THE MANUFACTURING SECTOR AND THE STRUCTURE OF INDUSTRIAL PROTECTION IN NIGERIA Table of Contents Page No. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS • . • • • . • . . • • . • . • • • . • • . • • • • • • • • • . • • • • • . i-vi • I. THE MANUFACTURING SECTOR: PAST PERFORMANCE .••.••.•••.•.••.• Growth and Structural Change in Nigerian Manufacturing • 1 Import Substitution: Past Performance and Prospects ••• 4 Export Producing Industries . . . • • • . • . . . . • • . • • • • • • • • . • • • . 5 Value Added in Nigerian Manufacturing •.•••••••••.•.•••• 6 Profit Rates in the Manufacturing Sector............... 8 The Location of Industrial Activity ..•••••.•••••••••••• 8 Foreign Participation in the Industrial Sector ••••••••• 9 II. GOVERNMENT POLICIES TO\vARD THE INDUSTRIAL SECTOR • • • • • . • • • • • • 11 Trade Restrictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Incentives and Tax Policies . . . • . • . . . . • • . . . • • • . • • • . • • • • • 14 Hanufacturing Priorities and the Role of the Public Sec tor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 III. THE STRUCTURE OF INDUSTRIAL PROTECTION IN NIGERIA • • . • . • • • • • • 22 The Effective Rate of Protection •.•.•••••...•...•.•••.• 22 Effective Rates of Protection: 1be Results ••...•.••••. 24 'fhe Export Industries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 Effective Protection and Excise Taxation ••••••••.•••••. 28 Effective Protection to the Major Import Substituting Industries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 High Cost Industries . • • . • • . • . . . . . . • • • • • . . • . . •. • • . • • • . • . . 33 The Structure of Protecti.on and Plan Priorities • • • . . . . . 33 Protection and Industrial Profits ••••••.••••••.•••.•.•• 37 I IV. FURTHER RESEARCH 40 Refinements of Effective Rates of Protection • • • • • • • • • . • 40 An Alternative Measure: Domestic Resource Cost • . • . • • . • 41 Inter-industry Relations • • . • . • . • • • • • • • . • . • • • • • • • • • . • • • • 42 ANNEXES 1. Hanufacturing Statistics in Nigeria 2. Conceptual .'lnd Methodolo~ical Issues in the Calculation of Effective Rates of Protection Table of Contentf! - (Cont'd) STATISTICAL APPENDIX INDUSTRY NOTES: Data Used in Calculatin~ Effective Rate of Protection, etc. LIST OF TABLES :rn THE TKXT 1. Value added in manufacturing and crafts, gross domestic product, and annual average rate of growth, 1958-1970 at 1962 factor cost 2. Structure of industry: value added in percent by sector~ 1965 and 1968 3. Nominal tariffs on domestically produced commodities, 1965 and 1968 4. Estimated coverage of the study of effective protection in 1968 5. Nominal and effective rates of protection for Nigerian industry, 1968 6. The effect of excise taxation on the degree of protection afforded selected Nigerian industries 7. Effective rates of protection on export industries industries processing domestic inputs for the domestic market, and industries processing imp.orted inputs for the domestic market, Nigeria, 1968 8. Effective rate of protection on import substituting consumer goods and intermediate-capital goods in Nigeria, 1968 9. Actual profitability, profitability at world market p.rices, and the effective rate of protection to profits in Nigeria, 1968 . This report is part of the work of the April/May 1970 economic mission to Nigeria headed by Mr. Joehen Schmedtje. It was prepared by Mr. Trent J. Bertrand, industrial consultant on that mission, with the assistance of Mr. Peter G. Kelk. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS i. This report analyzes recent developments in the manufacturing sector and the most important government policies affecting industriali- zation in Nigeria. Moreover, it represents the first attempt at defining the structure of industrial protection in Nigeria in terms of effective rates of protection, based on data for 42 industries in 1968. The find- ings have important implications for industrial policies in general. Considerable study remains to be done before detailed policy recommenda- • tions fdr specific industries can be developed • Recent Developments in the Manufacturing Sector ii. The manufacturing sector's contribution to GDP is still small - about 10 percent in 1969/70; but rapid rates of growth - estimated at close to 10 percent per annum - have been achieved over the 1965/66 to 1969/70 period despite disruptions by the civil disturbances. Nigerian manufacturing is characterized by low value added industries, this being the case both for the export industries engaged in semi-processing primary products and import substituting industries putting final touches to im- ported inputs. iii. There has been a pronounced shift from manufacturing in the early 1960's based largely on processing traditional primary products for export towards processing imported materials for the domestic market. As a consequence, industrial activity has become geographically more concentrated in areas with easy access to imported raw materials and large urban consumer markets. iv. The limits of import substitution have been reached for a number of consumer goods including beer, soft drinks, cigarettes, matches, bakery products, confectionery, soap and cosmetics and foot- wear. There remains extensive scope for further import substitution in textiles, especially in intermediate products (grey haft). Of inter- mediate goods, only cement, paints and tires and tubes have reached advanced degrees of import substitution. v. Foreign capital and expatriate management play a predominant l role in the Nigerian manufacturing sector. Over two-thirds of paid up capital in manufacturing firms with ten or more employees is held by private non-Nigerians. There has been no decline in the importance of foreign capital or expatriate management in the three-year period from 1965 to 1968. vi. The reliability of statistics on manufacturing in Nigeria is open to question on several accounts. In particular, the concept of value added used is not appropriate for showing the value of output at factor cost; and adjustments made to account for small scale production, non-reporting firms and price increases tend to overstate manufacturing production in real terms. - ii - Government Policies vii. Since Independence, Nigeria h-. moved from a relatively open economy towards a highly protected domestic market. This trend has been reinforced by tariff increases and quantitative restrictions im- posed during the war for balance of payments reasons. viii. In order to raise additional government revenues export taxa- . tion on processed raw materials was substantially increased during the war, from a basic rate of 10 percent to 15 percent for most commodities. ix. Special fiscal incentives to industry were widely used in the 1960's. These incentives have been used more stringently in the last three years and will be employed in the future only in support of high priority industries or to allow less thaq (economically) optional location of industries where differences in profitability are marginal. Tariff rebates on imported inputs into manufactured exports have been used as an export incentive but long delays in obtaining theee rebates are common. x. A wartime super-tax on profits,in excess of 15 Percent ot paid-up capital and capitalized earning~ h•s.,been retained up to the present (fall 1970). Its effect is to increase the rate of taxation on profits from 45 percent to a rate approaching 65 percent. xi. Excise taxes are an important feature of the Nigerian tariff-tax system, accounting for an expected 20 percent of Federally collected revenue in 1970/71. Since 1964, the policy has been to in- crease excise taxes on domestically produced commodities in line.. wf, th tariff increases. thus reducing protection afforded import substituting indus tries. xii. A quota system for expatriate technicians alld skilled workers is used to encout"age the employment of Nigerians in the foreign con- trolled industrial sector. xiii. An enlarged role for the public sector is envisaged in the 1970-74 Development Plan. This will take the form of significant government participation (either at least 55 or at least 35 percent of equity investment) in a wide range of large scale industries. xiv. Priorities in the industrial sector have been redefined with greatest emphasis given to agro-based, producer goods and export-oriented industries and with reduced emphasis on further import substitution in the consumer goods industries. - iii - Structure of Industrial Protection xv. The present study of industrial protection is based on data for 42 industries in 1968. It involved large scale data collection and processing in which the Federal Statistical Office actively coopera- tE!d by making available the raw data of the 1968 industrial census and other pertinent information. The data underlying the calculations of the effective rates of protection are presented in the Industry Notes appended to this report. They represent an important first step in deriving a detailed input-output table for Nigeria. xvi. On the whole, the structure of industrial protection in 1968 favored low value added industries thus encouraging the growth in low priority final touch assembly plants as opposed to industries better integrated with the local economy. xvii. There is a considerable difference in the degree of protection afforded different processing activities in Nigeria as defined by the effective rate of protection calculated for a 42-sector breakdown of industry. The structure of industrial protection discriminates heavily against export processing activities and in favor of import substituting industries. In 1968, the average effective rate of protection was minus 24 percent on the former and plus 85 percent on the latter. Import sub- stituting industries processing domestically produced inputs enjoyed greater protection than those processing imported inputs. xviii. The structure of industrial protection also discriminates against intermediate and capital goods industries relative to consumer goods industries, the effective tariff rate on the latter industries being 55 percent higher than on the former. This is also the case for the more recently established industries in Nigeria. xix. Excise taxation has had a pronounced effect in reducing the protection afforded import-substituting industries, the degree of pro- tection that would otherwise exist being reduced by over 45 percent for the potable spirits, matches and candles, tobacco, travel goods, beer and stout, cement, soft drinks, drugs and medicines, and textiles in- dustries. xx. Among the major industries, protection is highest for textiles and metal products. If adjustment is made for excessive profits in the textiles industry the level of its processing cost relative to world prices is not excessive. The benefit of further growth of the textiles industry would appear to compare favorably with most other import sub- stituting industries. The metal products industry would require even higher protection if a high cost domestic steel producing complex were established. - iv - xxi. Profits on capital of 18 percent or higher could be maintained under world market conditions in the beer and stout, tires and tubes and textiles industry. The metal products industry would barely make profits without protection. Policy Implications xxii. The policy implications of this report are centered on the strategy for import substitution followed in Nigeria; the tax system • with specific reference to export taxation, excise taxation, and the super tax; and the need for further researcl) and data improvement. xxiii. Import substitution. A large part of import substitution has developed behind tariffs and quotas imposed for revenue and balance of payments purposes. For these connnodities, there is a rough tendency for nominal rates of protection to be similar. This leads to a higher degree of effective protection to industries with low ratios of value added to gross output and thus encourages the bias towards final touch assembly industries. xxiv. Protection is designed to permit the domestic producer to earn a 15 percent net rate of return on investment. Tariff policies designed to equalize the rates of return on capital among industries will prevent tbe market from allocating factors of production bet.ween indus tries. Along with this restri'ction of market forces, indus trles facing international competition will tend to seek increased protection from the government rather than to increcas'e tne efficiency of their own operations. Moreover, the potentl'ill e:xport market will be neglected since it is more profitable to produce for the highly protected domestic market. xxv. A more rational approach is to give the same degree of protec- tion to different processing activities~ thus permitting market forces to influence the allocation of resources betWeen industries. While ex- ceptions to this principle might be advisable due to special aspects of certain industries, the adoption of such a general guideline would stop the discrimination in favor of low value added industries which now benefits the assembly type consumer goods industries relative to the intermediate and producer goods industries, accorded high priority in the 1970-74 Development Plan. xxvi. Under a policy of equal protection tariffs on competing imports, raw material inputs, and e:xcise taxes would be set so as to equalize the effective rate of protection among industries. The level of effective protection would be decided on the basis of a decision,on the e:xtent to which industry is to be favored relative to other activities because of the beneficial results of industrial activity in developing entrepreneur- ship, improving the quality of labor, and absorbing excess labor. - v - xxvii. To be consistent with the priorities established in the 1970-74 Development Plan, the degree of .protection accorded intermediate goods industries should be increased relative to that afforded consumer goods industries. However, raising ts.riffs on intermediate goods and/or lower- ing tariffs on consumer goods would tend to reduce the profitability of the consumer goods industries, many of which are high cost and inefficient. Preference should be given to industries processing domestic inputs as opposed to imported inputs. xxviii. Quantitative restrictions entail administrative costs and monopoly profits for those fortunate in obtaining import licenses. In the interest of administrative efficiency and increased government reve- nues quantitative restrictions should be replaced by tariffs designed to have an equivalent protective effect, except where they are felt to be temporary emergency measures. xxix. Taxes. The heavy penalization of export industries processing primary products in conjunction with protection of high cost import sub- stituting industries is unfortunate. The benefit is additional government revenue, the more important loss is an inefficient allocation of resources and an income transfer from domestic consumers not only to the government but also to predominantly expatriate producer groups. More moderate export taxation and heavier excise taxation of import substituting industries obtaining very high levels of protection would lead to a more efficient allocation of resources between industries and would be consistent with the priorities established in the 1970-74 Development Plan. xxx. There appears to be some potential for exporting manufactures to other African countries even without preferential treatment. Two obstacles to this are the high profitability of the domestic market and delays in receiving tariff rebates on imported inputs used in producing export manufactures. The tariff rebate scheme should be modified so that rebates are either received in a reasonable time or are waived subject to verification that the final products have been exported. Excise taxation should also be eliminated on manufactured commodities for export. r xxxi. Given the revenue constraints facing the government, the system of high tariffs with corresponding high excise taxation is an efficient way of generating revenue. Consumers lose through higher prices of imported goods but most of this loss is in the form of transfers to the government via import and excise duties collected. The high level of excise taxation greatly offsets the distortion in pro- duction that would otherwise result from high tariff protection. The loss in consumers' surplus due to the consumption distortion may well be an acceptable cost for generating, in recent years, almost 50 percent of Federally collected revenue. - vi - xxx1L The super-tax encourages the capitalization of earnings but discourages new investment by raising the rate of profits tax on new firms which typically have attempted to maintain low ratios of equity to debt capital in the early years of operation to minimize risk. xxxiU. Further research and data impro\f'etne.nt. The present study of effective rates of protection could be refined by further efforts to (a) derive satisfactory data on comparisons of ex-factory and c.i.f. prices, (b) indicate more reliably the e'xtent to which an industry's effective rate of protection reflects the le~el of factor costs or the existence of excessive profits, (c) calculate a 'net' effective rate of protection which adjusts the rates calcula"ted here for possible exchange rate over-valuation as compared to the free trade equilibrium and (d) carry out industry studies designed to isolate special aspects of particular industries that would justify special treatment. xxxiv. In addition to the effecti~e rate of protection, it would be useful to calculate an alternative crit'erion to eva:luate domestic indus- tries. This is the domestic resource cost measure which indicates the cost of a unit of foreign exchange earned in a:n export industty, or saved in an import industry in terms of the domestic resottrces used in producing this earning or saving. xxxv. The industrial statistics should be adjuBted so as to show value added at factor cos·t as uS'u~lly defined. Sut'\teys sbou1d be under- taken to improve the adjustments made for small scale industries and non- reporting firms. AppropTiate price indues for mamtfacturing inputs and outputs should be constructed in order tha't manufaeturing production and value added can be accurately measured in real terms. I. THE MANUFACTURING SECTOR: PAST PERFORMANCE 1. This chapter presents a brief survey of the nature and development of the manufacturing sector of the Nigerian economy over the past decade. Data on manufacturing are presented in order to define the size of the manu- facturing sector in relation to the total economy, its rate of growth, the nature of the structural change that has occurred, the pattern of location of industry, and the importance of foreign private investment in Nigerian • manufacturing • Growth and Structural Change in Nigerian Manufacturing 2. A sectoral breakdown of gross domestic product in current and con- stant prices is presented in tables 1 and 2 of the Statistical Appendix, while the real rates of growth of manufacturing, crafts, and gross domestic product are given in text table 1. These tables pertain to the total econ- omy but the data for 1967-1969 are only approximate since they include rough estimates of production in the war affected East-Central, South-Eastern, and Rivers States. 