Policy, Researci, and External Atiairs WORKING PAPERS Macroeconomi' Adjustment and Growth Country Economics Department The World Bank March 1991 WPS 631 ( The Macroeconomics of the Public Sector Deficit The Case of Morocco Riccardo Faini Growth has remained relatively high in Morocco, and inflation subdued. Morocco has made great progress toward macroeco- nomic and fiscal stability, but the need remains for an unshaken commitment to fiscal discipline, a determined effort to reformn the tax and public spending systems, and a measured attempt to make credit available for investment and to liberalize financial markets. rhc lolic! . Rcse4rch. and I.xitcnI AAffairs ('ompk,x d,'in ., 'ls I' I Wsrh' In 3p.r s mn'aC I5C I Jd:ags O, Es*rk nprgrcss and In cncouragc iho c,h. idc d:l1': F I I:d I ,:.! d ..: parv'g'' (a n I, the names of tC auIthnr'. refl . t.,t kthr s:1 , . a': .! Ii..! h...d .t! a.! % . .. ! d : I' : .:: - . a,td I. n st;oir arc thc o-h rrs na ,' I ' :' d,,,d I-t hv :.............. ..: ' H : U. '¾i s. I )1r. :.' :("'aa','v- w a,'s : g0 rc:cnhct couninc Polizy, Research, and External Affairs ;I IU3s _- Macroeconomic Adjustment and Growti WPS 631 'I'his papcr --- a product of' Itlc Macroeconomic Adjustment and (irowth Dlivision, Countr\ ILconomn ics Department -- is parn ol'a PRK research project, 'l'hc Macroeconomics ol lhc Public Sector- Delicit (RI") 675-31). Copies are available f'ree flrom tlhe World Biank, 1818 li Strect NW, Washington 1)DC (0113. Please contact Raquel l.u/, rootm N 1 1-057, cxtenisionl 34303 (39 pa-Cs). Morocco's reccnt cconomic history rcsemlblcs Faini argues that ;Iage moderation an1d those of'mansv At'rican countries. Morocco's judicious monetary policies were instrumnental in economic dilf'iculties originated in the comiminod- restrainiig inflation. Wilih a brief exception in ity (phosphate) boom of'tlic mid-1970s, which 1983, monetary autlhoNtics remained firmilv coincidcd with 1-isinig govenmeint spending and committed to avoiding inflationary financing of an unprecedented expatnsion of'public invest- the budget delicit, But this sitrategy could ment -- cndilg Morocco's earlier liscal conlser- succeed only becausc of the A ide-ranging system vatisilm. A sudden revcrsal of the temis ol' trade of credit and monetary rcoulationis thalt chiain- in tie late 1970s -- a resull of'a plunge in ncied domestic f'unids toward thc trcasIry' al phosphate prices and thc second oil shock- relatively low cost. But the prospects for conl- prompted Mor. 'o to resort increasingly to tinuing such a stratcey are not f'avorable. external capital markets to maintain an unabated level of public spending. Grolth perforlimaince canl be attributed to an outstanidinlg export responise to thc new trade But the continued deterioration ol' thc terms regimc anl(d to F1avorable supply shocks -- of trade and the unexpected rise in international includinig a strinlg ol' record agricultural harvests interest rates, together with thc severe droughlt of' and thc collapse of' real oil prices. 1980-84, croded debt service capacity and precipitated a major forcign exchange crisis in Morocco has made gr;eat pro-gress towvard 1983. macroeconomic and liscal stability but the autlio recommends: In response to this crisis, Morocco launchied a medium-term program of economic rceform and * An unshaken commimntcii to Fiscal disci- introduced comprehelisive stabilization and pline. Increa,sed govermcint spending will structural adjustment measures. Since 1983, probably crowd out investment, The shor-m--un Morocco has made great progress in alleviating benclets on output of suchl spendiiing may be botn initernal and extcrnal disequilibria - outweighed by its long-runi negative impact on reducing the budget deficit from 9 percent of' growth. GDP in 1982 to 4.5 percent in 1988, and the * A deteimined el'lfol to refborm thc tax and current account deficit from 12 percent of GDP public expcnditure system, so ihe brunit of liscal to 0.4 percent in the same period. adjustment wnill not again fall mostl) on public investment. Initerestingly, growth has remained Flairly * Encouraging thc availability ol' credit, which high in Morocco, at least in relation to other significantily inilueinces the demand for invest- highly indebted countries, and inflation subdued. ment. Morocco's perfonrancc seems to contradict the * Studying thie imnpact ol' macrocconloilic perceived wisdom that large budget deficits will equilibria, especially oi tihe government budget, foster inflation. The inflation record is particu- to assess the best spee(I lfor finalncial liherali;a- larly surprising because Morocco achieved a 20 tion. percent real depreciation in the 1980s. Thc l'RE Working Ptaper Series dissvninates the findings or \kork under w\av in th. Bank's Po h.\, kewirk h and E\toniia AffairsCompte\. An oh jictivc ofthl s'rics is lo ge tth.sac fmnhngs out thuicktv. e en i rpre. eorains a;. t. rtan ftlltv pot lie d The rindfinvs. intermretins. ncf:md conchiviions in rhese p.IVT'rs d(o not neee-(:riTV represent olh ial 11:ink p,th> f1r,.1 ut,\,, I\s tie I'Rft. 'lli !lI':. ('t',:' The Macroeconomics of the Public Sector Deficit The Case of Morocco by Riccardo Faini* Table of Contents 1. introduction 1 2. The Dudget Deficit: Evolution and Financing 3 a. The overall trend 3 b. The primary deficit 5 c. Financing the budget deficit 7 3. Assets Demand, Seigniorage, and the Inflation Tax 10 4. Investment and Saving Decisions 17 a. The investment choice 17 b. The saving decision 21 5 Modelling the Impact of Fiscal Policy 25 a. A macroeconomic model 25 b. Simulating the impact of fiscal policy 28 6. Conclusions 36 Endnotes 37 References 38 * This paper is an offspring of joint work with John Porter and Sweder van Wijnbergen. I am grateful to both of them for stimulating discussions and suggestions. I would like to thank Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel and Tobias Muller for providing me with crucial data and a preview of their paper which has been a constant source of ideas and insights. I am finally grateful to Roberto Fumagalli for very skillful research assistance. 