Effective Cooperation
                              on Transboundary Waters:
Photo: Mattias Granberg




                              A Practical Perspective
                                                                                             By David Grey, Claudia Sadoff and Genevieve Connors1

                          Building effective cooperation on transboundary wa-                       Uses of International Watercourses was 27 years in
                          ters is always a lengthy and complex journey. Embrac-                     preparation prior to its adoption by the UN General
                          ing cooperation is no simple task for a nation state,                     Assembly in 1997. Now, 12 years later, only 16 states
                          not least because of the perceived costs of the erosion                   have ratified the Convention and it has not entered
                          of sovereignty, however small that erosion might be.                      into force. As a consequence, despite the irreplaceable
                          While there are many examples of where cooperation is                     role of water in lives, livelihoods and production,
                          non-existent or weak, there are also examples – across                    there is no universal treaty in force to regulate the
                          countries and across time – of effective cooperation.                     use and protection of shared waters (Salman, 2007).
                          This essay examines these issues through a practi-                        The absence of this kind of universal treaty has not
                          tioner’s lens to draw a few lessons from experience on                    precluded cooperation between sovereign states, nor
                          why countries cooperate and how cooperation can                           does it imply that the principles are not broadly ac-
                          be achieved.                                                              cepted, but clearly most states are not ready to commit
                                                                                                    themselves to a binding legal obligation.
                          Why do countries cooperate?                                                  The record to date suggests, quite simply, that
                          Why do countries cooperate on transboundary waters?                       countries do not cooperate in the management of
                          At first glance, the obvious answer is that coopera-                      transboundary waters because they are compelled
                          tion is by definition good and is, therefore, the right                   by an ethic of cooperation. They cooperate when the
                          course of action. This is asserted time and again as a                    net benefits of cooperation are perceived to be greater
                          first principle in countless international meetings and                   than the net benefits of non-cooperation, and when
                          proclamations. Yet the reality is more nuanced. The                       the distribution of these net benefits is perceived to be
                          UN Convention on the Law of the Non-navigational                          fair. In other words, states work together when doing


                          1
                           The findings, interpretations, and conclusions in this paper are entirely the authors’. They do not necessarily represent the views of the
                          World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.