1be contribution of the manufacturing and crafts sector is small; in 1969/70 it is estimated at 9.5 percent. However, this repre- sents a substantial increase from the early 1960's, its contribution being only 5.6 percent in 1963/64. According to the figures in constant 1962 prices, the average annual rate of growth of the manufacturing sector was 21.0 percent for the period 1958/59 to 1962/63, 6.7 percent per annum for the period 1962/63 to 1966/67 and, for manufacturing and crafts together, 15.3 percent per annum in the period 1966/67 to 1969/70. Because of the disruptions caused by the war and more importantly, biases that occur in growth rate estimates due to assumptions made in constructing industrial statistics, these growth rates are upward biased. The problems involved and the likely magnitudes of the biases are discussed in Annex 1, Manufac- turing Statistics in Nigeria. However, correction for these biases would not alter the general picture of a small but rapidly growing manufacturing sector. 3. An indication of the structure of manufacturing and its change over the past decade is difficult to obtain because of the lack of reliable I industrial surveys prior to 1962 and the lack of data on manufacturing in the Eastern states during the war. A breakdown of value added by industry in 1958, 1963, and 1967 is presented in table 3 of the Statistical Appendix. From 1963 to 1967, industries experiencing the most rapid growth were tex- tiles, miscellaneous petroleum products such as lubricants and bitumens, garments, footwear, metal products, and vegetable oil milling. In 1963, textiles accounted for 7.2 percent of aggregate value added in manufactur- ing. By 1967, they accounted for 15.1 percent. The share of metal products increased from 5.2 percent in 1963 to 6.7 percent in 1967. The share of basic industrial chemicals rose from 5.2 to 7.8 percent. Vegetable oil milling increased in share from 6.2 to 8.0 percent. No meaningful compar- ison is possible between 1963 and 1958 since the structure of value added for 1958 is exactly identical to 1963. Obviously, the structure derived from the 1963 survey has been used to generate the breakdown for 1958 for which year there was no industrial survey. Table ·"1: VALUE ADDED IN MANUFACTURING AND CRAFTS, GROSS DOMEsriC PRODUCT, AND ANNUAL AVERAGE RATE OF GROWTH, 1958-1970 AT 1962 FACTOR COST 1958/59 1958/59 to 1962/63 1962/63 to 1966/67 1966/67 to 1969/70 (£N millie~) 1962/63 (£Nmillion) 1966/67 (fN million) 1969/70 ~N million) Average Annual Average Annual Average Annual Growth Rate Growth Rate Growth Rate Manufacturing 26.2 21.0% 56.1 6.7% 72.7l93.1 15.3 142.4 ;'\) Crafts 19.1 0.9% 19.8 0.7% 20.4 Gross Domestic Product 1023.9 6.5% 1315.4 4.7 1583.1 '-1.5% 1513.8 Source: Federal Office of Statistics and Ministry of Economic Development and Reconstruction. "' - 3 - 4. Because the 1967 survey excluded the East while the 1963 survey covered the whole country, even data presented for 1963 and 1967 are not strictly comparable. Furthermore, the inclusion of excise taxes in value added greatly distorts the true structure of industry since the growth of firms producing commodities subject to excise taxation tends to be exagger- ated because these taxes have risen substantially over the past decade. 1/ In order to take these factors into account, the structure of value added, excluding excise taxes, has been calculated from the 1965 industrial survey with the Eastern region excluded and from the 1968 survey which was not con- ducted in the Eastern states. The coverage of the two surveys would appear to be quite comparable and responses were used from 534 firms and 601 firms, respectively. Seventy-two of the firms reporting in 1968 went into produc- tion in the years 1966, 1967 and 1968. The results of the exercise are pre- sented in text table 2. The most rapid growth occurred in the import sub- stitute textile, footwear, and apparel industries whose combined share rose from 14.7 percent in 1965 to 23.2 percent in 1968. The growth in the vege- table oil milling industries - from 3.2 percent to 8.4 percent over the same period - reflects the rapid expansion of output in enterprises covered by the 1968 census, as access to the Eastern processing plants, where the in- dustry is concentrated, was cut off. Relative declines occurred in the food and beverages sector and in sawmilling and wood products. Table 2: STRUCTURE OF INDUSTRY /1: VALUE ADDED IN PERCENT BY SECTOR, 1965 and 1968 Sector 1965 1968 (%) (%) Food and beverages 27.6 17.6 Vegetable oil milling 3.2 8.4 Textiles, footwear, and apparel 14.7 23.2 Saw milling and wood products 8.1 5.0 Printing and paper products 5.1 4.7 , Chemicals, paint and plastics 8.4 11.1 Rubber products, tires and tubes 5.4 5.5 Cement, pottery and glass products 6.2 4.9 Metal products and miscellaneous 22.4 19.5 Ll Eastern States excluded. Source: Federal Office of Statistics, Industrial Surveys, 1965 and 1968. 1/ Cf. Annex 1, pp. 1-2. - 4 - 5. The rapid growth of the textile and footwear industries was in large par.t in response to greater protection afforded the domestic market by both higher tariffs and quantitative restrictions, the development of which is outlined in Chapter II of this report. The increase in protection led not only to capacity operation in the import substituting industries but also to rapid expansion in existing capacity and entry of new firms. This can be seen by an analysis of new firms entering production in the period 1966 to 1968. The number of firms, value added, and employment in these new firms in 1968 is presented in table 4 of the Statistical Appendix. Over 96 percent of value added and over 83 percent of employment in these firms was concentrated in the predominantly import substitute textiles, footwear, apparel, chemicals, paints, plastics, tires, tubes, cement, pottery, glass products, electrical supplies, radio and television assembly, hardware and cutlery, and metal products industries. Import Substitution: Past Performance and Prospects 6. With a gross domestic product in 1969/70 estimated at bN1.5 bil- lion or US$ 4.2 billion and a population officially estimated at 66 mil- lion 1f in mid-19 70, import substitution could be expected to become a prom- inent feature of the industrialization process. It was given a sharp stim- ulus by the disrup.tions of trade resulting from the war as, in response to a sharp fall in foreign exchange earnings and holdings, trade restrictions were introduced and tightened. However, there has been recognition of the need to rationalize the process of import substitution. In Chapter III of this report, the distortions caused by the structure of industrial protec- tion are quantified. Here we merely seek to give a rough indication of the extent of import substitution that has occurred in different industries and the potentials for further import substitution. The measure of import substitution is the ratio of imports to total supply. The analysis neces- sarily gives only a rough indication because both domestic production and imports of various commodities have been differently affected by the war and war related changes in commercial policies. 7. The ratios of the value of imports to total supply for selected products are given in table 5 of the Statistical Appendix. Where possible, these ratios have been derived from data on quantity units of production \ and imports. However, where figures on quantities produced are not avail- able, the ratios are in value units of production, measured at CIF prices plus tariffs. 8. The limits of import substitution have been reached in a 'few com- modities, and for these growth of domestic production will largely be de- termined by growth of the domestic market. These commodities include beer and stout, cigarettes, matches and candles, flour, products of the bakery industry, and soft drinks, all of which have a limited potential for ex- ports. ll Other estimates are as much as 10 million lower. - 5 - 9. For a second group of commodities, substantial strides have been made in import substitution during the past five or six years, but the pro- cess has not yet been completed. Of these, the most important has been the textile industry. In 1963, imports of textile yarn and thread, fabrics, and made up textile goods other than clothing were valued at bN 34.5 million accounting for over 16% of total imports. In the same year, domestic pro- duction of these goods was valued at bN 7.9 million. By 1968, domestic out- put had increased to bN 40.4 million and imports had declined to bN 19.4 million, 10% of total imports. Despite the decline in the ratio of imports to total supply from 81% in 1963 to 32% in 1968, the potential for further import substitution in textiles is extensive. Proposals for new investments in the manufacturing sector that have been submitted to the government are heavily concentrated in the textile industry and efforts have recently been made to encourage the backward linkage of the textile industry towards more extensive production of grey haft by a one-third increase in the import tariff. 10. Imported cement accounted for 36% of total supply in 1963. By 1968 this had been reduced to 12%, and would have been even lower had ce- ment production in the East not been disrupted. Cement imports will be eliminated in the near future. Imports of tires and tubes accounted for 82% of total supply in 1963 and only 36% in 1968. Imports of soap, per- fumes, cosmetics, and toilet preparations represented 30% of total supply in 1963; by 1968 this was reduced to about 5%. A sugar refinery began operation in 1964; by 1968 it accounted for 43 percent of the total supply of refined sugar. Other industries where the general trend towards import substitution has been pronounced are wooden furniture (the 35 percent of domestic supply from imports in 1963 being reduced to 20 percent in 1968), footwear (the corresponding figures being 55 percent and 6 percent), and paints (26 percent and 19 percent, respectively). 11. Finally, for a third group of commodities, extensive possibilities remain for import substitution. While truck assembly is carried out in Nigeria, car assembly has not yet been introduced. There are firm plans to introduce car assembly during the next two years. There are also pros- pects for expanding production of paper containers, boxes, and paper boards regarding which, in 1968, 76 percent of total supply was imported. Consid- erable scope remains for substituting imports of glass products, even after production in the glass bottles plant in Port Harcourt has resumed. Export Producing Industries 12. In 1958, roughly half of value added in manufacturing was contrib- uted by firms processing or semi-processing primary products for export. The major structural change that has occurred in Nigerian manufacturing is indicated by the fall in the share of value added of these industries to less than a quarter of the total by 1967. Even taking into account the greater disruptive effect of the civil disturbances on the primary product processing industries, the shift in the orientation of the manufacturing sector from the external to the domestic market has been pronounced. This - 6 - development was to be expected as the s-tructure of the tariffs and trade restrictions gives substantial preferences to import substituting indus- tries relative to export industries. The extent of these preferences is quantified in Chapter III. 13. Almost all of the exports produced by the manufacturing sector are processed primary products. Of the export producing industries the most important are the oil milling indU&tr·y processing groundnuts for groundnut oil and cake and palm kernels fior palm oil, the rubber industry processing raw rubber for rubber crepe and sheets, the non-ferrous metal industry processing ore for tin metal, the saw mill industry processing logs for lumber and plywood, and the tanneries and leather industries pro- cessing hides and skins. The development of exports of these products from 1965 to 1969 is outlined in table 6 of the Statistical Appendix. 14. Because the Eastern Region is an important producer of palm oil, rubber, and lumber, the civil disturbances had a very disruptive effect on production and export of these products. In value te11ms, export of the major processed exports fell by 40% from 1965 to 1967. The most drastic export drop occurred in palm oil exports, wh·ich fell from DN 13.6 million during the same time period. Of the 131 oil milling fi.rms employing ten or more employees listed in the 1970 industrial directory, 107 are in Rivers, East, Central and South Eastern States. As these areas recover from the war, substantial increases in palm oil exports can be expected. 15. The Nigerian manufacturing sector has not succeeded in developing non-traditional exports. However, small amounts of new manufactures are exported to neighboring African countries. For instance, in 1968, bN 363 thousand worth of textiles products were exported, mostly to Niger and Sierra Leone. In the 1970-74 Development Plan, 1/ greater priority has been given to stimulating exports. There is recognition in Nigeria that incen- tive schemes designed to encourage non-traditional exports, such as rebates of all import duties paid on intermediate goods used in the production of exports, have not been successful. Because of this and given the increasing level of protection of the Nigerian domestic market potential exports of manufactures may be foregone unless legislature designed to improve the ex- port promotion schemes becomes effective. Value Added in Nigerian Manufacturing 16. An important feature of Nigerian manufacturing is the low ratio of value added to gross output. As stated in the 1970-74 Development Plan: "Most industrial activities in the country are still not manufacturing in the true sense of the term, but mere assemblages. Very often, all the com- ponents used are imported and are merely put together behind the tariff wall" ];./. While this is most obviously the case for some import substituting 11 Second National Development Plan 1970-74, Federal Ministry of Informa- tion, Lagos 1970. !:./ 2£.:.. f.!!:_, p • 28 5 • - 7 - industries carrying out finishing touches on imported inputs, low value added is also characteristic of many of the export industries which only semi-process the raw material. The backward integration of the import sub- stituting industries and forward integration of industries processing for exports have been given higher priority in the 1970-74 Development Plan. 17. An indication of the low level of processing carried out in Nigerian manufacturing is given in table 7 in the Statistical Appendix which shows the ratio of value added to gross output for a 34 sector break- down of industry in 1967. The table shows value added both including and excluding "other cost", i.e. mainly excise taxes, but also payments for hired transport, advertising, office expenses, professional fees, rental payments, insurance, and miscellaneous expenses. Including "other costs", i.e. on the definition used by the Federal Office of Statistics, 1/ the ratio of value added to gross output for the manufacturing sector as a whole was 40 percent. Excluding "other cost" this ratio reduces to 26 per- cent. 18. On the basis of value added excluding "other cost" the industries may be grouped with respect to the ratio of value added to gross output in- to those having a ratio of value added to gross output above 40 percent (group I), between 40 and 20 percent (group II) and below 20 percent (group III). Since these ratios are direct value added to gross output, they can- not be used by themselves to indicate the linkage of manufacturing proces- sing to the rest of the economy because indirect value added in processing domestic inputs may be high. But they do indicate that value added in most processing industries is low. Group I Industries with High Value Added of Above 40 Percent of Gross Output Basic industrial chemicals and petroleum products, cement and concrete products, wearing apparel, sugar and spirit distillery, sawmilling, bricks and tiles, printing. Group II Industries with Value Added of 20 to 40 Percent of Gross Output , Dairy products, beer, soft drinks, rubber products, footwear, furniture, made-up textiles, paints, fruit canning, bakery products, textiles, confectionery, food and tobacco, and paper products. Group III Industries with Value Added of Below 20 Percent of Gross Output Meat products, grain products, tanning, vegetable oil, milling, basic metals (tin) and metal products, electrical equipment, motor vehicle repairs, machinery other than electrical, glass products and pottery, travel goods, motor vehicle assembly. ll Cf. Annex 1, p. 1. - 8- 19. The ranking of some industries changes substantially if the Fed- eral Office of Statistics definition of value added (i.e. including excise taxes) is used. Industries producing heavily excised commodities all ap- pear to have high value added relative to gross oUtput. Examples are beer (73%), miscellaneous foods and tobacco (78%), soft drinks (66%). Profit ,Rates in the Man\lfacturing Sect.or 20. It has not been pOssible to derive profit rates on capital in- vested in Nigerian manufacturing beeaU#e of the lack of reliable data oti capital eutployed. However, the data is used to show the rate of profit on sales by sector and over ti~ so as to provide an indication of intertem-' poral changes and inter-industry differences in profitability. Rates of profits on sales can only be used to indicate profitability proper i f cap- ital output ratios are similar bet-.7een industries; hence the results must be interpreted With caution. 