990               2000        2010   2020

                                Services           Industry
                                Agriculture


                         (c) Lower middle income

             Figure 3: Average sectoral value added shares


                                      16
      140
      120
USD per MWh
  80  60
      40 100




               1980        1990              2000        2010             2020

                       High income                  Upper middle income
                       Lower middle income




                      Figure 4: Average energy prices




                                       17
                                  Table 1: List of countries

                        Aggregate energy intensity

High income         Australia, Austria† , Belgium† , Canada, Chile, Croatia, Cyprus† ,
                    Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland† , France, Germany,
                    Greece† , Hong Kong, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea,
                    Luxembourg† , Netherlands† , New Zealand, Norway† , Poland,
                    Portugal, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain,
                    Sweden† , Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States
Upper middle income Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Hungary, Jordan,
                    Kazakhstan, Macedonia† , Malaysia, Mexico, Romania† ,
                    Serbia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, Venezuela
Lower middle income Armenia, Georgia, India, Indonesia, Moldova, Mongolia† , Ukraine

                        Industrial energy intensity

High income         Australia, Austria† , Belgium† , Canada, Chile, Croatia, Cyprus† ,
                    Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland† , France, Germany,
                    Greece† , Hong Kong, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea,
                    Luxembourg† , Netherlands† , New Zealand, Norway† , Poland,
                    Portugal, Russia, Singapore, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain,
                    Sweden† , Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States
Upper middle income Albania, Brazil, Bulgaria, Hungary, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Macedonia† ,
                    Malaysia, Mexico, Romania† , Serbia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey,
                    Venezuela
Lower middle income Armenia, Georgia, India, Indonesia, Moldova, Mongolia† , Ukraine

                        Agricultural energy intensity

High income         Australia, Austria† , Belgium† , Canada, Chile, Croatia, Cyprus† ,
                    Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland† , France, Germany,
                    Greece† , Hong Kong, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea,
                    Luxembourg† , Netherlands† , New Zealand, Norway† , Poland,
                    Portugal, Russia, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden† ,
                    Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States
Upper middle income Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Hungary, Jordan,
                    Kazakhstan, Macedonia† , Malaysia, Mexico, Romania† ,
                    Serbia, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, Venezuela
Lower middle income Armenia, Georgia, India, Indonesia, Moldova, Mongolia† , Ukraine
  Note: † denotes countries for which gaps in energy price observations are linearly interpolated
  using Consumer Price Index for multiple years.



                                            18
                                Table 2: Summary statistics

GDP                                Mean     Std. Dev.    Min        Max       No. of Obs.

 High income                     22476.39   17834.08    1330.75   116664.3       1269
Upper middle income               4036.65   3053.55      218.49   15,649.72      503
Lower middle income               1060.31    955.16       97.16    4387.70       340

Aggregate energy intensity         Mean     Std. Dev.    Min        Max       No. of Obs.

 High income                       0.12          0.06    0.005     0.404         2104
Upper middle income                0.11          0.08    0.006     0.52          1378
Lower middle income                0.14          0.10    0.036      0.75         1095

Industrial energy intensity        Mean     Std. Dev.    Min        Max       No. of Obs.

 High income                       0.13          0.07     0.01      0.52         1106
Upper middle income                0.27          0.24    0.004      1.70         1173
Lower middle income                0.48          0.57    0.002      4.76         915

Agricultural energy intensity      Mean     Std. Dev.    Min        Max       No. of Obs.

 High income                       0.11          0.10    0.0003     0.75         1106
Upper middle income                0.11          0.14    0.0001     1.27         1181
Lower middle income                0.07          0.15   0.00007     1.16          915

Energy price                       Mean     Std. Dev.    Min        Max       No. of Obs.

 High income                       75.86      11.64      42.17     327.78        1056
Upper middle income                64.88      33.25      12.22     169.64        309
Lower middle income                56.47      24.87       7.36     166.71        154
  Note: The unit of per capita GDP is 2005 USD PPP. The unit of aggregate and sectoral
  energy intensities is toe per thousand 2005 USD PPP. The unit of energy price is USD
  per MWh.




                                            19
                         Table 3: Panel unit root tests in levels

                                                  CIPS

     Income group             GDP     Aggregate    Industry     Agriculture      Price

     High income         −1.70           −2.31      −2.15        −1.94 (rw)   −2.92∗∗∗
     No. of Obs.         1645            1615        903            856        1050
     Upper middle income −2.52           −2.44      −2.37        −2.14 (rw)   −2.77∗∗
     No. of Obs.          570             562        463            443         309
     Lower middle income −2.39           −2.65      −2.90∗∗        −2.08       −1.83
     No. of Obs.          211             211        210            210         132

                                                  DHT

     High income         5.53             2.03        3.20       -0.19 (rw)      3.12
     Upper middle income 0.55             1.19        0.62       −0.92 (rw)      1.16
     Lower middle income −0.87            0.96        0.30         −0.38         1.13
        Note: ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respec-
        tively. (rw) indicates a null hypothesis of random walk. In all other cases,
        the null hypothesis is a random walk with a drift. Number of observations
        for DHT test are the same as reported for the CIPS test.