1 1. INTRODUCTION Morocco's recent economic hlstory bears strlking resemblances with the one oF many countries in Africa. The origins of Morocco's economic difficulties can be traced to the commodity (phosphate) boom of the mild- 1970's which coincided wlth rislng government expenditure and an unprecedented expanslon of the public investment program signallng the end of the conservative Fiscal policies of the past. The sudden reversal in the terms of trade in the late 1970's as a result of the plunge In phosphate prices and the second oil shock prompted Morocco to resort Increasingly to external capital markets In order to malntaln an unabated level of public expenditure. However the continued deterloratlon of the terms of trade, the unanticipated rise in International Interest rates together with the severe drought In 1980-84 eroded debt service capacity and precipitated a major foreign exchange crlsls In 1983. In response to this crisis, Morocco launched a medium-term program of economic reforms and, In consultation with the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, introduced a comprehensive set oF stabllizatlon and structural adjustment measures. Since 1983 Morocco has made great progress in allevlating both Internal and external disequllibria. The overall budget and current account deficits have been reduced from 9% and 12% of GDP in 1982 tc 4.5% and .4% respectlvely In 1988. There are several interesting features In Morocco's adjustment experience. Despite the severity of the crisls and the size of the adjustment undertaken, growth has remained fairly high, at least In relation to other highly indebted countries, and inflatlon subdued. As measured by the CPI, inflation was equal to 6.2% in 1983, It Increased to 12.5% in 1984 but then steadily declined to reach 2.3% in 1988. During the same period real GDP growth averaged 4.3%. This performance seems to contradict the received wisdom that large budget deficits will foster inflation. The inFlation record Is particularly surprising if we also consider that Morocco achieved a 20% real depreciation during the eighties. In this paper we try to uncover the reasons underlying the performance oF the Moroccan economy. To anticipate our concluslons, we argue that wage moderation and judiclous monetary pollcies were instrumental in restraining inflation. Wlth one brief exceptlon ln 1983, monetary authorities remained firmly committed to eschew any 2 inflationary financing of the budget deficit. This strategy could only succeed however because of the wide ranging system of credit and monetary regulations which worked to channel domestic funds toward the Treasury at relatively lov/ coEt.-. The prospects for the continuation of such strategy are not favou-able however. As far as the growth performance is concerned, it Eppears that it can be attributed to an outstanding export response to the new trade regime on the one hand and a set of favourable supply, s.ucks, including a string of record agricultural harvests and the collapse of real oil prices, on the other. The organization of the paper is as follows. In the next section, we study the evolution of the budget and of its different components. We also examine how the deficit was financed. In section 3, we argue that the reluctance by Morocco's policy makers to monetize existing budget deficits is well explained by the sharply unfavourable trade-offs between higher monetization and inflation that exist in Morocco. Such conclusions are based on the estimation of a system of assets demand. In the following section, we analyse the implications that continuing budgetary disequilibria entail on investment and saving decisions. We find that such implications may be substantial, even though they may not work their way exclusively through traditional interest rates channels. Frinally in section 5, we assemble the various pieces of econometric evidence collected in the paper to study the impact of fiscal policy in the context of a macroeconometric mGdel. The last section offers some conclusions. 3 2. THE BUDGET DEFICIT: EVOLUTION AND FINANCING a) the overaUl trend The budget situation in Morocco registers a continuous deterioration during the second half of the seventies. Sorme timid attempts to macroeconomic stabilization provide only temporary restraint to the burgeoning financial needs of the Treasury. However at the beginning of the eighties the fiscal repercussions of the fali in Morocco's terms of trade, the increasing burden of foreign debt attendart on the steep rise oF International interest rates and the growing weariness of foreign commercial banks to provide continuing financing' to the Treasury bring to the forefront the issue of fiscal responsabilit y. As a matter of fact the budget deficit, measured on a cash-basis, shows a slow but steady decline starting in 1981. After increasing, as a percent of GDP, from an average value of 3.2% in 1971-1974 to 153% in 1976-1981, it declines to 8% in 1984-5 and appears to stabi]ize around 5% in the more recent years (Table 1). Cash-based measures of the budget deficit can be however quite misleading. The Treasury may indeed resort to the use of financial arrears to cope with mounting financial difficulties. This Is indeed what happened in Morocco until 1985. Because cash-based deficits do .ot allow for the accumulation of financial arrears, they will fail to refle the full pressure that fiscal policy exerts on available resources. Conmersely, cash-based deficits will overestimate the size of the fiscal problem whenever financial arrears are being decumulated. Notlce in this respect that, after 1985, adjustment programs in Morocco have involved a sizeable reduction In the stock of a-rears. Overall, It Is more appropriate to treat the accumulation of arrears as a source of (involuntary) finance and measure the deficit on a payment order basis. If this is done for Morocco, the deficit plcture changes substantlally. Both the initial increase and the subsequent decline in the budget deflcit are more substantial when measured on a payment-order basis than on a cash basis (Table 2). This is simply due to the fact that arrears had been accumulated until 1985 and decumulated afterward. A further correction relates to interest payments. As column 3 of Table 2 shows, the latter have steadily increased as a share of GDP, compounding therefore the budget difficulties. Yet allowance should be 4 made for the fact that, under infltionary conditlons, a pote, allly conspicuous share of Interest payments represents early amortiz, on of outstandlng debt and, as such, should be considered as a (riegative) financing component. For Morocco, historlcally low Inflation rates mean that thls correction is not