21. In table 8 in the Statistical Appendix, profits are defined as gross output minus total costs (including excise taxes) and are shown as a percentage of the value of gross output by industt·lal sector foT 1963 and 1967. The mst promin:ent changes td have occurred over the four year per- iod are: (a) the very high profit rates in the long existing tobacco, beverages, and to a lesser degree textile industries have lieen substantial- ly reduced; (b) the profit rates on the IllOt'e recent tires and tubes indus- try (included under rubber products), cliemicals, footWear, llearing apparel, and made-up textiles industries have increased substantially; (c) the rate of profit in the electrical equipment industry is still loW' but has gone up considerably, in contrast to the unprOfitable truck asseinbly industry; and (d) the rate of profit has fallen in the- export oriented tanning industry and remains still relatiVely lOW' in oil milling an'd the indigenous domi- nated printing industry. The fall in profit rates in tobacco, beverages, and textile industries is mainly the result of a rise in excise taxation. The rise in returns in the new import substitute industries reflects the higher protection given the domestic market. The Location of Industd.a.l A,cU.vity 22. The locations! pattern of industrial activity is an important question in Nigeria because of the political desirability of economic pro- gress in all States of the country. Nevertheless, at an early stage of de- velopment, economic profitability must be the predominant determinant of location of enterprises. This principle has been accepted in the 1970-74 Development Plan and exceptions from it in favor of industrially less de- veloped regions will only be made in IIIB'tginal case.s. Positive steps have been taken to assure that less developed regions are, however, not pena- lized by high costs for public utilities. Thus, uniform rates for elec- tricity aTe being established throughout the country. The Federal Govern- ment can also play a role in coordinating planning activities carried out by the individual States to minimize any tendency towards uneconomic dupli- cation of production facilities. - 9 - 23. Because of widely diversified natural resources, manufacturing based on processing raw materials and agricultural products has been better distributed in Nigeria than in most developing countries. Groundnuts, cattle and cotton are spread throughout the northern region of the country. The western region has important base materials in its cocoa, palm trees, and timber resources. The Mid-West and East are benefited by major petro- leum deposits, some coal, and extensive palm tree forests. Iron and tin ore reserves are located in the Benue-Plateau and Kwara States. The latter • State also has important sugar producing areas. Thus, the contribution to manufacturing value added in 1965 was 26 percent in Lagos, 28 percent in the Western Region and 6 percent in the Mid-West, 21 percent in the North, and 20 percent in the East. 24. The growing importance of import-substitution since 1965 has, however, made a significant difference in the distribution of industrial activity. This conclusion is based on an analysis of the locational pat- tern for new firms entering into production in the 1966-68 period. In table 9 of the Statistical Appendix, data on the number of new firms, value added, gross output, and employment is given for all new firms with ten or more employees which responded to the 1968 industrial survey. There has been a clear tendency for domestic market oriented firms to locate close to the source of imported raw materials and urban domestic markets. Thus, sixty percent of new firms, accounting for 40 percent of value added and 70 percent of employment, have located in the Lagos area. 25. In the 1970-74 Development Plan, top priority has been given to the agro-allied industries, while reduced priority has been accorded fur- ther import substitution. As these new priorities are put into effect, a better distribution of industrial activity will be an indirect but impor- tant benefit. Foreign Participation in the Industrial Sector 26. Manufacturing in large scale plants in Nigeria is dominated by expatriate business. For the total manufacturing sector in 1967, 67 per- cent of paid up capital was private non-Nigerian, 18 percent was held by the Federal and Regional Governments, and only 12 percent was private Nigerian. The remaining 3 percent was held by international organizations. 27. There are two exceptions to the general rule of above 80 percent private foreign ownership of share capital in Nigerian industry. The first concerns those sectors where Federal, Regional, and State government de- velopment organizations have participated in industrial projects. Thus, approximately 28 percent of paid up capital in the textile industry, 57 percent in the printing industry, 37 percent in the vegetable oil milling industry, and 31 percent in the cement and concrete products industry are held hy government development corporations. The second is where private Nir,erlan capital has participated, often in moderately sized establish- ments. Thus, the private Ni~erian share in equity capital in 196 7 was 35 percent tn the bakery products industry (30 reporting firms with an avernge - 10 - employment of 52), 41 percent in the sawmilling industry (52 reporting firms with average employment of 122), 23 percent in the furniture industry (41 reporting firms with average employment of 87), 39 percent in the tanning industry (7 reporting firms with an average employment of 80), and 34 per- cent in the motor vehicles repair industry (80 reporting firms with an average employment of 78). 28. In order to learn i f any trend towards reduced foreign ownership of Nigerian industry could be ide.ntified in recent years, t~e structure of • paid up capital in firms commencing operaUon in the years 1966, 1967, and 1968 was analyzed. There were 70 such firms reporting in the 1968 indus- trial surveys. In table 10 of the Statistical Appendix, the rate of for- eign participation by sector is compared to the correspo-p.ding rate in 1965. The rate of foreign participation is substantially lower in new firms in the textiles, saw milling and wood products industries, but is higher in all other sectors. For the manufacturing sector as a whole, little change has occurred with foreign participation still 67 percent in new firms. The indigenisation of the Nigerian industrial sector has become a high prioritY, objective of planning author.ities in Nigeria. The relative importal'lce of foreign capital in the manufacturing sector can be expected to ~.cline in future years as the public sect.or plays the leading role in mos.t projected heavy industries. - 11 - II. GOVERNMENT POLICIES TOWARDS TI1E INDUSTRIAL SECTOR 29. The purpose in this chapter is to briefly outline the various gov- ernment policies having an important effect on the industrial sector in Ni~eria. Since protection afforded the domestic market through tariffs and • quantitative restrictions is of predominant importance, we first outline the development of trade restrictions in the late 1960's. The effect of these policies on industry will be considered in detail in Chapter III, where the degree of effective protection of individual industries is stud- ied. Secondly, other industrial incentives and tax policies are discussed. Thirdly, the priorities established in the 1970-74 Development Plan and the role of the public sector are considered. Trade Restrictions 30. In 1960, Nigeria was a relatively open economy with industrial activity concentrated in firms processing traditional primary products. The non-export sector was dominated to a great extent by the long established tobacco, beer, and cement industries along with the more recent textile in- dustry. Most other commodities entered Nigeria either free of tariffs (milk, fruit juices, bakery products, sugar, miscellaneous foodstuffs, travel goods, glassware, and electrical appliances) or with low or moderate tariffs (foot- wear - 33-1/3 percent, paper board-10 percent, radios and communications equipment-10 percent, and meat products - 15 percent). Tariffs were some- what higher on imports competing with domestic products (beer - 30 percent, cement - 20 percent, cigarettes- 112 percent and textiles- 37 percent). By the mid-1960's however, there was a shift to much higher protection of the domestic market as the data of text table 3 show. For example, whereas in the early 1960's most foodstuffs were imported free of tariffs, by 1965 the weighted average tariff on these products was 55%. The tariff on beer had risen to 60%, on tobacco it had doubled from its 1960 level to 225%, and on textiles it had risen from 35 to 54%. All in all, the weighted average of tariffs on all domestically produced goods (the weights being the industry's contribution to gross output) reached 67 percent in 1965. 1he weighted average for consumer goods alone was 73 percent and for raw materials 44 percent. Since the tariff on cigarettes was virtually prohib- itive, it was not relevant for protective purposes. Therefore the tariff levels for (i) consumer goods and (ii) all commodities were calculated ex- cluding tobacco in either case; the resulting averages were 49 and 48 per- cent, respectively. 31. The trend towards higher nominal protection of consumer goods in- dustries in the first half of the decade was continued in the late 1960's. Si~nificant increases in the tariff for foodstuffs occurred as a tariff was imposed on milk, and raised on butter and biscuits. The tariff on cigarettes increased by 7% but since the previous tariff was already virtually prohib- itive, this had little effect on the domestic industry. Of more relevance - 12 - to the rising level of protection were the substantial increases in the tariffs applied to footwear, textiles, and electrical equipment. All these increases contributed to a rise in the wei~hted average of nominal tariffs on consumer goods to 83% in 1968 (an increase of 14%) or, excluding tobacco, to 58 percent (an increase of 18%). 32. The nominal protection afforded to raw materials increased from earlier years when the basic rate was raised from 20 percent to 33-1/3% in 1964. However, from 1965 to 1968, there was a slight decline in the weighted average of tariffs on raw materials. This resulted from a fall in nominal rates on cement and flour not being quite offset by a substantial rise in the tariff on grey baft - the primary input into later stage bleachin?;, dye- ing and printing process in the textile industry. The tariff changes on flour and cement were of lesser significance since these tariffs were be- coming prohibitive. The increased protection of early stage textile proces- sing will have a major effect, however, because subotantial amounts of im- ported grey haft are used in preference to baft woven from locally grown cotton. 33. Besides the increase in the nominal tariffs outlin.ed in text table 3, a reconstruction surcharge has been imposed since 196 7. This increases the duty by 7-1/2 percent on all imported goods except (a) for raw tobacco imported by manufacturers on which a 5 percent surcharge is applied and (b) for goods imported at reduced rates by approved manufacturers on certain specific goods (milk, beet and cane sugar, and salt) for which no surcharge is levied. The effect of the surcharge in 1968 was to increase the average nominal tariff from 74 to 78 percent. 34. The level of tariffs in Nigeria is not exceptionally high in re- lation to many less developed countries where average nominal tariffs are often in the 80-100 percent range. But Nigeria is no longer a low tariff economy and the trend to higher protection is continuing. Since 1968, tariffs have been increased on travel goods (from 40 to 100 percent), foot- wear (from 40 to 100 percent), and cocoa based confectionery (from 12-1/2 to 33-1/3 percent). The most significant shift in tariff policies, however, has been the rise in tariffs on many raw materials and capital goods, a move designed to redress the imbalance in protection accorded consumer goods and intermediate capital goods industries. This is quantified in Chapter III of this report. Thus, the tariff has been increased in 1970 on imported yarns from 6d per lb. to 10d per lb, the tariff on grey baft from 6.8 per sq. yd. to 9d per sq. yd., the tariff on most intermediate metal products from 33-1/3 to 50 percent, and from 5 to 10 percent on machineries and parts. 35. Besides tariffs, quantitative restrictions on the import of spe- cific commodities have been extensively relied on as a measure to conserve foreign exchange during the recent civil war. Between July and December 1967, twenty-three items were under direct control, the most important of these being petroleum products, cement, various meat products, tires, and certain types of textile products. By June 1969, the list of commodities under specific license arrangements had been expanded to three hundred - 13 - Table 3: NOMINAL TARIFFS ON DOMESTICALLY PRODUCED COMMODITIES 1965 and 1968 Tariff Rate % 1968 consumer goods • Foodstuffs 55 63 Beer and stout 64 68 Tobacco products 225 240 Textiles (prints and piece goods) 54 74 Ti.res and tubes 45 45 Footwear 25 50 Furniture 75 75 Paints 40 40 Motor vehicle assembly 33 1/3 33 1/3 Metal products 33 1/3 33 1/3 Electrical equipment 66 2/3 100 Weighted average consumer goods 73 83 Ditto -excluding tobacco products 49 ~8 Raw materials Flour 62 31 CemP.nt 75 40 Concrete products 66 2/3 66 2/3 Miscellaneous products of petroleum industry 33 1/3 33 1/3 TextHes (grey baft) 34 48 Paper containers and paper board 25 25 MP.ta l pro ducts 33 1/3 33 1/3 lrJej ~hted average raw materials 44 41 fl 1.1 cormnodJtiea ( weighted average) 67 74 lli t.t.o -excluding l:.obacco products 48 55 Source: Federal Ministry of 'f'rade and Industry. - 14 - categories. Many of the additional commodities placed on restriction were either already produced, or could potentially be produced in Nigeria, so that the quantitative restrictions gave added stimulus to domestic indus- tries. The most important of these commodities include wood and plywood, footwear, paper and cardboard packing materials, radios, television sets, record players, textile piece goods, furniture, beer and spirits, travel bags, roofing sheets and other building materials, sugar, confectionery, food pastes, rubber latex, and electrical products and appliances. 36. The importance of the quantitative restrictions in relationship to the tariff system in providing protection to the manufacturing sector could be quantified by a comparison of the percentage difference of ex factory to CIF import prices plus the legal tariff rates. Ex factory prices substantially above the CIF plus tariff price would indicate that quantitative restrictions were the effective measure providing protection. Such price comparisons could not be made for most commodities, however, be- cause of a lack of data on ex factory and CIF prices for items of similar quality. While a price survey that should yield additional information on this question has been undertaken by the Ministry of Trade, the results are not yet available. It has not, therefore, been possible to adequately esti- mate the protective effect of the quantitative restrictions. These were un- doubtedly of considerable importance during the war years, but are likely to be much less significant as the recovery of foreign exchange earnings im- proves the balance of payments situation and permits the quantitative restric- tions to be relaxed. In April 1970, for instance, import quotas were removed from a wide list of commodities. Except where they are felt to be temporary emergency measures, quantitative restrictions should be replaced by tariffs designed to have an equivalent protective effect. The advantage of this change is that the monopoly profits of those fortunate in obtaining import licenses under a system of quantitative restrictions would accrue to the government as tariff revenue under the system of equivalent tariffs. 