                     Table 4: Panel unit root tests in first differences

                                                  CIPS

Income group             ∆ GDP      ∆ Aggregate     ∆ Industry      ∆Agriculture     ∆ Price

High income             −5.35∗∗∗       −7.22∗∗∗      −5.25∗∗∗         −5.43∗∗∗      −5.11∗∗∗
Upper middle income     −4.84∗∗∗       −5.99∗∗∗      −5.90∗∗∗         −6.33∗∗∗      −4.11∗∗∗
Lower middle income     −4.66∗∗∗       −5.52∗∗∗      −5.55∗∗∗         −4.85∗∗∗      −3.10∗∗∗

                                                  DHT

High income         −16.46∗∗∗         −24.92∗∗∗      −17.78∗∗∗       −21.08∗∗∗      −13.43∗∗∗
Upper middle income −9.82∗∗∗          −17.50∗∗∗      −16.45∗∗∗       −20.44∗∗∗      −7.14∗∗∗
Lower middle income −6.33∗∗∗          −11.04∗∗∗      −11.38∗∗∗       −11.96∗∗∗      −1.47∗∗∗
  Note: ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively. Number
  of observations are the same as reported in Table 3.



                                            20
           Table 5: Panel cointegration test

                                High income

Test statistic    Aggregate      Industry     Agriculture

Panel ν            −4.16∗∗∗       −1.09        3.61∗∗∗
Panel ρ             −2.17∗∗       −2.05∗∗     −24.74∗∗∗
Panel t - PP        5.45∗∗∗       2.95∗∗∗      −2.89∗∗∗
Panel t - ADF        1.73∗         0.97        −2.70∗∗∗
Group ρ            −50.20∗∗∗     −68.37∗∗∗    −149.56∗∗∗
Group t - PP       −2.64∗∗∗      −5.80∗∗∗     −14.14∗∗∗
Group t - ADF       −0.76        −2.66∗∗∗      −4.60∗∗∗

                          Upper middle income

Test statistic    Aggregate†     Industry     Agriculture

Panel ν             2.95∗∗∗       5.55∗∗∗       7.48∗∗∗
Panel ρ            −3.74∗∗∗      −2.94∗∗∗      −15.27∗∗∗
Panel t - PP        −1.77∗         0.56        −3.87∗∗∗
Panel t - ADF       −0.83          1.27        −2.81∗∗∗
Group ρ            −10.79∗∗∗     −7.22∗∗∗      −28.74∗∗∗
Group t - PP       −3.13∗∗∗       −0.86        −8.03∗∗∗
Group t - ADF       −2.17∗∗       −0.27        −7.13∗∗∗

                          Lower middle income

Test statistic    Aggregate      Industry     Agriculture

Panel ν             −1.30         −1.54         −0.29
Panel ρ              1.66∗         0.02        −3.64∗∗∗
Panel t - PP        2.75∗∗∗        0.85        −3.08∗∗∗
Panel t - ADF       2.84∗∗∗       3.84∗∗∗      −1.88∗
Group ρ             1.97∗∗         1.04        −4.08∗∗∗
Group t - PP         1.82∗         1.24        −3.10∗∗∗
Group t - ADF        1.51         3.11∗∗∗      −2.67∗∗∗
  Note: ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%,
  and 10% level respectively. † denotes no deterministic
  terms and ‡ denotes a constant and a trend term.




                           21
             Table 6: Estimation of long-run cointegration parameters

                   High income      Upper middle income      Lower middle income

Intensity          GDP     Price      GDP         Price       GDP         Price

Aggregate   −0.37∗∗∗     −0.10∗∗∗   −0.22∗∗∗     −0.02       −0.36∗∗∗    −0.18∗∗∗
Industry    −0.67∗∗∗     −0.03∗     −0.14∗∗∗    −0.29∗∗∗     −0.50∗∗∗    −0.27∗∗
Agriculture −1.20∗∗∗      −0.04     −0.16∗∗∗    −0.13∗∗∗     −0.16∗∗∗    −0.06∗
          ∗∗∗ ∗∗
  Note:     , , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively.