going to produce dramatic effects. Its impact Is nonetheless substantial, albeit declining. From column 4 of Table 2, we can see that capital gaIns on domestic debt due to Inflation were equal to 3.1% of GDP in 1984. Due to the drop In Inflatlon, they then declined to 1.3% In 1988. As a Xesult the operatlonal budget, whlch only includes real interest payments, reglstered a relatively modest deficit In 198x and a surplus in 1986. We have also corrected for valuation effects In the stock of foreign debts, by multiplying the outstanding stock at the beginning of the perlod by the excess of domestic Inflation (measured by the change In the GDP deflator) over the rate of devaluatlon (taken with respect to the nomlnal effectlve exchange rate). We feel much less confident about this correctlon insofar it overlooks valuatlon changes due for Instance to cross currency fluctuations which appear to have played a substantlal role in determlning the evolution of foreign debt indlcators for Morocco. We nonetheless report the results of such correction (column 5). Its Impact Is baslcally Inslgnlficant in 1984, but grows over tlme as domestlc Inflatlc l is no longer matched by a corresponding devaluation. The last measure we conslder is the primary deficit, which excludes all Interest payments. By excluding a component whlch Is to a large extent beyond the control of flscal authorlties, It provldes s more accurate Indicator of the effort to redress exlstlng fiscal Imbalances. The evolutlon of the prlmary deficit hlghlights the adjustment effort on the flscal front. The primary deficit was equal to 7.2% of GDP in 1983 a.nd has steadlly declined since then to reach a surplus of 1.9% of GOP In 1988. This amounts to a turnaround equal to nine percentage polnts of GDP. The Improvement In the overall and In the operational deficlts are less signlflcant due to the Increased burden of respectlvely nomlnal and real Interest payments. Summing up, it Is undeniable that Morocco has taken a declslve step on the road to redress its fiscal Imbalances. The substantlal achievements In the overall budget reflect an even more slgnlflcant Improvement In the primary deficit whlch more than compensated the rlslng burden of nomlnal Interest payments. The favourable evolutlon of 5 the budget was also facilitated by low and even negatlve real Interest rates on domestlc debt. Thls situatlon Is however comlng to an end and the Treasury Is now Forced to offer positive and hlgh real rates oF return to convince domestlc Investors to finance Its deflclt. The average cost of servlilng domestic debt Is likely to rlse qulte rapldly In the near Future, underscorlng the need for contlnulng flscal restralnt. b) the primary deficit. In this section we shall examine how the slzeable reductlon In the primary deficit was achleved. The relevant data are contained In Table 3. It is apparent how the burden of adjustment fell mostly on publlc Investment which registered a major fall fron 11.54% of GOP at the onset of the adjustment program In 1982 to only 3.61% In 1986 and recovered then, but only marginally, to around 6i In 1987 and 1988. The drop In public investment was therefore the major contrlbutlng factor In the process of fiscal retrenchment. Thls Is an unfortunate feature of the adjustment proc'ess that Morocco shares wlth many other developing countries. We shall find in a later sectlon how the decline In publlc Investment may have negatively affected the prlvate sector propensity to Invest. Table 3 shows how other Items also provlded a sizeable contribution to flscal restraint. Expenditure on goods and services fell somewhat, reflecting mostly the drop in public employees real wages and the more sober trend in public employment. Simple econometric analysis (not reported here) shows that expendlture on goods and services is not related to It ':on, suggestlng therefore that the latter was not paramount in reduL- ig public sector real wages. Finally we find that also the share of subsldies In GDP fell substantially mainly because the decline in Imported food prlces reduced the need for government Interventlo. . This Is Incldentally an interesting example of the direct impact of terms of trade fluctuatlons on the budget. A comparison between the evolution of the primary deficit, as reported in Table 2, and the behaviour of public expenditure in Table 3 already suggests that taxation did not provide a noticeable cuntribution to the Improvement In the budget. As a matter of fact taxation as a percentage of GDP fluctuates around 21% (Table 4). Had It not been for the windfall revenue attendant on the petroleum levy introduced In 1986, fiscal revenues would have actually registered a major decline over the 6 perioA 1983-'88. There are several causes behind thls unsatisfactory evolutio-i. On the one hand this was a time where, with t'ie support oF the World Bank and the IMF, the Moroccan government Introduced some far-reaching reforms in the system of both direct and indirect taxatlon. For instance the introduction of VAT in 1986 Is expected to represent in the medium-run a more efficient and more reliable source of revenue. Due to implementation problems it was however accompanied upon its Introduction by a revenue shortfall. Similarly the overhaul in the system of direct taxation with the phasing out of a set of Income taxes differentiated according to income sources and thelr consolidatlon Into - unique tax Is not likely to contribute to the budget In the very short-run. Other factors may also have helped to determine the evolution of tax revenues. For Instance it is often argued that high inflation will reduce the real value of tax revenues because of delays in revenues collectlon. This effect is unlikely to be significant in Morocco because of relatlvelv low inFlation levels and may also have been offset by the bracket creeo mechanism where taxpayers in an unlndexed system are taxed aL increasing rates because of the Impact of inflation on nomlnal inrnomes. Agaln econometric evidence does not suggest a slgnificant relatlon between the share of tax revenues in GDP and the level of Inflation. A further noticeable factor which affected the evolution of government revenues was the process of trade reform. In 1984, with the support of the World Bank, the Morocco government, in an attempt to rationalise the trade regime and reduce the protection to import- substituting productions, chose to