                                                                                                                                                                        15
     so offers special economic and political advantages                     The scale of benefits derived and the perceived fairness
     over unilateral development, and when these larger                      of the benefit sharing arrangement together with the
     benefits are shared.                                                    political ideal of solidarity between the three coun-
         Perceptions are pivotal. States must believe that                   tries have sustained substantive cooperation and a
     greater economic benefits will be gained and distribut-                 strong river basin organisation on the Senegal River
     ed equitably. Indeed, the role of perceptions in a coun-                (Yu, 2008).
     try’s cooperation calculus underscores the importance                       It is our view that an increasingly important and
     of shared, trusted information. Perceptions are often                   compelling driver toward effective cooperation is the
     distorted by inaccurate or mistrusted information,                      management of water-related risks (e.g. of floods) com-
     but might be tempered by more credible information.                     mon to some or all riparian states within a basin. This
     Perceptions can also be influenced by historical ten-                   is an example of the third type of benefit described
     sions and suspicions, which might be lessened through                   above. This can also be seen as a growing focus on
     sustained dialogue. We will return later to these central               managing the destructive impacts of water, relative
     themes of knowledge and dialogue.                                       to capturing the productive potential of water – both
         Benefits themselves go beyond the obvious, and                      of which are key aspects of achieving water security.2
     take different forms (Sadoff and Grey, 2002). This                      In recent years, there have been growing concerns
     describes four types of benefits: environmental benefits                globally regarding the uncertainties of our climate
     to the “river” (e.g. improved water quality, conserved                  future and, in particular, the impact of a changing
     biodiversity); economic benefits from the “river” (e.g.                 climate on water resources. Taken together with other
     increased food and energy production); reduction of                     changing “climates” – changes to demographic, fi-
     costs because of the “river” (e.g. reduced geo-political                nancial, economic and political climates – the future
     tensions, enhanced flood management); and benefits                      challenges in managing the world’s water resources
     beyond the “river” (catalysing wider cooperation and                    look daunting and the risks great.
     economic integration). Any one of these four benefit                        Co-riparian states can manage these risks that they
     types can promote cooperation. The broader the basket                   face by pooling their resources to enhance informa-
     of benefits, the greater is the scope for structuring                   tion and early warning systems on their changing
     mutually beneficial cooperation.                                        hydrologic variability and by fostering system-wide
         If these kinds of enhanced benefits are to be gen-                  river basin management. Climate change raises the
     erated, they also must be shared – in a manner that                     stakes of non-cooperation, encouraging nation states
     is perceived to be fair. This can mean the separation                   not only to capture additional economic benefits, but
     of the physical location of river development where                     also to manage better their growing common risks. In
     benefits are derived, from the physical location where                  transboundary river basins, existing risks are likely to
     benefits are distributed. For example, in the Senegal                   be intensified by climate change. Effective cooperation
     River Basin, the three countries of Mali, Mauritania                    in transboundary basin management could become a
     and Senegal – through the OMVS (the Senegal River                       singularly effective risk management strategy.
     Basin Development Authority) – developed a clear                            History suggests that a perception of common risks
     methodology and framework to first quantify and                         can be particularly compelling motivation to manage
     then allocate the benefits and costs of multi-purpose                   and share these risks through cooperation. Coopera-
     investments across the entire basin. The Manantali                      tion between Canada and the Unites States on the
     Dam, for example, which is located entirely inside                      Columbia River, for example, was catalysed in large
     western Mali, was constructed through the OMVS in                       part by recurring and sometimes devastating floods.
     the 1980s for hydropower, irrigation and navigation                     This is true even though – and this is important – the
     benefits to be distributed across all three countries.                  perceived economic benefits of flood control were


     2
       Water security can be defined as the “availability of an acceptable quantity and quality of water for health, livelihoods, ecosystems and
     production, coupled with an acceptable level of water-related risks to people, environments and economies”. See D. Grey and C. W. Sadoff,
     “Sink or Swim? Water Security for Growth and Development” in Water Policy Vol. 9, No. 6. pp 545- 571. 2007.



16
considerably less than those of other benefits from
the Treaty. Energy was the other key driver of the 1961
Columbia River Treaty and the new storage dams,
constructed under the Treaty and cooperatively op-
erated, enabled significantly more power generation
than could otherwise have been produced by unilateral
action (Yu, 2008).
   Today, similar processes may play out in the im-
mense Ganges-Brahmaputra-Meghna (GBM) Basin,
which is shared by Bangladesh, Bhutan, China, India,
and Nepal. The GBM is characterised by the world’s
highest mountains (including Mount Everest), greatest
floodplains, and largest basin population, with over
500 million people, many of whom are very poor.
Added to these superlatives are: a unique monsoonal
climate, with 50 percent of precipitation in 15 days and
90 percent of runoff in 4 months; very little hydraulic
infrastructure, with only 30 days of flow in artificial
storage (compared to the 900 days of storage in the
Colorado and Murray-Darling basins (Briscoe and
Malik, 2006); extreme pollution (with consequent
ecosystem damage and biodiversity loss); and very
limited existing transboundary cooperation. Climate
models suggest that monsoon intensity could increase
and glaciers retreat, while populations, cities, indus-
tries and economies continue to grow rapidly. The
risks faced by the basin’s populations today are already
high: 70 million people in India and Bangladesh were
seriously affected by the 2007 monsoon, 4,500 were
killed, and crops across 75,000 km2 were destroyed.
Although the dynamics are complex and causality
is difficult to determine, it is possible that there are
already large numbers of “climate migrants” leaving
the basin, temporally or even permanently.
   Future risks are undoubtedly high and could poten-
tially be mitigated through cooperation. Joint institu-
tions for information sharing could help predict and
monitor the basin’s changing hydrology and underpin
early warning systems, thus enhancing both agricul-
tural productivity and disaster preparedness. Coop-
erative infrastructure development and/or operation
                                                           Photo: Arne Hoel/World Bank