37. Finally, mention should be made of the negative protection implied in export taxation. Export taxation on most products was at a 10 percent rate until 1969 when the basic rate was increased to 15 percent. The new rate applies to exports of groundnut products, palm kernel products, cotton lint and seed, rubber, and logs. The previously lower rates have been in- creased for lumber export from 2.5 to 3 percent. The export tax rate on plywood has remained unchanged at about 10 percent. While the change in tariffs on raw materials tended to redress distortions caused by the struc- ture of industrial protection, this export tax change has added to the al- ready heavy penalization of export activities that is defined in Chapter III. Incentives and Tax Policies 38. Industrial incentives other than tariffs and quantitative restric- tions have been extensively used in Nigeria although in more recent years, - 15 .... they have been of reduced importance. Special industrial incentives 1/ are based on four main legislative acts: (a) the Industrial Development (Income Tax Relief) Act of 1958, (b) the Industrial Development (Import Duties Re- lief) Act of 1957, (c) the Customs Duties (Dumped and Subsidized Goods) Act of 1958, and (d) the Customs (Draw Back) Regulation of 1958. 39. The Industrial Development (Income Tax Relief) Act grants income .. tax relief to 'pioneer' companies, the relief extending from 2 to 5 years depending on the size of their capital expenditure on fixed assets. If profits are not earned in these years, the period of pioneer status can be extended by the number of years of unprofitable operation. This incentive has been granted to 156 firms (out of approximately 1000 medium or large scale firms) between 1960 and 1969. While of considerable importance from 1960 to 1966, pioneer status has been granted far less frequently during 1967 to 1969: Year No. of firms declared pioneer 1960 10 1961 22 1962 16 1963 15 1964 22 1965 25 1966 19 1967 7 1968 4 1969 1 40. The main beneficiaries of the pioneer industry incentive were the metal and textile industries. However, this incentive has also been used extensively in the food processing, chemicals and paint, rubber and rubber products, pharmaceutical, tin alloys and aluminum, cement and hotel indus- tries. The distribution of pioneer industries among major industrial sec- tors between 1956 and 1968 and the estimated total investment in these firms is shown in table 11 in the Statistical Appendix. One third of the pioneer firms, accounting for over half of total estimated investment, were in the metals and textile products industries. 1 There is considerable evidence based on surveys of businessmen in • 11. Nlg~ria that the pioneer industries incentive has not been an important factor in the decision to invest by foreign private investors to establish npe rRtions in Nigeria. Y Since tax sharing agreements do not exist between II 1\ccelerntPd df.'rreciat1c,m allowances were previously a very important I ncentlve in Nt~;Pdn, !H~rmitting the investor to write off 50 percent of his :lnvr-etmPnt in the first year, but since 1966 this incentive has heen vlrtu~lly ellmtnaterl. ].j _See P. Kilby, -~-I}dustrialization in an Open Economy: Nigeria 1945-1966, Cambridge 1969, and S. Aluko, Incentive Policies in Nigeria, Ife, 1968. - 16 - Nigeria and foreign countries, the benefits of the tax holiday accrue to the foreign government if profits are repatriated. While this reduces the at- tractiveness of the incentive it does have the beneficial effect of encourag- ing the re-investment of profits by expatriate firms to avoid home country taxation. However, since the tax holiday can be extended, the pioneer pro- gram also reduces the incentive to realize profits in the initial years of operation. The revenue lost through the ~ranting of the pioneer industry incentive could have been more efficiently used in supporting industrializa- tion by improving basic public utility services, such as electricity and water supply that are at present costly and unreliable. The decrease in the use of this incentive is desirable and certainly the possibility of extending the holiday beyond five years should be eliminated. 42. The Industrial Development (Import Duties Relief) Act provides tariff rebates to industries not viable without them if it can be shown that the tariff rate paid on imported inputs is higher than on the firm's final product. The Customs Duties (Dumped and Subsidized Goods) Act permits spe- cial tariffs to be applied to goods being dumped in Nigerian markets or subsidized by foreign governments. The Customs (Draw Back) Regulation pro- vides for repayment of all duty on goods imported and exported in the same state or on inputs used in the production of exports. All these incentives are justifiable but there is room for improvement in administering the tar- iff rebate schemes. This is especially true for the tariff relief on inputs processed and then exported. In interviews with industrialists, many felt that it would be feasible to begin exports of modern manufactures to neigh- boring African markets even w,ithout trade preferences, if the full rebate could be obtained. Actually, however, administrative delays in granting drawbacks greatly reduced the incentive to export, especially given the profitability of the domestic market. 43. In contrast to the positive ~ncentives noted above, a quota sys- tem on expatriate te-chnicians and skilled workers acts as a dis-incentive to foreign investors in Nigeria. Since it is much more costly to employ expa- triates than Nigerians in Nigeria, there :ts already a strong incentive to substitute Nigerians for foreign employees. It is questionable whether the quota system is beneficial. In any case it is very arbitrary in its adminis- tration, being an effective constraint on certain firms but having no effect on the operations of others. A better approach would be to concentrate on improving the quality of Nigerian labor. 44. The basic tax rate applied to industrial profits in Nigeria is 40 percent. However, as a temporary measure a 'super' tax was introduced during the war years by which profits above 15 percent of share capital would be subject to additional taxation at a rate of 10 percent for the first LN 5 thousand above the fifteen percent of share capital limit, 15 percent for the next LN 5 thousand, and 25 percent for any profits above that amount. Because share capital is interpreted as including earn- ings capitalized by issuing stock dividends, the tax encourages a retention of profits in Nigeria. It does, however, act as a disincentive to new in- - 17 - vestment in Nigeria as the ratio of share to debt capital is normally kept law in the first years of a firm's operation in order to lower the risk. It has often been possible for new firms to keep this ratio low enough that government provided debt capital was in effect risk capital. The advantage to the ~ntering firm from this type of financial arrangements is reduced by the nature of the super tax. • 45. Besides taxation on profits, excise taxation is heavily relied on in Nigeria to capture part of the income resulting from excess protection. In contrast to most other less developed countries, excise taxation is not applied to imported commodities, so that it has the effect of reducing the degree of protection to the domestic industry. The extent of which such reduction has occurred and haw it has affected individual industries is analysed in Chapter III. At this point, it is intended merely to define tt.e importance of excise taxation in terms of the range of commodities in- volved, to outline the rapid increase that has occurred in excise tax rates, and to indicate the extent to which the importance of excise taxation rela- tive to tariffs has changed. 46. An indication of the extent to which excise taxation has expanded in importance is given in tables 12, 13 and 14 in the Statistical Appendix. Table 12 lists the commodities subject to excise taxation in 1960, 1965 and 1970, table 13 shows the changes in the excise tax rates applied on these commodities, and table 14 indicates the importance of excise taxation rela- tive to import ~nd export taxation as sources of government revenue in the years 196.5/6fi to 1970/71. The salient points are the following. The com- modi tv h;u;e of excise taxation has expanded rapidly. In 1960, only ciga- rett<'<"l, hePr, lemonlirlP, r1Jnfectionery, and Ronp werl'! subject to excise. By IQ lfl, this list had Pxpanded to 46 commoditi e~ including virtually all the m::finr produ<..:ts of ~.i.gerian inrlu:=:try. F~trther'Tlnre, the rates of taxation imposed ou these cn111morlitl.es lvlVP lncl'P;1sed substantially over the decade. i\'8 ::t result of both the e~p i.n ltJo'J/(j() (a:=: coP,p:lrcd to !t7.1 and 10.0 percent for import and export taxes, re-specti.v~ly), thev are estimated to account for nea·rly 20 percent of ri"VPtiUe ln lfl7fl/71 (as comp1.red to 2.5.5 percent for import taxes and 8.1 perr~··nt for export taxes). • 4 7. The policy i.n !Ji.gc>ri n l1as bPc>n to use hi1~h t3riffs to protect new- ly introdue0d industries anrl then, with increased efficiency in these indus- trff'n, to n•duce nrot1~rtlnn not hv lnwt~dn:~ tariffs but by impoRing heavy excise taxation. Furtlu:>rmorP, 3ince 1'161,, it has been the policy to offset the protPctive effect of lncrpnq0s !11 tnrJffs desi~ned for revenue or bal- ::mce of paymt>nlB purpor;••<.; '-11tll corresponding increases in the excise tax rates on thP domestic industries concerned. - 18 - Manufacturing Priorities and the Hole of the Publi.c Sector 48. Concern has been expressed in the 1970-74 Development Plan about the extent to which the manufacturing sector has become characterized by industries processing imported inputs with low value added for a protecteo domestic market. !/ In an attempt to increase the linkage effects both with- in industry :md he tween industry and other s-ectors of the economy, the Plan proposes a realignment of priorities in the industrial sector. Priority areas of investment during the Plan period are therefore set as: • (a) Establishment and expansion of agro-allied industries. (b) Establishment of liquified petroleum gas and petro- chemical industries. (c) Promotion of integration, forward or backward linkage and diversification of the textile industry. (d) Establishment of a basic iron and steel industry to provide the input for the manufacture of inter'!114;!diate and capital goods as base for a future metallurgical complex. (e) Establishment of a passenger motor vehicle asserrbly plant. (f) Expansion of export-oriented industries. (g) Further import-substitution in areas of current deficiency. The attempt will be made, therefore, to give greater priority to raw mater- ial producing industries, industries processing domestically produced raw materials, and export-oriented industries, while reduced priority will be attached to import substituting industries based on imported raw materials. In Chapter III of this report, the structure of industrial protection is evaluated on the basis of these new priorities. 49. An indication of prospective development in the private sector of manufacturing may be obtained from investment proposals submitted to the government by potential investors. At the time of the Plan's prepara- • tion, 177 proposals of new firms were received. Table 15 of the Statistical Appendix ranks these proposals by industry group. While this gives only a rough indication of private sector prioTities, the te}(tile and metal pro- ducts industries rank highest. A better indication of the high priority attached to these industries by the private sector is that textiles account for 46 percent and metal products for 12 percent of total proposed private sector manufacturing investment. 1/ ~Cit., Chapter 29. - 19 - 50. The private sector investment plans are considered by government authorities as "in sharp contrast to the national priorities" and it is proposed to influence these plans with the selective use of the industrial incentives discussed above to benefit high priority raw material and domes- tically-produced-inputs processing firms. However, it is doubtful whether these incentives can have a significantly pronounced effect to redress the bias against raw material producing industries implicit in the structure of industrial protection. Thus changes in the tariff system may be required to increase the degree of protection accorded intermediate goods industries. To some extent, a change in tariff policy along these lines is being pre- sently instituted in Nigeria as was noted in the discussion of trade re- strictions. The selective use of incentives, however, should be very useful in encouraging industries processing domestic inputs as opposed to imported inputs, where the structure of protection has been found to be in accordance with Plan priorities (see Chapter Ill). 51. As well as attempting to influence private sector plans with trade, tax and incentive policies, the Nigerian Government also intends to play a more positive role through public sector control or participation in certain manufacturing activities. This is the most prominent feature of the 1970-74 Development Plan as it concerns the industrial sector. It represents an at- tempt both to alter the structure of manufacturing giving higher priority to the agro-allied, intermediate, and capital goods industries and to pro- mote Nigerianization of the manufacturing sector. To these ends it has been decided that the government will hold at least 55 percent of the equity in- vestment in the following industries: 11 (a) Iron and steel basic complex (b) Petro-chemical industries (c) Fertilizer production (d) Petroleum products (especially for local distribution). Substantial participation, to the extent of at least 35 percent of equity investment, will be required for a second set of industries: (a) Plantation production of traditional cash crops and • of basic raw materials for processing industries, such as wheat and sugar (b) Food industries (c) Forest product industries (d) Building materials and construction industries. J../ QE.:.. Cit., Chapter 16. - 20 - 52. The total projected cost of the Federal industrial program is about ~N 235 million. Since much of this program is to be carried out on the basis of participation with foreign investors, and as only part of the program will be executed in the 1970-74 period, the actual government dis- bursement during this period is expected to be only about ~N 41 million. 53. The government is expected to play a supplementary role in aiding the reconstruction of industries in the war affected regions. With about 60 enterprises involved, the total rehabilitation cost is estimated at J!!N "30 million by the Nigerian Government, a figure that should be interpreted as conservative. The predominant share of the reconstruction cost will be bon1v by the private sector but government loans can be expected to aid a number of industries controlled by public age·ncies such as the Nigerian Cement Com- pany at Nkalagu and the Glass Factory at Port Harcourt. 54. Specific projects in which heavy government participation will occur, the projected total investment involved, and the Federal Government share of the investment over the 1970-74 Plan period are as follows: Projected Federal Projected GOvernment total investment investment 1970-74 (~N million) (a) Sugar estates 19.5 4.1 (b) Palm kernel crushing 2.8 0.6 (c) \o/ooden furniture for export 0.6 0.6 ' (d) Pulp and paper mill 9.9 2.5 (e) Fish trawling and distributitm 3.9 0.7 (f) Fish and shrimp trawling 1.0 0.2 (g) Chemical complex 14.1 2.7 (h) Nitrogenous fertilizer 25.8 5.0 (i) Liquified petroleum gas 6.9 1. 3 (j) Single superphosphate 1. 2 0.2 (k) Second petroleum refinery 9.0 2.5 (1) Salt refinery 2.4 0.5 (m) Iron and steel complex 120.0 7.0 (n) Passenger car assembly 4.5 0.4 • 221.6 28.3 The balance of the LN 41 million projected Federal capital expenditures on industries during the 1970-74 period includes investment in other industries (bN 7.5 million), the previously noted loans to war affected areas (~N 3 million), aid to small scale industry (~N 1 million), and expenditures on training (~N • S million), research (bN • 3 million) and an industrial devel- opment consultancy service (LN .3 million). - 21 - 55. State capital expenditures on industries over the 1970-74 period are projected at ~N 45 million. A large number of State projects are in the range of agro-allied industries such as groundnut, palm kernel, and cotton seed crushing, textiles, leather tanning, integrated wood industry and starch manufacture. A considerable part of the planned expenditure is earmarked for rehabilitation of war damaged industries, industrial estates and aid to small industries generally. About one-quarter of the program remains to be identified. - 22 - III. TilE STRUCTURE OF INDUSTRIAL PROTECTION IN NIGl~RIA 56. In recent years, there has been a marked change in the environ- ment affecting the industrialization process in Nigeria. The low tariff open economy of the 1950's and early 1960's has been altered by a general rise in tariff and quantitative restrictions. As a result, Nigeria now has a manufacturing sector of which a significant part is not viable without continued protection from foreign competition. The system of industrial protection that has emerged is an outcome of several different policy ob- jectives. Trade restrictions have been introduced in order to (a) increase government revenue, (b) provide protection to enterprises establishing in Nigeria, and (c) to curtail import demand in the face of balance of payments pressures resulting from the civil war. The effect has been different de- grees of protection to different industries. In this chapter, the system of industrial protection is studied in order to quantify the degree of pro- tection afforded different industries. Such a study allows the comparative advantage of Nigeria in manufacturing activities to be identified, indicates the directions in which the allocation of resources has been distorted, and represents a first step in rationalizing industrial tariff - tax policies. 