substantially reduce Import duties and gradually phase out the so-called special import tax, an across the board tariff. The revenue shortfall attendant upon this measure was estlmated to reach 4% of GDP. Continuing budgetary difficulties prompted a reassessment of the sitjation. In 1987 the special import tariff had its rate inlcreased to 12.5%, from 5%, and its name changed (to fiscal import duty). This policy shift is likely to lead to a growing contribution of trade taxes to government revenues. The last column of Table 4 highlights the impact of terms of trade fluctuations on fiscal revenues. In Morocco production and trade of phosphate products (the main foreign exchange earners for the country) are controlled by the Office Cherifien des Phosphates (OCP), a public eneterprise. The latter contributes to the Treasury budget through tax and dividend payments. As shown in the Table, these contributions -6a- TA3LE 1 BUDGET DEFIrCT (cash-basis, before debt relief, ir, perzent of GDF) Years Years 19'' 2.9; 198: 13.64 1972 4.01 1982 9.22 1973 2.C: 1983 11.51 19I4 3.9 1984 8.07 1975 9.5' 1985 8.57 1976 12.C' 1986 5.69 197, 15.84 1987 6.11 1978 11.28 1988 5.45 1979 15.1- 1S8^ 9.0' Scurce: World Ba-.K data base. TABLE 2 BUDGET DEFICITS: VAR-CUS DEFINITIONS (as a share of GDP) cash basis payment order interest capital gains basis pavments cn dom. debt 1983 0.115 0.12I 0.049 na 1984 0.081 C.112 0.061 0.031 1985 0.086 0.096 0.062 0.030 1986 0.057 0.053 0.059 0.035 1987 0.061 0.057 0.059 0.022 1988 0.055 0.041 0.060 0.013 capital gains operational primary on foreig.n debt deficit deficit 1983 na na 0.072 1984 0.005 0.081 0.051 198' 0.019 0.066 0.034 1986 0.017 0.018 -0.006 1987 0.034 0.035 -0.00l2 1988 0.045 0.027 -0.0'.) Source: 'orld Bar. data base TABLE 3 CENTRAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE (before debt relief, in percent of GDP) Years Current Capital G & S Interests Subsidies 1971 14.12 3.72 12.51 1.01 0.60 1974 19.25 5.77 12.20 0.85 6.21 1977 18.58 18.93 14.44 1.50 2.63 1979 19.46 12.89 15.05 2.19 2.21 1981 24.60 12.33 15.42 3.88 5.30 1983 23.72 9.64 15.05 4.86 3.81 1984 24.00 8.09 13.63 6.08 4.29 1985 23.09 7.18 12.63 6.23 4.23 1986 20.62 3.61 12.20 5.92 2.50 1987 20.36 6.03 12.64 5.91 1.81 1983 2^.3: 6.34 12.17 6.01 2.13 Sc_rce: Worit Ear k da:a tese. 7 r-earhed a p-ak in 197/1 Vi, -,-n-onoitantly v. ith the phcsphate. pr.re bo,^om. ThP, hav,e been declining since (except for a small rebound in 19B 1), adding therefore substantilc,v to budgetary diffirulties. e) flwru:n 21 the budget dlefiit The impact of budgst deficits on macroeconorm,ie conditions is to a s.gniFicant extent a function of the mode of financing of the deficit Itself. It is therefore essential to take a closer look at the way budget imbalances have : een financed in " e past. Prior to 1983, foreign borrowing flnancea nearly 60% of the Treasury deficit. The avallability of foreign Finance came to Fin abruot halt in 1983, precipitating a major payment crisis. The government was Forced to rely to an unprecedented extent on Central Bank borrowing during 1983 and, to a lesser extent, 1984. This was also the period when, as it was mentioned earlier, the government increasingly resorted to the accumulation of arrears as a source of involuntary finance from the private sector. Yet the increased monetization of the deficit would have unavoidably provided fuel for inflation. It was the firm commitment by monetary authorities to eschew inflationary financing which prompted a major revision in the financing strategy. Starting in 1984 the government increasingly began tapping non-inflationary domestic sources of financing. The Treasury reliance on voluntary domestic lending was enhanced by the need to reduce the sizeable stock of financial arrears. This strategy was helped by .he partial liberalization of domestic interest rates which was associated with a major shift in the private sector portfolio composition from currency to time deposits. At the same time the ceiling on credit to the economy forced commercial banks to channel a substantial part of these financial resources to the Treasury, creating thereby a steady source of finance for government deficits. Another important component of the financing strategy was the direct sales of Treasury bills and bonds to the non-bank sector. The counterpart of this strategy was its increased cost to the Treasury. To make time deposits more palatable to commercial banks, they were excluded from the base on whict obligatory investment in Treasury bonds are calculated. Together with the reduction of arrears and the need to offer att tive (post-tax) returns on direct issues of government bonds, this measure induced a significant increase in the cost of domestic financing for the Treasury. This is -Iearly reflected in the rapid increase in the average real Interest rate on government domest ic debt, as noticed in the previous paragraph. Further iristitutional developments arz likely to reinforce this trend, iF existing pr-oposals to reduce liquidity and portfolio requirements for tne banking sector are implemented. In the last section of this paper, we shall assess the macroeconomic impact of furthering the process of financial liberalization. We can try to sum up the main conclusions of this section and draw some implications for the future course of fiscal policy in Morocco. Overall Morocco has been quite successful in coping with VormIdable financial difficulties. The foreclosing of foreign borrowing In 1983 represented a major shock to the economy and to the Treasury, more significant perhaps than the rise in international Interest rates. The two-prong response of M4croccan policy-makers relied on a sharp reduction in the Treasury i,nancing needs and a shift in the composition of finance with a view of eschewing inflationary pressures. A key to the success of this strategy was the availability of relatively cheap sourcs, of domestic finance, mostly determined by a complex system ,t Financial regulations. However the difficulties of relying at the margin on financial repression as a cheap source of funds, together with the relaxing of fiscal discip,ine in the most recent years, have already prompted a reassessment of ex'sting strategies and, perhaps merea crucially, highlighted the shiarp trade-offs that continuing budget disequilibria entail. Today the major question facing Morocco's policy- makers is 'shether the