could help regulate river flows, to mitigate floods and
droughts, generate power and irrigate fields. Coopera-
tive environmental management could enhance water
quality and ensure environmental flows for ecosystem
health. And all of this cooperative engagement could
improve regional relationships “beyond the river”.


                                                                                         17
     How is effective cooperation achieved?                       (investing in natural and man-made infrastructure) and
     There are no blueprints for achieving cooperation –          managing (investing in institutions, information and ca-
     indeed it is often unclear what is meant by the term         pacity) basin-wide transboundary river flows. While the
     cooperation itself. The debate tends to be cast as an        latter remains an aspiration probably not yet achieved in
     all-or-nothing proposition implying that “cooperation”       any transboundary basin, there are increasing examples
     is an absolute, in direct opposition to “water wars”.        of effective transboundary cooperation.
     In reality there are innumerable practical avenues of            Different modes of cooperation must be considered
     cooperation that states can undertake to their mutual        in response to different circumstances, and will de-
     advantage, each with different potential benefits and dif-   pend on many factors. A continuum can be conceived
     ferent associated costs. Effective cooperation can range     from unilateral action (independent, non-transparent
     from simple information sharing and hazard warning           national planning and management), to coordination
     protocols, to a fully integrated approach to developing      (sharing information regarding national planning and


18
                                                                                    Effective cooperation on an international watercourse
                                                                                is any action or set of actions by riparian states that leads
                                                                                to enhanced management or development of the water-
                                                                                course to their mutual satisfaction.

                                                                                    While the reasons and the mechanisms for coop-
                                                                                eration may be increasing, and increasingly apparent,
                                                                                getting there remains a difficult journey and typically
                                                                                requires a conscious, multi-year effort by all parties.
                                                                                But practical experience does tell us something about
                                                                                how to get there. Building the enabling environment
                                                                                – and in particular knowledge, trust and confidence
                                                                                among co-riparian states – is usually the first step in
                                                                                building cooperative transboundary institutions. The
                                                                                ownership of the cooperation agenda must be entirely
                                                                                with concerned riparian countries, in order to ensure
                                                                                commitment and endurance. However, experience
                                                                                suggests that invited third-party facilitation can be
                                                                                useful, especially on large international river basins
                                                                                with tense pasts and complex futures. Third party
                                                                                facilitation by trusted brokers and conveners can help
                                                                                generate impartial knowledge and analyses, create a
                                                                                neutral space for dialogue, and ultimately help secure
                                                                                financing for cooperative investment. We have learned
                                                                                that this facilitation must be patient, respectful and
                                                                                reliable over a long period of time, possibly a decade or
                                                                                more, and that it must almost invariably be low-profile.
                                                                                “No-footprint” is a useful rule, unless a footprint has
                                                                                a specific and strategic value.
                                                                                    Process is almost as important as product, at least
                                                            Photo: Xu Jianchu