                                        22
                                         Table 7: Granger causality - Aggregate energy intensity

         Income group                 Without control for structure                          With control for structure

                             GDP/Price        Aggregate/Price   GDP/Energy      GDP/Price      Aggregate/Price     GDP/Aggregate
                                 ↓                  ↓               ↓               ↓                ↓                  ↓
                             Aggregate             GDP            Price         Aggregate           GDP               Price

           Long run

         High income           −1.19∗∗∗            0.31∗∗           0.61          −1.05∗∗∗            0.12               0.15
                                (0.28)            (0.15)           (0.65)          (0.21)            (0.11)             (0.67)
     Upper middle income       −1.33∗∗∗           −0.01             0.31          −1.31∗∗∗           −0.13              −0.36




23
                                (0.28)            (0.21)           (0.92)          (0.28)            (0.19)             (0.77)
     Lower middle income       −0.88∗∗∗           −0.97∗∗          −3.30∗∗        −0.87∗∗∗           −0.65              −2.73∗
                                (0.31)            (0.47)           (1.56)          (0.31)            (0.44)             (1.44)

          Short run†

        High income             7.74∗∗            15.79∗∗∗           1.45          9.38∗∗∗            4.23                3.03
     Upper middle income         0.42               0.35             0.40           0.31              0.19                0.52
     Lower middle income         1.18               0.09             1.01           0.59              1.28                3.83

       Note: ↓ denotes direction of Granger causality. ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively.
       †
         represents the chi squared statistic for the test of Granger causality. Standard errors are reported in parentheses.
                                    Table 8: Granger causality - Industrial energy intensity

         Income group                Without control for structure                       With control for structure

                             GDP/Price     Industry/Price   GDP/Industry GDP/Price          Industry/Price   GDP/Industry
                                 ↓               ↓               ↓           ↓                    ↓               ↓
                              Industry         GDP             Price      Industry              GDP              P

          Long run

         High income          -1.70∗∗∗         -0.01             0.66          -1.57∗∗∗          0.04              0.75
                               (0.34)         (0.11)            (0.54)          (0.33)          (0.10)            (0.57)
     Upper middle income      −1.40∗∗∗        −0.17∗∗          −1.17∗∗∗        −1.32∗∗∗         −0.15∗∗          −1.17∗∗∗




24
                               (0.19)         (0.08)            (0.43)          (0.22)          (0.08)            (0.45)
     Lower middle income      -1.52∗∗∗        −0.07             −0.64          −1.57∗∗∗         −0.05             −0.23
                               (0.25)         (0.09)            (0.27)          (0.27)          (0.10)            (0.39)

          Short run†

        High income            4.64∗          16.42∗∗∗            3.36           2.44             3.46             1.43
     Upper middle income        1.49            0.04              1.13           0.15             0.30             0.26
     Lower middle income       6.11∗∗           0.35              2.33          8.00∗∗            1.00            5.42∗

       Note: ↓ denotes direction of Granger causality. ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level
       respectively. † represents the chi squared statistic for the test of Granger causality. Standard errors are reported in
       parentheses.
                                         Table 9: Granger causality - Agricultural energy intensity

         Income group                    Without control for structure                         With control for structure

                            GDP/Price Agriculture/Price        GDP/Agriculture GDP/Price Agriculture/Price           GDP/Agriculture
                                 ↓            ↓                     ↓               ↓            ↓                        ↓
                            Agriculture     GDP                    Price       Agriculture     GDP                       Price

          Long run

         High income          −0.65∗∗∗           −0.03                0.05          −0.62∗∗∗          −0.03              −0.002
                               (0.24)            (0.02)              (0.14)          (0.26)           (0.02)              (0.14)
     Upper middle income      −1.87∗∗∗           −0.02               −0.12          −1.68∗∗∗          −0.05               −0.22




25
                               (0.53)            (0.04)              (0.20)          (0.54)           (0.05)              (0.25)
     Lower middle income      −1.47∗∗∗            0.05               −0.27          −1.32∗∗∗          −0.09              −0.0004
                               (0.12)            (0.03)              (0.17)          (0.13)           (0.10)             (0.24)

          Short run†

        High income             2.72             7.10∗∗               3.36            1.00             2.15                 0.28
     Upper middle income        0.79              3.91                0.37            1.51             4.79∗                0.04
     Lower middle income      12.70∗∗∗            2.12              19.65∗∗∗        22.42∗∗∗           3.19                 4.37
                                                                                                                                         †
       Note: ↓ denotes direction of Granger causality. ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively.
       The values represent the chi squared statistic for the test of Granger causality. Standard errors are reported in parentheses.
Appendix

           Table A1: Linear interpolation for energy price

                    Country     Years

                    Austria     2001-2003; 2009-2011
                    Belgium     2001-2007
                    Cyprus      2007
                    Finland     2006
                    Greece      2006-2007
                  Luxembourg    1990-2007
                  Netherlands   2002-2006
                    Norway      1992 - 1999
                    Sweden      1998 - 2006
                   Macedonia    2000 - 2003
                   Romania      2006 - 2007
                   Mongolia     2000 - 2002




                                  26