fiscal policy stance is consistent with the mainterance of low inflation, the resumption of investment and growth and the external payments constraint. Consider the not too unlikely case where foreign finance will not increase substantially in the medium-run. Under these circumstances, the failure to oersevere on the road to fiscal discipline may entail severe macroeconomic consequences. Even the perpetuation of present financing strategies of a relatively unchanged budget deficit would soon run into severe problems. First of all the bucget is still evtremely vulnerable to international interest rates and terms of trade shocks. For instance the revenue from the petroleum levy which in 1988 still represented 3.4% oF GDP is likely to vanish under increasing oil prices. Second the cost of domestic finance is likely to rise steeply in the 9 future. Again the Treasury budget would be extremely vulnerable to such evolution. Would the cost oF servicing domestic debt Increase to competitive market rates, this would add to the budget an extra burden equal to around 2% of CDP. Could Morocco resort at the margin on larger monetlzation of the deficit ? By internatiou,al standards Morocco s inflation Is typlcally low. An increase in the Inflatlon tax may then represent a palatable alternative. However, besides the danger of tampering with monetary policy and damaging the credibility of the Central Bank commitment against Inflation, thero. Is ac-tually little room for a substantial contribution to budget Financlng from Increased monetizatlon of the deficit. We will show in the next sectlon that, for Morocco, estimated elasticities From a system of assets demand indicate an extremely unfavourable trade-off between inflation and monetary financing. Continuing reliance on non-inflationary sources of domestlc finance is thereFore essential to keep Inflation under check. However this strategy could result in large increases In domestic real rates of interest. Besides putting into jeopardy budget equilibria, this would most likely crowd out investment. Moreover even if the increase In interest rates did not materialize and the perpotuation of a system of financlal regulations guaranteed a source of inexpensive finance for the Treasury, the impact of unabated budget deficits on investment and on growth would still be signi ficant because of their effects on credit markets. We shall examine this issue in section 4. -9a- TABLE 4 TAX REVEENJES (as a share of GDP) Total Income Taxes on goods Taxes on revenue taxes and serv. int. trade 1971 0.1'849 0.C282? 0.07604 0.02582 1972 0.14401 0.02814 0.07402 0.02407 1973 0.16157 0.03206 0.07454 0.02879 1974 0.21112 0.03294 0.06797 0.03625 1975 0.23329 0.07023 0.07320 0.04331 1976 0.20292 0.04011 0.07688 0.04184 1977 0.21672 0.05145 0.08326 0.05187 1978 0.2120i 0.05343 0.08012 0.04993 1979 0.22246 0.05364 0.07990 0.05477 1980 0.20506 0.04507 0.07836 0.05562 1981 0.22570 0.04765 0.07642 0.06190 1982 0.22046 0.04125 0.08410 0.06235 1983 0.21272 0.04380 0.08768 0.05307 1984 0.2v890 0.04438 0.08510 0.05009 1985 0.20653 0.04337 0.08376 0.04456 1986 0.18891 0.04040 0.07089 0.03629 1987 0.20679 0.0.475 0.07656 0.03561 1988 0.22582 0.34717 0.07793 0.03954 petroleum other OCP levy taxes contributions 1971 0.00000 0.01836 0.00182 1972 0.00000 0.01778 0.00176 1973 0.00003 0.02617 0.00609 1974 0.00000 0.07395 0.06306 1975 0.00000 0.04655 0.06776 1976 0.00000 0.04408 0.02316 1977 0.00000 0.03014 0.01843 1978 0.00000 0.02852 0.01450 1979 0.00000 0.03415 0.01128 1980 0.00000 0.02601 0.01080 1981 0.00000 0.03973 0.01641 1982 0.00000 0.03276 0.00581 1983 0.00000 0.02817 0.00756 1984 0.00000 0.02933 0.00979 1985 0.00000 0.03484 0.01342 1986 0.02444 0.01689 0.00000 1987 0.02782 0.02204 0.00290 1988 0.03375 0.02743 0.00401 Source: World Bank data base TABLE 5 IMPACT ON INFLATION CF A 1% INCREASE IN THE GDP SHARE OF MONETARY FINANCING Initial inflation low elasticities High elasticities 4% 7.5% 7.6% 6% 9.8% 11.1% 8% 12.9% 16.9% 10% 16.7% 26.4% Source: own calculaticns 10 3. ASSETS DEMAND, SEI-;INORAGE AND THE INFLATION TAX. Received wisdom argues that, following the drying up of commercial lending after 1982, developing countries had to make a twin transfer of resources: one abroad to foreign creditors insofar as new lending had fallen much below the required service on outstanding external debt; the other internal, toward the governnent, to the extent that in several developing countries the State had taken onto itself the burden of servicing foreign debt. Together with the increase in interest rates and the fall in terms of trade, this has often meant the disruption of budgetary equilibria, already jeopardised in many cases by previous unsustainable fiscal policies. The inflexibility of the tax system, the downward rigiditv of fiscal expenditure (with the noticeable exception of public investment) and the thinnes of domestic financial markets left then little choice to local policy-makers but to monetize the fiscal deficits with sometlmes calamitous consequences on the inflation rate. Under this interpretation, the exceptional inflation record in Morocco is undoubtedly puzzling. In the previous secticn it was shown how financial repression, by channeling low cost funds to the Treasury, was instrumental in a strategy of relying on non-inflationary sources oF budegt financing. Yet the question remains of why Morocco's pollcy- makers remain staunchly opposed to even a limited monetlzatlon of the deficit and a greater reliance on the inflation tax. As a matter of fact inflation in Morocco is extremely low, 2.3% in 1988, even by the most stringent international standards. A recent report (United Nations- World Bank, 1990), wh le not explictly advocating an increase In Inflation, argues nonetheless that there is some mileage for boosting revenues from the inflation tax. The issue however cannot be solved on purely theoretical grounds as the inflationary implications of deficlt monetization depend on the response of money base demand to changes in inflation and interest rates. In what follows we shall argue that the outlook for greater monetization of the budget deficlt In Morocco Is altogether unfavourable. If we also consider the destabilising effects on Morocco's social fabrics and the loss of Central Bank credlbility that a higher inflation would Imply, we can perhaps understand the firm commitment of the country's policy-makers in favour