57. While the general rise in tariff rates on final products and the introduction of quantitative restrictions outlined in Chapter II reflect the increase in the 'tariff barrier', nominal tariff rates do not indicate the degree of protection given to manufa'Cturing processin·g activities. This is so because for the domestic producer not only tariffs on the product matter but also tariffs levied on material inputs, such as industrial mater- ials, fuels, parts, and components used in the production process. These tariffs reduce the extent of protection accorded to a particular firm or industry by raising the cost of raw ma'terial inputs, and can be regarded as a tax on the proce·ssing of such inputs. 1be Effective Rate of ProteGtion 58. The relevant concept for measuring the degree of protection is the effective rate of protection. 1/ This is defined in terms of value added (factor cost) rather than product price. I t thus takes into account the imposition of tariffs and protective measures on inputs as well as outputs. Accordingly, the effective rate of prote·ction represents the percentage margin by which the factor cost (value added) of a particular production process can exceed the factor cost of the same process if performed at world market prices at the existing rate of exchange. This measure has been calculated for a forty-two sector break-down of the Nigerian manu- facturing sector. 1/ This concept is considered at greater length in Annex 2, Conceptual and Methodological Issues in the Calculation of Effective Rates of Protec- tion. A still more comprehensive treatment is in Bela Ballasa's "Indus- trial Protection in Developing Countries", IBRD Report No. EC- 175, June 1970. - 23 - 59. Apart from tariffs on inputs and outputs, the effective rate of protection also depends on the share of value added in the product price. Effective rates can be very high if value added is a small proportion of the price even if nominal rates are low, or vice versa if value added is a large proportion of the total price. Thus effective protection may be high in a country with low or moderate nominal tariff rates if its manufacturing sector is mostly comprised of low value added industries. This is the case in Nigeria where low value added as a ratio to gross output in most indus- tries leads to fairly high levels of effective protection.1f 60. The significance of the effective rate of protection can be il- lustrated with an example. Assume that it requires x units of raw materials to make y units of final products. At the existing rate of exchange, let it be further assumed that valued at CIF prices, the x units of raw mater- ials cost bN800 and the y units of final products cost bN1000. Thus, if no tariffs are applied to either the raw materials or final goods, a do- mestic industry processing the raw materials would have a value added or factor cost of bN200. Let us now take the case where a 20 percent tariff is applied to imports of the final products and a tariff of 12-1/2 percent is applied to imports of the raw material, the domestic value of final out- put will be bN1200 and the domestic cost of the raw materials will be hN900. A firm that can process the raw .materials at a factor cost of no more than bN300 will be able to compete with the imported commodity. The effective rate of protection implied by the 20 percent nominal tariff on the final product and 12-1/2 percent nominal tariff on the intermediate goods is 50 percent - the percentage difference between free trade value added (bN200) and tariff distorted value added (bN300). This indicates that a firm with fifty percent higher factor costs than the corresponding value added at world prices is viable, given the structure of tariffs. If the excess of value added that protection provides is fully absorbed by the higher pro- cessing cost of domestic industry, the effective rate of protection serves to rank the efficiency of domestic industries relative to world prices. 2/ The excess of value added above world price levels permitted by the struc- ture of tariffs and other trade restrictions, however, may also reflect 1j Value added as a ratio of gross output for the total manufacturing sector in 1967 was 26 percent (cf. para. 18). If evaluated at world • prices it would be much lower because tariffs on the final product are higher than on the inputs, thus raising the value of gross output in relation to the value of the intermediate product. 2/ This assumes that the removal of trade restric:tions would not leave the domestic currency overvalued. If it did, the correction for overvaluation associated with free trade wou]d affect the calcul:tted protPction afforded domestic industries. The 'net' effective rate of protection, a measurP of protl"'etlon adjusted for differences be- tween the nctunl and free trndc shadow nxchangE- rate, is discussed ln Annex 2. - 24 - above average profits as well as high manuto...:lux:iug costs. To tht extent t:J.tt excessive profits are made, an income transfer from consumer to producer groups results and the calculated effective rate of protection will no longer ade- quately reflect the relative efficiency of different industries. In the long run, however, resources will tend to move into activities with above normal profits until any excess profits are eliminated. The structure of industrial protection as defined by the effective rates of protection will with time, therefore, influence the allocation of resources and determine the relative efficiency of different industries. Effective Rates of Protection: The Results 61. The effective rates of protection calculated in this study relate to 1968. They have been derived for both a narrow industry classification and for industry groups that are useful in summarizing the structure of in- dustrial protection and in analyzing the degree of protection afforded dif- ferent types of industry in relation to the priorities established in the 1970-74 Development Plan. In the most detailed breakdown, the effective rates of protection have first been calculated for a forty-two sector (4- digit !SIC) classification of industry. 1hese rates have then been aggre- gated for two broader industrial classifications: the first differentiat- ing industries as (a) primarily processing domestic materials for the do- mestic market, and (b) primarily processing imported materials for the domestic market; the second classifying industries as (a) producers of con- sumer goods and (b) producers of intermediate and capital goods. 62. The coverage of each industry is summarized in text table 4 by indicating value added and employment in the firms on which the calcula- tions are based relative to the corresponding totals for all reporting firms in each industry. Value added in non-reporting firms in recent industrial surveys has been rather small, about 10% of value added in reporting firms, so that table 4 gives a fairly good indication of the total coverage. This can be considered good in relation to often used practices of basing calcu- lations of effective rates of protection on one or two firms. For twenty- three sectors, all firms reporting in the 1968 industrial survey have been used in the study. For only five sectors (cutlery, handtools and hardware, textile spinning and weaving, wearing apparel except footwear, furniture except of metal, and glass products), has the coverage been less than 40 percent by either the value added or employment criterion. 63. The results for the forty-two sector classification of industry are presented in text table 5. As would be expected, effective rates of protection tend to be higher than nominal rates of protection, reflecting the fact that materials imported for use in Nigerian industry typically have much lower tariff rates than the tariff (or tariff equivalents when quantitative restrictions are important) applicable to the final products produced by these industries. The exceptions to this are export industries and industries producing products on which heavy excise taxes are levied. Where industry processes raw materials produced in Nigeria behind tariff barriers, the tariffs on their final products tend to be even higher. - 25 - Table 4: ESTIMATED COVERAGE OF THE STUDY OF EFFECTIVE PROTECTION IN 1968 Fh~s covered in %of reporting firms' Industry Value added Employment Tanneries and leather finishing 100 100 . Tin 100 100 Oil milling 100 100 Lumber and plywood 59 42 Rubber 100 100 Distilling and blending spirits 100 100 Soft drinks 100 100 Drugs and medicines 96 n,.a. Dairy products 100 100 Beer and stout 100 100 Paper containers, boxes, and paper boards 100 100 Paints, varnishes, and lacquers 100 100 Concrete products 100 100 Tires and tubes 100 100 Cement 100 100 Structural met~l products 70 92 • Structural clay products 100 100 Soaps, perfumes and cosmetics 89 49 Miscellaneous products of petroleum and coal 100 100 Bakery products n.ao 51 ~ectrical apparatus and supplies 100 100 'T'uble 4 cont'd. - ?6 - Firms covered in fEDIATE-CAPITAL GOODS INDUSTRIES IN NIGERIA, 1968 Effective rate of protection % Consumer goods industries L~ (a) including beer and tobacco 91 (b) excluding beer and tobacco 114 Intermediate-capital goods industries ~ (a) including cement 59 (b) excluding cement 73 1]_ Includes spirits, matches, drugs, dairy products, beer and stout, tobacco, textiles, paints, soft drinks, soap, cosmetics, shoes, elec- trical appliances, cutlery, plastic products, fabricated metal pro- ducts, motor vehicles, furniture, glass products, radios, television sets, record players, travel goods, tires and tubes, bakery products, made up textiles, sugar, canned fruit, meat, grain products, miscel- laneous food preparations, pottery, and wearing apparel. /2 Includes cement, structural clay products, concrete products, paper containers, boxes, paper board, structural metal products, and mis- cellaneous products of petroleum. - 37 - 83. Whether based on all industries or with the long established beer, tobacco, and cement industries excluded, these findings indicate the extent to which the system of industrial protection discriminates against raw ma- terial and capital goods industries in favor of consumer goods industries. l~e structure of protection is inappropriate to the priorities established in the 1970-74 Development Plan and partially explains why the misallocation of resources in the Nigerian manufacturing sector emphasized in the Plan, 1/ has become so pronounced. d4. The difficulty in rationalizing tbe protection afforded the con- sumer goods industries relative to the intermediate capital goods industries results from the fact that raising tariffs on the products of the latter will undermine the viability of the former, a good part of which is high cost and inefficient rather than excessively profitable. It is for this reason that the rapi.d rate of growth for industry projected over the coming plan period will be much more difficult to achieve than the past rapid growth in final processing import substituting industries. These latter industries could easily be stimulated especially in an economy with a large domestic market such as in Nigeria. The cost in terms of further misallocation of resources and higher cost of products to the Nigerian consumer would, however, be con- siderable. The loss would be compounded by the fact that a significant part of the income transfer from consuming groups to producing groups im- plied in tariff protected industrialization accrues to the expatriate and foreign business community. Protection and Industrial Profits B.5. The effective rate of protection calculation is based on the as- sumption that the value added is the return to scarce factors of production and that changes in value added determine the movement of factors of pro- duction between industries. In less developed countries, it might be argued that labor is not a scarce fActor of production and that it is solely the 1Hfff>rence in the rate of profit on capital invested that determines the allocation of resources between different activities. The relevant concept the-n is the effective rate of protection to profits; that is, the percentage increase or decrease in profits from world market conditions caused by the imposition of tariffs :md excise taxes. 86. While adjusting the effective rate of protection for the unrealis- tic assumption that unskilled labor is a scarce factor of production, the effective rate of protection to profits is subject to the theoretical criti- cism that i t ignores a scarce factor, skilled labor, and to the practical objection that since profits vary considerably from year to year, and from firm to firm, the calculated effective rate of protection to profits will tend to he even more unstable than the effective rate of protection based on \N\lue added. 1/ 2E_. _Git. , Chapter 29. - 38 - 87. In order to derive the effective rate of protection on profit~, data have been collected on profits. Using the admittedly unreliable origin- al book value of fixed assets as an indication of capital stock, estimates of the rate of return on capital were also derived. These data are useful in themselves as they indicate the absolute level of profitability in a parti- cular industry and, when calculated at world prices, allow the absolute dif- ference in profitability between the protected and world market conditions to be compared. Accordingly, the actual rate of profits, the rate of profits with world prices prevailing, and the effective rate of profits are presented in table 9 for the 42-sector breakdown of Nigerian industry. While, as noted before, the capital stock data are suspect, this does not affect the effective rate of protection on profits measure. However, it does mean that inter-industry differences in profit rates (as opposed to differences in pro- fit rates within particular industries under protected and world market con- ditions) have little meaning. 88. Since, with the assumptions made, all the benefits of protection or losses due to taxation are absorbed in profits, the effective rate of protection to profits indicates that the protective and export taxation policies are even more important in determining the viability of different industries. Thus, at the existing rate of exchange 12 industries would not have made positive profits if tariffs and excise taxes on their outputs and inputs had been removed. These include drugs and medicines, travel goods, cutlery, fruit and vegetable canning, slaughtering and preparing meat, mis- cellaneous food products, motor vehicle assembly, metal furniture, pottery, china and earthenware, wearing apparel, glass products, and the radio, tele- vision and communications assembly industries. Although the qualification must be kept in mind that the effective rate of protection to profit measure discriminates against labor intensive industries and is very sensitive to changing market conditions, it does give an indication of the extent to which many of the recently established industries are completely dependent on protection for survival. 89. Concentrating on the most important import substituting industries in Nigeria, the effective rate of protection to profits significantly affects the ranking of only one of these: the ~obacco products industry. Because of the importance of wage costs in aggregate gross value added (a relatively high 60 percent), the removal of protection would greatly reduce the profit- ability in this industry, from 77 percent to only 7 percent return on capital. On the other hand respectable rates of profits of 18 percent or higher could be maintained under world market conditions in the beer and stout, tires and tubes, and textiles industry. Among the six largest in- dustries only the cement and fabricated metal products industries are be- low the 18 percent return. For cement, the capital stock figures are high- ly suspect and the roderate extent to which profits depend on protection suggests that this industry should be ranked with the former group. The fabricated n~tals industry is highly profitable but it would barely make profits without high protection. 