                                                                                in the early days, and can be costly. Time spent build-
                                                                                ing effective communications, working relationships
                                                                                and a level playing field of knowledge and skill is an
                                                                                essential investment for reaching sound negotiation
                                                                                outcomes. The process can be as diverse as neces-
management), to collaboration (adaptation of national                           sary; shared experience, joint learning, round tables,
plans for mutual benefits), to joint action (joint plan-                        cooperative assessments can all be part of the process
ning, management or investment).                                                tool box. Starting from a low base might mean nego-
    For each international basin the optimal mode of                            tiating a “shared vision”, which sets a goal of a better
cooperation will depend on a mix of factors including:                          future, and then builds shared knowledge to provide
hydrologic characteristics, the economics of cooperative                        the evidence to change the perceptions of benefits and
investments, numbers and relationships of riparians,                            catalyse cooperation.
and the costs of parties coming together. It may not                                There are many stories of “how” the path to real
necessarily be the case that “more” cooperation reaps                           cooperation has been or is being explored – a variety of
“more” benefits in all river basins (Sadoff and Grey,                           pathways to cooperation. Two evolving examples help
2005). The art is in identifying “effective cooperation”,                       illuminate this point, one based on informal dialogue,
a term that deserves clear definition.                                          the other rooted in high level institutional structures.


                                                                                                                                                19
                                                                                                                              Photo: Arne Hoel/World Bank
         Among the countries that share the Rivers of the          cooperative regional assessments and analyses, capacity
     Greater Himalayas and where cooperation today is very         building and investments in the Nile Basin.
     limited, the current “Abu Dhabi Dialogue” (ADD)                  In both examples, shared knowledge and patient
     provides a path of informal consultation. Each year           dialogue are the common themes – however different
     it brings together senior political, government, and          the paths to cooperation might otherwise be. Knowl-
     non-government participants from seven countries.             edge is essential to identify the common opportunities
     Through non-representative, non-formal, and non-              and risks of transboundary water management, and to
     attributable dialogue around the themes of “common            structure equitable benefit sharing arrangements. Sus-
     problems seeking common solutions”, participants              tained, information-based dialogue is essential to build
     build knowledge, relationships and trust. Together            a shared understanding, to enable productive negotia-
     they have defined a shared vision of “a knowledge-based       tions, and to achieve robust cooperative outcomes.
     partnership of states fairly managing and developing             So, states that are cooperating on international
     the Rivers of the Greater Himalayas from the sum-             rivers will almost invariably have worked long and
     mits to the seas”. To materialise this vision, the ADD        hard together to build trust, knowledge and institu-
     Knowledge Forum has been launched in parallel to              tions – often, but not always, with patient, trusted and
     bring together key knowledge institutions and to fi-          committed external support. Their analysis, explicit
     nance collaborative research.                                 or implicit, individual or collective, will have dem-
         The Nile Basin Initiative (NBI) illustrates a different   onstrated that the benefits of cooperation are greater
     path. Since 1999 the NBI has been guided by a Council         than the benefits of non-cooperation. The choices that
     of Ministers and supported by a dedicated NBI Secre-          they have made will therefore have been rational. They
     tariat in Uganda. More recently, offices were established     may still have much work to do to ensure that planned
     for two sub-basins in the Nile: the Eastern Nile Techni-      benefits are actually being derived and being shared
     cal Regional Office in Ethiopia, and the Nile Equatorial      fairly. But they have had the courage to change, mov-
     Lakes Coordination Unit in Rwanda. These offices,             ing from a past of non-cooperation towards a future
     working in a coordinated manner, are undertaking              of effective cooperation.


     References
     Salman, S. (2007) The United Nations Watercourses                and Sharing Benefits. Water International, 30:4,
        Convention Ten Years Later: Why Has its Entry into            420-427.
        Force Proved Difficult? Water International, 32:1,         Yu, W. (2008) Benefit Sharing in International Riv-
        1-15, & pers. comm.                                           ers: Findings from the Senegal River Basin, the
     Sadoff, C. and D. Grey. (2002) Beyond the River: The             Columbia River Basin, and the Lesotho Highlands
        Benefits of Cooperation on International Rivers,              Water Project. World Bank AFTWR Working Paper
        Water Policy, 4, 389-403.                                     1, November.
     Sadoff, C. and D. Grey. (2005) Cooperation on                 Briscoe, J. Malik, R. (2006) India’s Water Economy:
        International Rivers: A Continuum for Securing                Bracing for a Turbulent Future. The World Bank.



20