of prlce stability. The scope for increased government revenue from seignorage and the 11 inFlation tat< is determined by the private sector's choice of assets. In this paragraph we rely on a standard Tobin's portfolio approach to analyse the demand for currency, demand and time deposits. Other assets are not included in our analysis on the ground that, with the exception of real assets, they play a minor role in the private sector's choices. In what follows we assume that the demand for each asset Is related to its own return, the other assets' returns and the level of income. As a proxy for the return on real assets we use the (expected) inflation rate, which however is not observable. We assume that expectations are formed rationally and depend on the set of inFormatlon available at time t-i, which is defined to include the lagged level of prices, the money supply, the wage rate and the exchange rate. According to our estimates, the last variable does not contribute significantly to the prediction of future prices. This prellminary evidence suggests that, for Morocco, the pass-through from the nominal exchange rate to domestic prices is Fairly weak accounting therefore for the fact that a sizeable real depreciation did not translate into higher inflation. Similarly the significant impact of wages on prices supports the claim that wage moderation (the real minimum wage declined by 7.3% from 1983 to 1988, after increasing by 17% in the three prevlous years) was instrumental in containing inflation. The fitted value from the price equation is used as an estimate for expected inflation. In the process of estimation, we rely on Pagan's (1984) procedure and use our proxy for expected inflation as an instrument for actual inflation. This procedure is designed to yield consistent standard errors for the coefficients. We still have to determine whether the system of assets demand should be expressed In nominal terms (with prices included among the explanatory variables and the relevant homogeneity assumptions tested) or in real terms. We take the first course for the sake of generality and assume thereby that assets demand do not fully respond instantaneously to changes in prices. We also allow for the possibility of lagged adjustr1ient to income and interest rates variations. Therefore the estimating equation for a generic asset MW reads as: In MJt ao + a, In Pt + a2 In Pt_l + a3 In Yt + a4 In Yt + as it + a6 it1 + a7 Tre + ae In M(I) t-i t ~ Mt-i 12 where p and Y denote the prlce and Income level respectively, "I" represents the vector of assets' returns and Tre Is expected Inflatlon. We would expect that in the long-run the prlce elastlclty of assets demand is equal to one, I.e. that assets demands are homogeneous of degree one in prices. Formally this implies t,Lat a1+a2=i-a8. We can reparametrlze the prevlous equation to test this restrict3on: In (Mj/p)t = ao + (a,-1) In Pt + a3 ln Yt + 84 ln Yt + as It + a6 i + a7 wet + (a8+a2) In pt_, + a8 ln (MJ/p)t_1 (2) If long-run price homogeneity holds, we have ln (Mj/p)t = ao - (a2+a8) A In Pt + a3 In Yt + 84 In Yt + as it + a(, 1 + a7 wre + a8 ln (M /P)t (3) Eq. (3) shows that Imposing long-run prlce homogenelty In a context where assets are expressed in real terms adds a backward-looklng Inflation term, A In p, to the equation itself. This term however does not reflect any substitution effects between real and financlal assets, but only lagged adjustment to price changes. Traditional money demand equations where Inflationary expectations are simply modelled in a backward-looking fashion may therefore mistakenly Interpret the significance of A In p as evidence of substitution toward real assets, whereas only a process of dynamic adjustment Is Involved. Our approach allows to distinguish between these two effects by separately evaluating the statistical signlficance of A In p and Tr . Admittedly though, the coexistence of these two effects may be difficult to justlfy on purely theoretical grounds. In the estimatlon process we include in the tector of assets' returns ("i") only the Interest rate on time depo_its, I . Some demand deposits are also remunerated, but their return moves in a almost perfectly collinear way with the one on time deposits. We have therefore Included the remunerated component of demand deposlts in the aggregate of time deposits. We can now describe the results of the estimatlon of the system of assets demand. Our estimation strategy Is as follows. We start from the more general dynamic specification In eq. 3 and restrlct the model to obtain a parsimonious representation of the data generatlng 1 3 process. In what foll-ws ,e only report the F.nal e,quation. All equations are estimated over the 1974-1988 period. The last year however is saved to test For out-of-sample stability. We begin by the demand for currency. A In (CUR /pt) -. -1.10 itd + .30 In Y - .60 In (Pt/Pt_1) t t ( 17i (. 17t (.07) (.14) - .70 In (CURt iPt- l) DW = 2.01 SER .013 LM - .25 Hendry = 1.47 The demand for currency (CC9E) is significantly related to the interest rate on time deposits (i ) and to income. Actual inflation appears in the equation with a short-run elasticity of .60. This is not necessarily, as mentioned earlier, an indication of significant substitution possibilities between currency and real assets, but may simply reflect the fact that nominal demand for currency fully adjusts to changes in the price level only in the long-run. The coefficient on expected inflation instead is not signiFicantly difFerent from zero and bears the wrong (positive) sign. Jointly estimating the price and the currency equations (and testing for the expectational restrictions) did not improve the results. The variable 7re therefore has been eliminated from the final equation. Finally the hypotheses that nominal demand for currency be unit-elastic in the long run with respect to the price level and to income are not rejected by the data (tio = .94). As diagnostic tools we rely on the Hendry test for out-oF-sample stability and the Lagrange multiplier test for serial correlation. Both are distributed as X (1). They do not provide any indications of misspecification. We now turn to the equation for demand deposits (DD). In (DD /Pt) = -11.65 - 8.46 i td 1.03 ln (pt/pt1) + 1.20 ln Yt + t t (4.26) (2.96) t 41) (.37) .76 ln Y (.26) DW = 1.43 SER. = .033 LM = 1.56 Hendry = .81 Demand deposits have been defined to exclude saving deposits. 