90. Adequate capital stock data would permit above normal profits to be distinguished from high factor costs, but the approximate capital stock data employed here is not reliable enough for this purpose. - 39 - Table 9: ACTUAL PROFITABILITY, PROFI'rABILITY AT WORLD MARKET PRICES, AND THE EFFECTIVE RATE OF PROTECTION TO PROFITS IN NIGERIA, 1968 Actual Profitability Effective rate profitabi- at world market of protection lity prices to profits ---- Percent of book value of fixed assets Rubber products 8 14 -42 Lumber and plywood 13 20 -35 Tanneries and leather finishing 111 170 -34 Non-ferrous metals (tin) 239 334 -28 Oil milling 204 279 -27 Distilling and blending spirits 108 6 - 1 Matches and candles 142 139 2 Beer and stout 56 41 .36 D:Li:ry products 11 6 83 Tires and tubes 38 18 111 Paints, varnishes and lacquers '3~ 18 111 Paper containers, boxes and paper board 17 8 112 O!lment 15 1 114 Soft drinks 26 12 116 Structural clay products 42 18 133 Soaps, perfumes, cosmetics 74 28 164 Sugar refineries 324 106 205 Concrete products 25 8 212 Electric&l apparatus and supplies 106 33 221 Textile spinning,weaving and printing 65 20 225 Miscellaneous products of petroleum, coal 95 28 239 Plastic products 67 18 272 Bakery products 23 6 283 footwear except of rubber or plastic 21 4 425 Grain mill products 26 3 766 Struct1~al metal products 29 17 982 'robacco 11 1 1000 Made up textiles except wearing apparel 39 3 1200 Fabricated metal products 47 2 2250 Drugs and medicines -11 -15 Travel goods -28 -44 * Cut,lery, handtools and hardware 23 -15 * ~,ru.i t and vegetable canning /rn t 6 - 1 * [~la11ghtering, preparing and preserviiiia' 70 -24 * Miscellaneous food products -13 -26 * Motor vehicle assembly 14 -19 * Metal fumi ture 58 - 4 * Pottery, china and earthenware 39 -4? * Wearing apparel except foo·twear 47 - 1 * Glass and glass products 27 -23 * Radjo, television and communications * ass~mbly 17 -28 * * Indust:ry not profitable at world market prices. - 40 - IV. FURTHER RESEARCH 91. The preceding analysis has attempted to indicat<~ hmv th<> industri- alization process in Nigeria has been affected hy tariff and tax policles. In these follotving parar-raphs, an indication ls giV(•n as to tlu~ natun• of further research that would be helpful tn Ci:tf'nding tills analysis. \-Je first consider how the reliability of calculations of effective rates of protee- tion m . be improved and then discuss other types of analysis that mif!,ht lw .1.y applied in Nigeria. Refinements of Effective Rates of Protection 92. The present study of effective rates of protection should be re- fined by further efforts to (a) derive satisfactory data on comparison of ex factory and CIF prices, (b) indicate more reliably the extent to which an industry's effective rate of protection reflects the level of factor costs or the existence of excess"profits, (c) calculate a 'net' effective rate of protection t..rhich adjusts the rates calculated here for possible exchange rate over-valuation as compared to the free trade equilibrium, and (d) carry out industry studies designed to isolate special aspects of par- ticular industries that would justify special treatment. 93. l~enever the CIF price plus tariff does not reflect prices of com- parable domestically produced commodities, price comparisons should be used to define an implicit nominal tariff to be used in calculating the effective rate of protection. This will be the case when quantitative restrictions have been imposed and when tariffs are prohibitive. While price comparisons were used in a few instances in this study, adequate price data are lacking. But even if ex factory and CIF price data were obtained for commodities where tariff rates do not reflect the degree of nominal protection~ consid- erable analysis of quality differences between imported and domestically produced commodities would be required before these price comparisons could be adjusted for use in the calculation of effective rates of protection. 94. A further aspect of the effective rate of protection measure is that it is difficult to determine whether a high effective rate of protec- tion indicates high factor costs or excess profits. While an attempt has been made to deal with this question by analyzing profit rates in industries studied in this report, the results could not be more than suggestive due to the lack of satisfactory data on the value of capital stock in Nigerian manufacturing. Improvement of the analysis in this respect must be delayed until more reliable capital stock data become available. 95. If the free trade shadow exchange rate is above the present ex- change rate, export and import substituting industries are being penalized by an over-valued exchange rate. To indicate relative efficiency of domes- tic industry in comparison to the free trade situation, it is necessary to adjust the effective rate of protection for the difference in free trade and protected exchange rates. The new measure is termed the 'net' effective - 41 - rate of protection; it is considered in detail in Annex 2. If the free trade equilibrium exchange rate were calculated, it would indicate the degree of protection justifiable on grounds of over-valued exchange rates. This would be an important factor in adopting the policy of equalizing the degree of protection to different import substituting industries. 96. The value of the findings given in Chapter III of this report rests in defining the present structure of industrial protection; consider- able study remains before these findings can be translated into detailed " policy recommendations concerning specific industries. While there is an 'n priori' expectation that efficiency \.rill be increased if the degree of protection is uniform between industries, this must be qualified by a con- sideration of possible factors which justify preferential treatment to certain industries. Thus, higher protection might be accorded (a) indus- tries processing domestically produced inputs because of the beneficial ef- fect these industries have on the domestic industries producing inputs, (b) industries which yield special benefits in ter~~ of improving the quality of the labor force, (c) industries that require temporary 'infant industry' protection - a result that could be achieved by delaying the introduction of excise taxes on the industries' output. In the context of the Nigerian economy, preference might also be given to industries with a high ratio of Nigerian ownership, although it might be advisable to rely on differential tax treatment to achieve this objective. An Alternative Measure: Domestic Resource Cost 97. In addition to the effective rate of protection, it would be use- ful to calculate an alternative criterion to evaluate domestic industries. This is the domestic resource cost measure which indicates the cost of a unit of foreign exchange earned in an export industry or saved in an import industry in terms of the domestic resources used in producing this earning or saving. The relative merits of the effective rate of protection and the domestic resource cost measure have been considered in detail elsewhere, 1f so they can be briefly indicated here. The domestic resource cost measure is relevant if the whole domestic production process (including domestic production of inputs used in production of the final product) is being evaluated while the effective rate of protection is appropriate if only the processing activity carried out in the industry under study is being evalu- ated. The measure that should be used will depend on the nature of the particular industry. 1bus if the output of an intermediate goods producing industry could be exnorted or used in other industries, it would be best to consider the final processinr, activity in isolation. On the other hand, if the intermediate goods producing industry is a mere satellite of the final ~oods industry with no alternative demand for its product, it is best to evaluate the combined production process. -Y See B• .Balassa and D. M. Schydlowsky, "Effective Tariffs, Domestic Cost of l.<'oreign Exchange and the Equilibrium Exchange Rate", Journal of Pol- itical Economy, May/June 1968. - 42 - Inter-industry Relations 98. Finally, the data collecteu on inter-industry relations for the calculation of effective tariff rates represents an important first step in deriving an input-output table for the Nigerian economy. While such a table does exist in Nir,eria, it is too aggregative and out of date to be used for evaluating different industries at the present time. Once a re- liable table is calculated, estimates can be derived of the shadow prices of all factors of production, which can then be used to directly calculate .. the profitability of different industries. ANNEX 1 MANUFACTURING STATISTICS IN NIGERIA 1. The basic source of statistics on the manufacturing sector in Nigeria is the annual survey of all firms with ten or more employees. Be- fore 1962, all industrial surveys suffered greatly from non-response. By calculating average value added for different industries per unit of major raw materials from the scanty returns and using the results in conjunction with information on supply of raw materials (with some allowance being made for household consumption), a rough estimate of aggregate value added was obtained for the total manufacturing sector. After 1962, the aggregate value added estimates have been obtained directly from the annual surveys which achieved a much wider coverage. The major disruptions caused by the civil war resulted in the 1966 survey being discontinued in the Eastern Region and prohibited other surveys from being conducted in East Central, South Eastern, and Rivers States in 1967 and 1968. For these reasons, com- parisons of the manufacturing statistics for the pre-1962 years, the 1962- 1965 period, and the post-1965 period are not reliable. 2. Aside from the disruptions caused by civil war, recent data on manufacturing suffer from major deficiencies that will be briefly outlined in this Annex. These concern the definition of value added adopted by the Nigerian Federal Office of Statistics, the method of adjusting for non- reporting firms in the survey, the method of adjusting for firms with less than ten employees, and the method of deflating current price value added in order to obtain constant factor cost series. Definition of Value Added 3. In official publications, value added is defined as gross output minus industrial costs. The latter are defined so as to include the cost of raw materials, fuel, electricity, contract work done by others, and the cost of goods bought and resold without further processing. Industrial cost excludes, however, an 'other cost' item comprising rental payments, professional fees, costs of water, office materials, postage, insurance, advertising, hired transport, non-specified costs, and excise taxes. All these latter costs are thus included in value added-.--This has important implications for published statistics on the industrial sector. 4. Firstly, it leads to a substantial over-estimation of value added in manufacturing, as reported in the industrial survey, by 30 percent in 1963 and 64 percent in 1967. Several adjustments are made to the survey value added aggregate before it is used in the Nigerian national accounts but excise taxes are not deducted. Subtracting excise taxes collected from domestic industry in 1965, (the last year for which a country wide survey is available), the size of the manufacturing sector is reduced by 20 percent from 4.8 percent to 3.8 percent of gross domestic product at factor cost. ANNEX 1 Page 2 5. Secondly, because rates of excise taxation have risen rapidly and have been extended to an increasing number of commodities, and since excise taxes account for about half of the 'other cost' item, the inclusion of other costs in value added has imparted an upward bias to the rate of growth of manufacturing. Between 1963 and 1967, for instance, revenue from excise taxation rose by 407 percent while in the same ped.od gross domestic pro- duct contributed by manufacturing rose by 35 percent. If value added is redefined as gross output minus total non-factor costs except for depreci- ation, the rate of growth of value added in the period 1963 to 1967 in cur- rent prices as reported in the industrial survey is reduced from 59 percent to 10 percent, or on a compounded annual basis from 12.4 percent to 2.S per- cent. Since manufacturing is reported to have grown in current prices at 7.9 percent per annum for the same period, adjustment made to the valut:: added aggregate as reported by the Industrial Survey Branch of the Federal Office of Statistics before it is used in the National Accounts corrects to some extent the upward bias. However, since it is explicitly stated that excise taxes are not deducted, this correction is not complete, in terms of value added at factor cost. Adjustment for Non-reporting Firms 6. Adjustment of the reported value added aggregate in the industrial survey must be made in order to account for firms failing to report. An indication of the magnitude of the required adjustment is suggested by the estimated coverage of the survey in 1965, the last year of a countrywide census. In terms of establishments responding to the questionnaires, the coverage was 83.5 percent. In terms of employment, the coverage is esti- mated to have been 94.1 percent. The adjustment of the value added aggre- gate is done by assuming the same value added per worker in non-reporting firms as in reporting firms and using estimates of employment in non-report- ing firms to estimate value added in the latter firms. 7. It could be argued that the .adjustment for non-reporting firms further inflates the value added in $8.nufacturing on the grounds that ef- ficiency in firms that haven't responded to the survey might be less than in reporting firms. But the unreliability of the estimates of employment in non-reporting firms and the wide variability of value added per man noted for reporting firms merely tends to increase general uncertainty in the statistics. The effect on estimates of the growth rate is also ambig- uous and hard to quantify. The response to the surveys has generally im- proved and to the extent that non-reporting firms were previously inade- quately accounted for, the rate of growth might be slightly upward biased. However, if value added in previously non-reporting firms was over-esti- mated, improved coverage of the surveys will tend to bias the growth rate slightly downward. ANNEX 1 Page 3 Adjustment for Firms with Less than Ten Employees 8. The industrial surveys cover firms with more than ten employees. It is therefore necessary to adjust the value added aggregates to account for firms with less than ten employees. For this purpose, an upward adjust- ment of 20 percent has been used. This may turn out to be reasonable, but it is only an arbitrary assumption. The value added aggregate might be up- ward or downward biased because of errors in this assumption • • 9. The twenty percent adjustment can, however, be expected to upward bias the rate of growth. This is because in a growing economy the expan- sion of large scale industry tends to replace small scale operations. This would lead to a falling proportion of value added contributed by small scale industry. By assuming it constant, the growth rate is exaggerated. 10. The lack of adequate surveys on small scale industry substantially distorts data on the structure of manufacturing. The percentage of value added contributed by small scale enterprises, even if it should average out to 20 percent, can be expected to vary widely from industry to industry. This is not taken into account in published data on the sectoral distribu- tion of manufacturing activities. Price Index Used for Deflating 11. In order to obtain growth rates in real terms, the value added series in current prices is deflated by a producer price index. The method of deriving this producer price index is not adequate to permit reliable growth rates to be calculated. It is constructed by halving the number of points above or below 100 of a consumer price index for commodities. This is said to be justified on the grounds that consumer and producer prices tend to move in the same direction but that producer prices tend to lag be- hind consumer prices. However, in a period of rising prices, this can be expected to underestimate increases in producer prices. The lag in adjust- ment, if i t occurs, will only be a temporary delay before producer prices can be expected to increase in line with consumer prices. The effect of using the calculated producer price index will be to upward bias the rate of growth shown by the constant price series. Thus, the implicit manufactur- ing and crafts deflator used in the national accounts shows an increase in manufacturing producer prices of 3.5 percent from 1966/67 to 1969/70, while the implicit gross domestic product deflator indicates a general price rise of 6.8 percent. While further study is required, the significant rise in tariffs and trade restrictions on manufactured commodities during these years suggests that producer price increases have been more substantial than this. If the manufacturing price increased at the same rate as prices in general, the industrial growth rate would be reduced by this factor alone from 15.1 percent in 1966/67 to 1969/70 to 11.8 percent. In any case, the arbitrary assumptions involved in deriving the producer price index add to the dubious quality of the growth rate estimates. ANNEX 1 Page 4 12. In summary, it is hard to escape the conclusion that part of re- corded growth is illusionary. Thus, while the rate of growth of manufactur- ing and crafts is recorded as averaging 11.7 percent per annum in real terms over the period 1965/66 to 1969/70, excluding excise taxes and assuming pro- ducer prices move in line with retail prices of manufactured goods reduces growth in real terms by 22 percent to an average rate of 9.1 percent per annum. • ANNEX 2 CONCEPTUAL AND METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN THE CALCULATION OF EFFECTIVE RATES OF PROTECTION 1. In this Annex, certain properties of the effective rate of protec- tion are considered in greater detail, and methodological issues that arose in calculating this measure in Nigeria are discussed. 