14 Following this modification, we find that both inflation and the return on time deposits pla>E a significant role in affecting demand deposits. The long-run income elasticity is equal to 1.96 and significantly different from one. Once again expected inflation does not contr'bute in a statistically significant way to the equation. There is no sign of misspecification as indicated by the usual battery of tests. The last component of our menu oF assets are time deposits (TD): A In (TD /Pt) = -1.54 + 6.94 I td + .96 [(In Y - In (TD[ /Pt 1)] t t (.8D) (4.22)t (.18) t t- t DW = 1.97 SER = .09 LM = .02 Hendry = .18 As expected, time deposits respond positively, albeit not very significantly, to an increase in their own rate oF return. The dynamic specification of the equation is very simple. There is no evidence of lagged adjustment to prices as indicated by the insignificant coefficient on actual inflation. On the same ground, also expected inflation has been excluded from the final equation. It was not possible to reject the hypothesis that the demand for time deposits Is unit-elastic with respect to income (F1,9 = .54). The LM and Hendry tests Fail to point to some misspecification problems. Overall the previous results indicate that the demand for monetary assets In Morocco is strongly influenced by the patterns oF returns. The estimated semi-elastlcltles on the interest rate on time-deposits suggest potentially conspicuous shifts in portfolio composition In response to variation of the structure of interest rates. There is however less Indication of strong substitution posslbilltles with respect to real assets. Our proxy for expected inflation never proved to be significant In any of the three equations. It is not apparently a problem of multicollinearity insofar as the coefficient on actual inflation was quite well determined even in the more general specifications. It is not either a problem of statistical methodology. Our approach should provide at least consistent estimates oF the coefficients and of their standard errors. As mentioned earlier, more eFficient simultaneous estimation methods which also allow for the expectational restrictions fall to change the basic findings. Perhaps our proxy for expected lnflatlon Is not well specified. Alternatively, expectations may to a large extent 15 have an adaptive form. We leave the matter unsettled. To c,-mpute the amount oF monetary financing the government can count upon, we must allow for the fact that in Morocco a distlnction must be made between reserve requirements, which apply only to demand deposits, and liquidity requirements, which force commercial banks t,- invest a fixed share oF their deposits in low yield treasury bills. Recent financial sector reForms have however substantlally inc reased the interest rate paid on liquidity requirements which now approaches market rates levels. We include therefore liquldity requirements in the domestic public debt. The narrowly defined monetary base (MB) is thereFore equal to: MBS, = c t + rrdd DDt (4) where rrdd is the reserve requirement coeFficient for demand deposits. At any point of time the amount oF monetary financing is equal to the change in the monetary base. As a share of nominal GDP, the amount of monetary Financing, A MB t/(pt Yt) is equal to the rate of change of monetary base, (A MBt/MBt), times the GDP share of MB, (MBt/ptYt). We can now use eq. 4, together with our estimates of the demand of currency and demand deposits, to evaluate the relationship between inflation and the amount oF monetary financing. We focus on a steady state situation and arbitrarily impose that demand deposits be unit- elastic with respect to income. As a result, the growth rate of MB will be equal to the sum of output growth (n) and inflation (Tr). Similarly the GDP share of MB will depend on the level of nominal interest rates and, possibly. of inflation: CUR rrdd D r d A MB/ (pY) = +n) CUR + rrddDD = (Tr+n) [ A eacr+ rrdd B e 9 ] p Y (5) where the coefficients A and a (B and 6) are computed from our estimates of the currency (demand deposits) equation. In assessing the value oF a and 6 we face a basic ambiguity. Changes in the inflation rate can have a direct impact on the demand for monetary base to the extent that they lead to cor.-esponding variations in nominal interest rate. We assume this to be fully the case. But changes in Tr have also a direct effect on the demand for currency and deposits. However if we interpret 16 the signiFicant coefficient of actual inflation in our estimates as simply evidence of lagged adjustment, then this effect should not reasonably play a role in this steady state kitid of analysls. If alternatlvely we believe that expectations are adaptive and our results reflect the existence of significant substitution possibilities with real assets, then inflation should have an indipendent effect. Notice that, In the latter case, changes in inflation will exert a larger Impact on the demand for monetary base. In what follows we allow for both posslbllltles. We can use eq. 5 to compute the effect of a one percent change In the inflation rate on the quantity of monetary financing as a share of GDP. We take GDP growth to be equal to 4 percent. From eq. 5, it Is clear that this derivative is a function of the Initial share In GDP of currency and time deposits, which in turn depends on the Inflation rate Itself. We can also compute the inverse derivative, which measures the Ir-rease in the inflation rate attendant on a one percent Increase in the GDP share of monetary financing (Table 5). Our estimates suggest that the inflationary impact of higher monetization Increases very rapldly and the trade-offs between Inflation and inflation tax worsens zubstantially as inflation increases. This provides considerable support to the cholce of Moroccan policy-makers not to rely on inflationary forms of deficit finance. 17 lN. I\L'KTM-'N AN' `AVINi A 'I LLIIIDN AN h'sth rat-~ -I in.-~?tm;nr--r e-.ents a basic condit'ion fo-r ru-taine' !n.x-agc~ in ec-nomn,- gr-oxth -,e the long-term. Since 1992 ho\ever the fGUrre-nt Fpicer 'p chare of invostment in Moro-cco has been stoa1i'. falling %,ith the o nl, e<-eption of 19_RS'. raising increasing c2Dncer nr about th"- long-run perFs-pecives oF the economy. L,oo.king at tho >:-nstant price ratio bet.v.Feen int-stment and iGP wouldi onlP accentuate tr.