2. The effective rate of protection {z) is given by formula {1), where t and tm are the tariff or tariff equivalents on the final product and material inputs, m and v stand for the share of material inputs and value added in the world market price of the product, and w is the domestic value added distorted from the world value added by protective measures. {1) {1 + t) - m {1 + tm) - {1 - m) ... t mtm 1 - m 1 - m It is assumed that the input coefficients for raw materials are constant and that all world prices are determined externally. 'Net' Effective Protection 3. As noted in Chapter III, the effective rate of protection repre- sents the percentage margin by which the factor cost {value added} of a particular production process can exceed the factor cost of the same pro- cess if performed under world market conditions. The effective rates of protection indicate the efficiency of the domestic industry relative to international forces if it is assumed that the existing exchange rate is the free trade equilibrium exchange rate. However, existing exchange rates in many less developed countries are either over-valued at present or would become so if all import restricting measures were removed. It is therefore necessary to derive the 'net' effective rate of protection by adjusting the effective rate of protection for exchange rate overvaluation if the absolute degree by which protected value added exceeds free trade value added is to be indicated. Otherwise, the effective rate of protection merely serves to rank industries. In the example given in paragraph 60 in Chapter III, assume that under free trade conditions, the actual exchange rate overvalues the domestic currency by 50 percent. The values of final product and raw mater- ials in domestic currency converted at the shadow exchange rate would be bN 1500 and bN 1200 (rather than bN 1000 and bN 800), respectively. The . resulting value added of bN 300 is equal to the value added distorted by tariffs of 12-1/2 percent and 20 percent on raw materials and final pro- ducts, respectively and calculated at the actual exchange rate. Thus, while the unadjusted effective rate of protection was 50 percent, the 'net' effective rate of protection is zero reflecting the fact that the domestic industry, capable of processing the raw materials at a factor cost of bN 300 would be viable under free trade conditions. 4. It would be useful to calculate the 'net' effective rate of pro- tection. For instance, if it were then decided that, say 20 percent pro- tection should be given to industry because of the effect of industrial ANNEX 2 Page 2 activity on promoting entrepreneurship and developing skilled labor, or be- cause it is felt that an enclave petroleum industry, efficient in generating for- eign exchange, will restrict the development of industry better integrated with the local economy by maintaining a lower exchange rate than would be viable without foreign exchange revenues from the petroleum industry, the 'net' effective rate of protection would identify those industries that meet the criterion decided upon. Calculation of the 'net' effective rates of protection required for the viability of proposed industrial projects could also be useful in their evaluation. The adjustment, once the shadow exchange rate is determined, is carried out by formula (2) z' (2) z' • r (1 + z) _ 1 z' a r (1 + z) - 1 r' r' is the 'net' effective rate of protection, r the actual exchange rate, and r' the shadow exchange rate. Note that the adjustment for overvaluation does not affect the ranking of industries given by the effective rate of protection. 5. The calculation of 'net' effective protection has not been at- tempted at the present time because of the difficulty of estimating the free trade shadow exchange rate given the extensive disruptions to trade resulting from the war. The quality of statistics in Nigeria even under normal circumstances would make the estimation of the shadow exchange rate difficult since it is required to know the demand and supply elasticities for exports and imports at home as well as abroad. Once the balance of payments returns to more normal conditions, an attempt should be made to calculate the shadow exchange rate. The Effective Rate of Protection and Excise Taxation 6. While excise taxes on a product do not affect its protection if levied on both the domestically produced and imported varieties, they re- duce protection if, as in Nigeria, they are levied only on the domestic products. Since the excise tax is placed on the ex factory value of the domestic goods, the price the domestic producer in competition with imports realizes net of these taxes is p(l + t)(1 -e), where pis the CIF price, t is the import duty, and e is the rate of excise taxation. Accordingly, the effective rate of protection is given by formula (3). (3) z • t - e - te - mtm 1 - m 7. The effect of the imposition of an excise tax on the nominal and effective rate of protection is substantial. Thus, if import duties were 33-1/3 percent and excise duties were 25 percent, the nominal protection to the industry would be zero (t - e - te • 0). Since nominal tariffs on final products are typically higher and excise tax rates lower than this, the nominal protection is still, of course, positive. But even a 100 percent nominal tariff will be reduced by 40 percent with the imposition of a 20 percent excise duty. The effect on the effective rate of protection is con- sidered below. ANNEX 2 Page 3 Sensitivity of the Results 8. Because of the poor quality of data in Nigeria and variation in the input coefficients between firms in the same industry, it is important to appreciate the sensitivity of the results to errors in estimating the variables and parameters that enter into the calculations. For this reason, sensitivity elasticities have been derived from (3) that give the percentage change in the calculated effective rate of protection per unit percentage error in estimating each parameter or variable. The results are given in relations (4) through (7) where (4) Et a ~1-e~ t (1-m) z (5) Etm = -- -m (1-m) . tm z (6) Ee = -(1 + tl .~ (1 - m) z (7) Em • -(1-m) tm + (t-e-te-mtm) m (1-m) 2 z E is the sensitivity elasticity of the effective rate to a one percent change in the subscribed parameter or variable. To evaluate these results, hypothetical values have been taken for the parameters that roughly approxi- mate the values for the Nigerian economy. They are t = .7, tm = .3, e = .1 and m = .8. The value of m may appear high, but it should be recalled that for manufacturing as a whole, the ratio of value added to gross output was 26 percent in 1967 (see table 7, Statistical Appendix). This would imply a share of inputs in final output of .74, but this is in tariff distorted values. International prices are relevant for calculating m and since final output is overvalued by tariffs on inputs (except for export industries) and excise. the .8 value seems reasonable. With these values, the effective rate of protection from formula (3) is 145 percent. 9. Substituting the hypothetical values in the formulae (4) through (7), it is determined that Et • 2.2, Etm • .8, Ee • .6, and Em • 3.2; that is, for instance, that a one percent error in estimating the tariff on the final product will be translated into a 2.2 percent error in estimating the effective rate of protection. These findings shaw that the effective rate of protection is most sensitive to errors in estimating the tariff on the final product and the m parameter based on the input-output coefficients. Since t is the percentage increase (or decrease, if an export tax) in domes- tic price permitted by tariffs, it is adequately defined by the legal tar- iff (or export tax rate) only (a) if international prices cannot be affected by the domestic economy; (b) if the domestic commodity is qualitatively identical to the competitive imported commodity; and (c) if tariffs are not prohibitive and quantitative restrictions are not imposed. Condition (a) is satisfied for prices of imported commodities, but some degree of market power may exist for exports. Conditions (b) and (c) are not satisfied, at ANNEX 2 Page 4 least to some extent, for many or even most domestically produced import substitutes. Thus, errors in estimating t are very likely to occur. The estimation of t in Nigeria was based on three different sources of data, as described below, in order to improve the reliability, but some degree of error must be expected. The m was estimated from returns to the industrial survey by adjusting the reported share of inputs (valued at domestic prices) for the effect of the tariff distortions. Since moderate variations occur in the share of inputs in total output from year to year and from firm to firm in the same industry, the input share in domestic prices will not be perfectly stable and some variation of the effective rate of protection from firm to firm and year to year will occur. Added to this, errors may occur in reporting for the industrial survey, and more importantly (since tariffs and tariff equivalents must be used), in calculating the input share in world prices from the import share in domestic prices. The calculated ef- fective rate of protection is least sensitive to variations in the two para- meters that are most easily es.timated, the excise tax rate and the tariff 'equivalent' on the input, which is usually the legal tariff in Nigeria, since most inputs are freely imported in Nigeria. However, even here, dif- ficulties arise because of tariff rebate schemes that apply to some firms and not to others and depend on whether any output is exported or not. 10. An example of not completely unrealistic errors occurring in es- timating the parameters that all tend to increase the effective rate of pro- tection measure is useful for both indicating the sensitivity of the measure and how important it is to be very careful in making the calculations, and also suggests considerable care should be taken in using the measure for project evaluation. Assuming a ten percent over-estimation of t and m, and a ten percent under-estimation of tm and e, the effective rate of protection is raised from 145 percent to 311 percent: an increase of 115 percent. Nominal Tariff Rates Used in Calculating the Effective Tariff Rates 11. The nominal tariff rates used in calculating the effective rates of protection were derived from three types of information: (a) legal tar- iff rates; (b) observed tariff rates defined as duty collected as a percent- age of CIF import value; and (c) price comparisons between ex factory prices and CIF (Lagos) prices. Legal tariff rates would be adequate if no quanti- tative restrictions or foreign exchange controls were imposed and if these rates were applied to all imports within a specific tariff classification. These conditions have not existed in Nigeria during the period of this study. Quantitative restrictions and foreign exchange controls were increasingly relied on during the crisis years. 'Ihe tariff rates on raw materials ap- plied to different producers differ depending on whether the producer has qualified for the approved user and tariff rebate schemes designed to stimu- late industrialization. Further difficulties arise in relying solely on legal tariff rates because of changes in the tariff schedule during the period of study. While 'observed' tariff rates on the narrow five digit SITC commodity classification can help take into account these difficulties, they may also be misleading, because of special tariff rates applied to gov- ernment (procurement) imports. They also show tariff collections gross of ANNEX 2 Page 5 tariff rebates. Furthermore, they give unreliable indication of nominal protection if import restrictions are used hand in hand with tariffs. Price comparisons are, in a sense, the ideal indicator since it is possible to calculate the nominal tariffs implicit in quantitative restrictions. 12. Nevertheless, besides the considerable practical difficulty of obtaining reliable ex factory prices in Nigeria, price comparisons have a major weakness for this purpose. In Nigeria, as in most less developed countries, considerable qualitative differences exist between the imported commodity and its domestically produced counterpart. Price comparisons are thus made up of two components: a difference due to the effect of tariffs and/or quantitative restrictions which will be reflected in a higher sell- ing price for the domestically produced commodity, and a qualitative dif- ference which will favor the imported commodity. 13. The importance of the qualitative difference was reflected in many price comparisons that were made, where, even with high nominal tariff rates, prices of domestically produced items were found to be lower than the CIF price. This was found to be the case, for instance, with tires, tubes, re- cord players, confectionery, and shoes. Of course, with sufficient time and effort, it should be possible to obtain meaningful price comparisons on qualitatively similar commodities. This was not feasible within the time available for this study. 14. Modifications of the price comparisons made for this study may not greatly change the results obtained here. Firstly, quantitative restric- tions, while imposed prior to 1968 and expanded during that year, had their greatest impact in 1969 and early 1970. The effective tariff rates calcu- lated for 1968 for products where meaningful price comparisons could not be obtained may still adequately reflect the protective effect in that year. Secondly, there is reportedly a considerable lag in the adjustment of pro- ducer prices to higher retail prices. Even where quantitative restrictions were imposed in 1968, adjustment in 1968 producer prices may not have taken place in that year. Of much greater relevance to our purposes, however, is the expectation that with the end of the political crisis and the rapid re- covery of foreign exchange earnings, especially from petroleum, there will he a relaxation of the quantitative restrictions. This expectation was buttressed by the lifting of some of the quantitative restrictions in April, 1970. 15. Where possible, all three of the above mentioned sources of infor- mation were used in arriving at appropriate nominal tariff rates. The exact sources used for particular commodities are discussed in the Industry Notes appended to this report. In the vast majority of cases, legal or observed tariff rates were employed. Only for wheat flour, matches, cigarettes, candles, beer, stout, textiles, and cement were price comparisons sufficient- ly reliable to be used. 16. In those cases where an industry produces more than one commodity, the nominal tariff rates on particular commodities have been weighted by the commodities' share in the total output of the industry to arrive at nominal ANNEX 2 Page 6 protection for the industry as a whole. For most studies, data with the required detailed breakdown of output by product are not available. However. for Nigeria the responses to the 1968 industrial census are quite good in this respect and no difficulty was encountered in finding an appropriate average for nominal tariffs. The Data on Input-Output Relations 17. The structure of industrial costs used in deriving the estimates of effective rates of protection is based on the 1968 industrial survey that was conducted for all of Nigeria, except for the war affected East Central, South Eastern, and Rivers States. Since the structure of raw material costs is not published, and since the 1968 survey will not be published until 1971, this data was obtained from the individual industry responses. The quality of the returns varied widely from industry to industry. Many firms supplied a detailed breakdown while others simply aggregated all material costs and gave the aggregate value. In deriving the cost structure for the 42 sector breakdown, the data for all reporting firms could not be used for every industry. In certain cases, it was necessary to choose firms that did give a detailed breakdown as representative of the total industry. On the other hand, the breakdown of outputs produced and other industrial costs has been found to be very satisfactory. Similarly, data on employment and wage costs used in the alternative profitability calculations are very re- liable, but data on the original book value of fixed capital assets is only a rough indication of the true value of capital stock. Data on tariff rates is satisfactory, but where price comparisons were necessary, the available price data was often found inadequate. Despite data difficulties and a rapidly changing trade system, the effective tariff rates derived do give a good indication of the degree of protection given different industries in Nigeria. 