- Fall' in in .est`ien, beause .' the irncrease in the real price of in. estmentF goods .attesndant on the real deprecdation. More wsiorry,ingly porhaps, the drop ir .acital a-cuTnlation is a generalised cne, in.dylving bot,h pub:i> andr pr-i'ate in.estment. Contra-v to initial eXving the pre.icus Fbias a&falnst labourintensive productions:', an i-crease in the of c-apital wou allow the same level of grow>th to be ae;ed ith a l. er volume oF investment. LUnder this nt-rpretIatln thD ropi in inestunt would on.;, represent the out-ome F atcusting to a no.. constellatioDn of factor prices. Empirical evidence -r a roJatiel> large samFle co developing countries (Faini and de !-:-. 199s rufLggesto that CcsDt ,-F capital considerations can account on'. f-r a small fraction of the fall in investment and other factors t!he-ref-re must be- at .%vork. In ,,,hat follows:, We shall assess the r>-.-s,>- F9--f thlis aFproach for the --ase of Morocco. We- ro -r. a smzer m.de' rf a Firm. The fir,m is assumed to a m:<1-!7e itS rne-t v-. -rtk. sub c-- 1- a standard nsoolasK' -ai p'-oluctio-n r--t.- r-cr.t.-a-t . tl- the itionalt s-t-up hov-.e,vr. financ,ial a--sl ' h a shFi -'iant boearing on real d ' E o mr-'.-<' th>e 9.mQ>a-t I f 9nancia, variables by assuming that e.- Ferhap tF au-- .f ta :nsiderat ios). Ar internal sciin fc:r the optimal dett choice of the firm still! e<1-ts. though. prnxbided that v.e assume that h!gher debt, relativel',y tD the firm's capita! stor k, is as,lt '.52th increasing agenc, costs. Emal'l, because of -oQnstraints in the credit market, at each point of time the adebt to capital r.ticfk rati,- of the firm is b.ound by an upper ronstraint. Formally,: maK ( F. Y Nt - qt It + Et 1itr)-1 1~~~~~~~~~~~ t- C(t 'It Kt!] (. s.t. K f* qt Kt (7; t FKt.N (8' KCt fI:iKs_, + It1c 'x.here. in standard notations, Y, N, K and I represent the level of pr oduction, employment, capital stock and investment respectively, whereas B denotes the outstanding stock of debt. The function et ! with c >0. cjj') and c2<0, is the agency cost function, which is. assumed to be quadratic. The output price is indicated as p, the wage as w, the price oF investment goods as q, while r and i denote the interest rate and the discount rate respectively. We assume that I+i= (l+r) (I+k) N.here k is a multiplicative risk premium. Finally d is the depreciation rate. Eq. 6 is the leverage constraint whi-ch defines the madmum amount of debt as a time varying proportion (E*) cf the capital stock, while eq. 7 and 8 describe the production relationships and the capital accumulation identity respectively. Suppose first that the debt constra;nt is not binding. It can be easily shown that, at an optimum, debt Vill be a fixed proportion , say y, of nominal capital stock. In turn v is a function of the risk premium k and oF the parameters aFfecting the position of the agency cost function 2 Notice that y does not depend on the interest rate. As matter of fact, variations in r (or in the discount rate i) affect the level of investment, not the con.position of its financing. The choice oF y in turn afFects the demand for capital which is otherw.ise determined in a standard way. IF we consider the case where the debt constraint is binding (i.e. B*i:n''r inr F:r--:i,ti.:n. it c-arn t: >, shown that the optimll -> ta*. ¶t>'K ..:'. i:. n a furw't .-r of zutrut.-F the r,aa cost o-f capit-l rini the Aa.la liti- --f d4t:t. FsrniaJiv: KC K Y . -4 i (1 p 4- I arameters r and p den.:te the :--rprt> ta rate and the percentage reduction in q indiuc- t. the s - ,r fiscal and financial in-entives available t, investors in Mi.-r~-r-. Fu'l details For the calculations of r arnd p are provilr-l in W-Drlid dlk (1990?. fJne -r'2,blem .w;ith the Formulatio-n of eq. 10 is that it containr one oh' i-uF'] Ssndigenous variable, the le,el of output Y . In what follows we rel; lr th- Following procDedure. It is assumed that, because oF delivery lags, flrms must determine their desired level of output, and therefore their investment, one period in advance. They will need therefore to predict, based on available inFormation, the optimal level of capaoity outrut For the Following period. This will in turn determine their demand fo r investmenrt gcods. We alsco assume that expectations about thp determinants of the output decision can be simply modelled by a Fir-st-o-rder autoregressive process. The expected, optimal level of cutput (t- Iy t ' ,,iJll thereFoDre be equal to: t-' IYt =Y (Ft- I , '>t- I,'t _t-I PUbt_ tv-1'st-1! II w.here the inFormatilon set has been augmented1 to include both Ipub (the level cF public investnment on the ground that this may affect the pro-ducti,on relationship > and MS (the stock of money, as a further predictor of prices). In estimating eq. I 1 we must allow For the fact that t Yt is not observatle. Howeve-, under rational expectations, it will YVfetr From actual output Y only for a random term uncorrelated w\.ith an'. available informaticn at t-I. We can therefore use the actual product :-n level Y Es the dependent variable and take the Fitted '.alue oF eq. I I as the estimate of expected output. 2'. estimating eq. 11, it is now possible to take into account the endogeneity oF Y in eq. 10. We follow again Pagan's (198t suggestion and take the estimated value of Y (Y.F) in eq. 1I as an instrument For the actual level oF output in eq. 10. We present First the estimates of 20 ~~(ri .u(1:. i 1 +C.: (I, . Ye + C. +9Mo - l ! F-u' k.K+t tim s.C di:.9 N. 'XV) LV\! = AX-. WK: - .r5 LNAm =.5 w,here- dil iF a dummy variab-e which takes a '.r!ue of I in coDrrespcndanm2e of the agricultural negative supply shocks in 1981, 19.33 and 1937. The wage rate dc1es rot pro.tide a si-ni6ant ccntributicn to the equation. This may be attributed to- measuremenrt errors (\We use an indicator of the minimum wage) or to the fal-t that labcur does represent a signifIcant ccnstrdint. T he cocst of c acpital instead appears to plaY a more significant rcle together with public inv,estment and the money supply. As a diagnostic t-ol, we relv on the Lagirange Multiplier test for serial correlati:n, which does not indicate any significant problems. Mloving> nov.' to the investment equation, we find that: A In lt -3 .555+ 1.9 4 A InY - .6 In (l'Y - - .7 In (e/F: (q1.82) ( .83) t '1 (c/pt- Bt 5-.67 (2 /Y) 2 R -.50 DW= 1.i1 SER P .12 whe;re I represents private investment. E /Y, the ratic oF firms credit to ';Ci7, is used as a pro