18. So that the reliability of these calculations may be easily judged and because it may be helpful to further work on defining the structure of industrial costs and inter-industry relations in Nigeria, extensive industry notes are appended to this report giving the data used in deriving effective tariff rates. In presenting this data, the confidentiality rule of the Nigerian Federal Office of Statistics has been complied with, so that in the cases where it has not been possible to use three or more firms, the detailed breakdown is not given. The Treatment of Depreciation 19. For purposes of this study, depreciation allowances have been in- cluded in the definition of value added. Their inclusion in value added means that the effective rate of protection has been calculated as the per- centage distortion of gross value added. Since a major share of industrial capital formation is comprised of traded commodities whose cost to domestic industry is affected by trade restrictions, it might be theoretically pre- ferred to deal with net value added and to take into account the extent to which trade restrictions have increased depreciation allowances. The ANNEX 2 Page 7 eJ:'fect of this modification of the analysis would be minor, however, since depreciation allowances are a small share of value added. Furthermore, practical difficulties exist in properly defining the commodity mix of items on which depreciation allowances are calculated. The accelerated depreciation allowance scheme heavily relied on in the past as an industrial incentive 1/ also distorts the figures available on total depreciation. The effective rate of protection calculated on a gross basis has therefore been adopted in this study. Non-Traded Commodities 20. In calculating the effective rates of protection, it has been necessary to take into account the effect of the tariff system on non- traded goods. Non-traded commodities may be accounted for under several alternative assumptions. Corden adds the direct and indirect value added and the cost of direct and indirect material inputs in the non-traded goods to the value added and the material costs of the industry using these goods for which effective tariff rates are to be derived. An alternative proce- dure has been used by Balassa based on the assumption that non-traded goods are supplied at constant cost and that their prices vary in response to changes in the cost of material inputs used in their production. 2/ For the Nigerian study, non-traded goods consist of electricity and an 'other cost' item encompassing such expenses as repairs, advertisements, and entertain- ment. Since these are a very small part of total industrial costs, the choice of procedure for handling non-traded commodities does not have much practical significance. The Balassa procedure has been adopted and the percentage increase in price of electricity due to tariffs on material in- puts in its production has been calculated, being 20 percent, and a rough estimate has been used for the total costs item, 35 percent. 11 Cf. para. 38 of the report. !/ The Corden and Balassa methods are discussed at greater lengths in Bela Balassa, Structure of Protection in Developins Countries, The John Hopkins Press, forthcoming. STATISTICAL APPENDIX Table No. 1 Gross Domestic Product at Current Factor Cost, 1963/64 - 1969/70 2 Gross Domestic Product at Constant (1962) Factor Cost, 1963/64 - 1969/70 3 Value Added of the Manufacturing Sector by Industry Group 1958, 1963 and 1967 4 Value Added and Employment in 1968 in Finns with Ten or more Employees commencing Production in 1966, 1967 and 1968 by Industry Group 5 Ratio of Imports to Total Domestic Supply for Selected Commodity Groups, Nigeria 1968 6 Exports of Processed Primary Products, Nigeria, 1965-1969 7 Gross Output and Value Added in Manufacturing, 1967 8 Rates of Profits on Sales in Nigerian Manufacturing, 1967 and 1963 9 Value Added, Gross Output, and Employment in 1968 in Firms with Ten or more Employees comm.enciltg Operation during 1966 to 1968, by State 10 Private Foreign Share of Paid Up Capital, 1965 and in Firms commencing Production during 1966 to 1968 11 . Pioneer Companies by Industry, 1968 12 Commodities Subject to Excise Taxation, 1960, 1965 and 1970 13 Selected Excise Duties, 1960, 1964 and 1969 14 Revenues from Excise Taxes, Import Duties, and Export Duties, 1965/66 to 1970/71 15 Industries Ranked by the Number of Projected New Finns, Nigeria, 1970 Table 1: GROSS OOMESTIC PRODUCT AT CURRENT FACTOR COST 1963/64 - 1969/70 (In millions of £N) 1963/64 1964/65 1965/66 1966/67 1967/68 1968/69 1969/70 Ag~iculture, Forestry ar:d. ?ishLii; 837.5 839.0 645.9 892.2 656.5 86J.J 871.9 ,....: ...... .,. ":..~.: •• ..J..4........:_. 'L 28.0 40.8 74.J 81.7 40.8 44-9 60.6 Harr:..fc.ctu!'i.-,g and Crafts 78.9 82.4 96.4 ~8.0 115.6 135.2 155.5 ?:l::!c-vricity and ivater Supply 7.7 8.8 9.J 9 .~J 9.1 9.5 10.3 f.~-~~n: and Constr~ction 6.::..o4 6).2 80.6 82.7 74.4 77.0 81.6 D::.::::;ribution 191.0 208.2 216.4 216 ..1 209.6 211.7 215.9 '.:'::·~:---!.:: po:t 62.9 62.3 58.0 55.5 52.7 53.0 53.5 Cc.:-~~:.,.ica t.ions 6.9 8.4 9.8 10.0 8.5 8.6 9.0 G(;T.':::r-::!.1 Govern.'1l.ent 52.5 54.6 54.0 54.0 49.1 51.1 55.7 ::.c.::c;.: ~ion 37.6 4h.l 45.0 49.4 h6.4 47.3 49.7 !ie:1l~h 7.7 9.8 lO.J 9.7 9.6 9.8 10.5 o:.:-:.er Se:-vices 31.1 35.4 LO.} L.S .. 8 53.6 59.0 6h.9 Total 1403.2 1457 .o 151.:.0.3 1605.0 1525.9 1570.4 1639.1 Scr..u:-ce: Federal Office of Statistics ~'1d Federal Ministr,y of Economic Development and Reconstruction. ' l;ote: For 1967/68 to 1969/70 finn data on the three Eastern States are not available. il:o-,raver '·.as fa::- as possible, production in these states is included in these figures.. The figures for 1967/68 to 1969/70 ara not strictly comparable to those of earlier years • .. ; .,_ Table 2: GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT AT CONSTANT (1962) FAC'roR COST 1963/64 - 1969/70 (In millions of £N) 1963/64 1964/65 1965/66 1966/67 1967/68 1968/69 1969/70 Agriculture, Forestr.y and Fishing 870.8 866.7 870.9 869.5 817 805.8 801.8 Nining 31.3 47.5 82.4 114.4 51.5 55.6 68.4 Y.ia..""l.ufacturing and Crafts 76.8 78.8 91.7 93.1 108.9 126.3 142.7 Electricity and Water SupplY 1.3 8.1 9.2 10.7 10.0 10.5 ll.2 Building and Construction 66.0 65.0 80 .. 0 81.3 72.3 73.4 76.3 Distribution 180.9 194.9 202.7 200.9 193.9 191.0 190.0 Transport 61.4 59.3 55.6 53-3 50~1 49.8 50.4 Corr.municatio:::1s 6.7 7.9 9.2 9-4 7.8 7.8 8.1 General Government. 51.3 52.1 51.6 51.6 48.1 49.1 52.6 Education 37.8 43.0 43.7 48.2 46.3 47-3 49.2 Health 1.5 9.4 9.8 9-3 9.6 9.1· 9.7 Other services 27.9 )0.7 )6.2 41.4 47.2 50.5 _24.0 Total ~25.7 1463 .J~ l5lt3 .o 1583.1 1462.4 1475.2 1513.8 Source: Federal Office of Statistics and Federal Ministry of Economic Development and Reconstruction. Note: See note to Table 1. Table 3: VALUE ADDED OF THE MANUFACTURING SECTOR BY INDUSTRY GROUP 1958, 1963 AND 1967 Industry Group £N million %Shares 1958 1963 1967 1963 1967 Food and tobacco 4.76 10.77 16.02 19.6 17.7 Beverages 4.50 10.17 11 .79 18.5 13.0 Vegetable oil milling 1.51 3.42 7.22 6.2 8.0 Textiles 1.76 3.99 13.68 7-2 15.1 Garments 0.04 0.09 1.02 0.2 1 •1 Footwear 0.24 0-54 1.35 1.0 1.5 Furniture and fixtures 0.32 o. 73 0.62 1.3 0.7 Glass products and pottery 0.01 0.02 0.05 o.o o.o Paints 0.16 0.36 0.59 0.7 0.6 Bricks & tiles 0.04 0.10 0.12 0.2 0.1 Cement and cement products 1.51 3.42 3.14 6.2 3-5 Basic industrial chemicals & petroleum products 1.27 2.87 7.04 5.2 7.8 Electrical equipment o.o5 0.12 0.44 0.2 0.5 Basic metal and metal products 1 .27 2.88 6.07 5.2 6.7 Motor vehicle assemblY 0.29 0.65 o.8o 1 .2 0.9 Other manufactures 6.57 14.80 16.68 27.0 18.4 Total Manufactures 24.3 54.9 100 100 Crafts 16.2 20.4 22.4 Total Manufactures & Crafts 40.5 75.3 112 ·9 Source: Federal Office of Statistics; Industrial Surveys, 1963 and 1967. Table 4: VALUE ADDED AND ~PLOYMENT IN 1968 IN FIRMS WITH TEN OR MORE ~PLOYEES COMMENCING PRODUCTION IN 1966, 1967 AND 1968 BY INDUSTRY GROUP l/ Industry Group NUmber of va!ue aaaea . .new firms ( £N thousand) Employment Food and beverages 5 8 144 Textiles, footwear and apparel 9 1,420 3,344 Saw milling and wood products 12 9 302 Printing and paper products 4 72 261 Chemicals, paints and plastics 13 417 1,330 Rubber products, tires ·and tubes 2 220 161 Cement, pottery and glass products 5 -3 898 Metal products and miscellaneous 22 378 1,978 Total 72 2,521 8,148 2/ Eastern States excluded. Source: lt,ederal Office of Statistics, Industrial.Survey 1968. Table 5: RATIO OF IMPORTS TO TOTAL DOMESTIC SUPPLY FOR SELECTED COMMODITY GROUPS 1 NIGERIA 1968 Soft drinks ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1% Matches and candles •••••••••••••••••••••••••• 2% Bakery products •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1% Flour .•...•................•...•••.•.•.....•. 1% Beer and stout ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 2% Cigarettes ................................... Confectionery •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 3% 4% Roofing sheets ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 5% Footwear ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 6% Soaps, perfumes and cosmetics •••••••••••••••• 5% Cement ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 12% Paints ....................................... Furniture •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 19% 20% Miscellaneous products of petroleum and coal •• 26% Textiles ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 28% Daiq products ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 28% Tires and tubes •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 36% Radios, television sets and record players ••• 40% Suitcases and bags ••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 44% Potable spirits •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 47% Refined sugar •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 57% Structural clay products ••••••••••••••••••••• 76% Drugs and medicines •••••••••••••••••••••••••• 90% Glass and pottery ............................ Motor vehicles ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 94% 98% Source: Derived from: Federal Office of Statistics, Ni~ria Trade Summary, December 1968 I and Indus trial Survey 1 o8. Table 6: EXOORTS OF PROCFSSED PRIMARY PRODUCTS, NIGERIA, 1965-1969 Quantity Quantity (thousand units) Value (£N million) . ll.lrl.t 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 Groundnut oil tons 91 108 71 109 99 10.0 10.0 7.2 9-5 11 •1 Groundnut cake " 163 133 131 171 168 5.3 4. 7 4.2 4.9 5.0 Rubber II 68 70 48 52 56 10.9 11 .5 6.; 6.3 9.6 Palm oil II 150 140 16 3 8 13.6 11.0 1 ·3 0.1 0.4 16 Tin metal II 11 11 10 11 10 14.9 15.4 13.0 13.7 1J.9 Timber and plywood Cu.rt. 20, 1o6 18,896 11,598 11,353 12,133 1·7 6.8 4.J 4.J 5.2 Hides & skins cwt. 171 163 150 144 144 4. 7 5.8 4.4 4.0 4.2 Total major processed exports 67.1 65.2 40.7 42.8 49.4 Total exports 263.3 278.8 238.1 2o6.5 320.1 Major processed exports as % of total exports 25% 24% 17% 21% 16% Source: Federal Office of Statistics. Table 7: GROSS OUTPUT AND VALUE ADDED IN MANUFACTURING, 1967 Value added Value added Ratio of value added to gt'OS3 output Industcy Gross output including excluding Including ~xcluding "other cost" "other cost" "other cost" "other cost• -------------- £N thousand -------------- ------------ Percent ------------- Meat products ?.,oS4 571 391 28 19 Daicy products 480 206 176 43 37 Fruit canning 46 17 12 35 26 Grain mill products 6,805 1,787 1;292 26 19 Bakecy products 2,484 948 663 38 27 Sugar and spirit distillery 1, 796 979 803 54 45 Sugar confectionery 3,094 1_,056 768 34 25 Miscellaneous food preparations and tobacco 14,309 10,456 3,588 73 25 Beer 14,047 10,942 5,503 78 39 Soft drinks 1,~80 844 475 66 31 Textiles )0,241 13,678 10,085 45 33 Footwear 3,636 1,344 1,146 37 32 Wearing apparel 483 253 231 52 48 Made up textile goods 11 929 767 601 4o 31 Sawmilling 4,6)8 2,626 2,184 57 47 Furniture and fixtures 3,612 1,626 1,147 45 32 Paper produce 2,675 909 572 34 22 Printing 4,044 2,209 1,842 55 46 Tanning 2,071 36o 258 17 12 Travel goods 252 48 11 19 4 Rubber goods 6,)09 3,081 2,403 49 38 Basic industrial chemica1 and petroleum products 2,239 1,347 1,210 6o 57 Vegetable oil milling 24,194 7,225 3,681 30 15 Paints 1,337 591 405 44 3D Miscellaneous chemica1 products 12,147 5,687 3,747 47 31 Bricks and tiles 230 12;1 97 54 42 Glass products and pottery 456 48 9 11 2 Cement and concrete products 5,Bo6 3,139 2,794 54 48 Basic metals and metal products 25,599 6,o69 4,821 24 19 Machinery other than electrical 533 213 88 40 16 Electrical equipment 1,817 440 330 24 18 ~fotor vehicle assembly 799 479 9 6 Motor vehicle repairs 2~~~~~ 6,348 4,820 22 17 Miscellaneous manufactured goods 1,573 892 657 57 42 219,246 87,631 57,450 2J "Other cost" includes excise taxes, professional fees, rental payments, water charges, cost of' office materials, postage, insurance, advertising, hired transport, and miscellaneous operating costs. Source: Federal Office of Statistics, Industrial su:rvey 1967. Table 8: RATES OF PROFITS ON SALES IN NIGERIAN MANUFACTURING. 1967 AND 1963 Sales Profit Rate of Profit 1967 (£ NtOOOl ~£Nt000} on sales (%) Foodstuffs and tobacco 31 ,o68 5,462 18 Beverages 15,327 4,791 31 Textiles 30,241 6,589 22 Footwear, travel goods, wearing apparel and made up textiles 6,300 1,233 20 Saw milling 4,638 755 16 Wood products, furniture and fixtures 3,612 15 Printing and paper products 6,719 593 ') Tanning 2,077 117 6 Rubber products 6,309 1,623 26 Chemicals 14,386 3,583 25 Oil milling 24,194 3,119 13 Paints 1,337 251 19 Bricks, tiles, potter,r, glass products 686 -62 -9 Cement and concrete 5,8o6 2,095 36 Basic metals 25,599 3,129 12 Metal products 25,599 3,129 12 Electrical equipment 1,817 187 10 Motor vehicle assemb~ 8,497 -25 -.2 1963 Foodstuffs and tobacco 20,648 8,899 43 Beverages 14,036 7,625 54 Textiles 6,931 1,885 27 Foot,wear, travel goods, made up textiles 2,887 107 4 Saw milling 5,120 1,163 23 Wood products, furniture and fixtures 1, 728 184 11 Printing and paper pra.ducts 3,578 463 13 Tanning 743 165 22 Rubber products 7,621 953 13 Chemicals 6,897 1,335 19 Oil milling 14,371 1,202 8 Paints 757 202 27 Bricks, tile a, pottery, glaes products 284 105 -37 Cement and concrete 5,894 2,174 37 Basic metals 10,676 157 1 Metal products 5,815 1,025 18 Electrical equipment 248 -1 -0 Motor vehicle assemb~ 9,478 -31 -0 Sotirce: Federal Office of statistics, ~dustrial Surveys, 1967 and 1963. Table 9.: VALUE ADDED, GROSS OUTPUT, AND EMPLOYMENT IN 1968 IN FIRMS WITH TEN OR MORE -IiltfPLOlEES COMMENCING OPERATION DURING 1966 TO 1968, BY STATE Number o£ State new Value Added Gross OUtput Employment firms (£N 1 000) (tN •ooo) Lagos 44 965 8,740 5,795 Western 15 199 625 415 Benin Plateau 5 504 2,313 841 Kana 4 247 447 661 North Central 1 442 1,480 221 North Eastern 1 -15 15 56 Mid Western 2 179 298 159 Kwara North Western Total 72 2,521 13,916 8,148 1/ Eastern States excluded. Source: Federal Office of Statistics, Industrial Survel 1968. Table 10: PRIVATE FOREIGN SHARE OF PAID UP CAPITAL, 1965 AND IN FIRMS COMMENCING PRODUCTION DURING 1966 TO 1968 PriYate foreign participation rate in Paid-up capital2/ 1965 1968 Sector All firms New firms entering in 1966-1968 Food and beverages 71% 90~ Vegetable Oil milling 7.5% Textiles, footwear and apparel 65% 46% Saw milling and wood p·roducts 52% 14% Printing and paper products 32t 57% Chemical paint and plastics 69~ 84% Rubber products, tires and 'tubes 47% 83% Cement, p,ttery and gLass products 37% 84% Metal PrOducts and miscellaneous 94% 96% Total 68% 67% l/ Eastern States excluded. y All of Nigeria, necessitated l):t an inconsistency in the data on paid up capital in th.e Eastem Region • Source: Federal Office of StatisU.cs, Industrial SurveY!, 1965 and 1968. .. *.· c .,.. ! Table 11: PIONEER COMPANIES BY INDUSTRY, 1968 Estimated total Average per Industry Number or value or company Pioneer investment investment Companies (£N million) (fiN thousand) 1• Metal (based on iron and steel) 33 22.5 680 2. Textiles and textile products 21 19.0 900 3. Food processing (including animal reed) 18 5.5 310 4. Chemicals and paints 12 5.2 430 5. Rubber and rubber products (including. synthetic 9 6.6 130 rubber) 6. Phannaceuticals 1 3.5 500 1. Tin alloys and aluminium 10 2.5 250 8. Cement 1 3.1 530 9. Hotels 4 2.5 630 10. Others 27 4.0 150 Total 148 75.0 500 Source: Federal Ministry or Industry • Table ··12 : COMMODITIES SUBJECT TO EXCISE TAXATION, 1960, 1965 AND 1970 1965 1970 Cigarettes Cigarettes Cigarettes beer beer beer lemonade lemonade lemonade confectione17 matches matches soap soap confectionery confectionery biscuits apparel blankets biscuits cement blankets enamelware cement nails, barbed wire enamelware paint footware piece goods nails, barbed wire plasticware paint spirits piece goods towels plasticware travelling trunks spirits yarn towels tires travel ling tl'Wlks thread yarn metal containers tires household utensils thread tanned leather metal containers oils household utensils wine and aperitifs tanned leather LPG oils radiograms and record players wine and aperitifs tabs & raps snuff roofing sheets butter packing containers cosmetics and perfumes flour furniture records jewelry electric bulbs ballpoint pens bicycle tires socks mattresses batteries disinfectants bacon radios and television sets metal structures Source: Federal Ministry of Finance. Table 13: SELECTED EXCISE DUTIES, 1960, 1964 ~ND 1969 Colliimodities 1964 1. Cigarettes manufactured in Nigeria a) where 100 cigarettes are 30% of selling less 2 lb. weight price 30% of selling price 30% of selling price b) 1,000 between 2 and 2 1/2 48% of selling 40 or 48% of selling 40-50% of selling lb. price price price c) 1,000 exceed .2 l/2 lb. 50% of selling 50% of selling price 50% of selling price price - ::>. Cigars manufactured in 3/6d per lb. 3/6d per lb. 20% ad valorem per Nigeria 1000 cigarettes or 30-40% or 50% depend- ing on .type. 3. Tobacco .1IUUIU.f'actured in .Nigeria other than prepared in the primitive fashion for s.okfng 3/6d per lb. 3/6d per lb. 20% ad valorem 4. Beer brewed in Nigeria other than native liquor 4/- per gal. 7/6d per gal. 7/6d per gal. 5. Matches In boxes containing 80 6 /9d per gross 6 /9d per gross 3-12/- per gross matches or leas box 6. Lemonade and other aerated water l/4d per gal. l/8d per gal. 2/- per gal. 7. Confectionery 4d per lb. 2d per lb. 8. Biscuits 5% of selling price 10% 9. Blankets 50% of selling price 10% 10. Cement Not locally manufactured 15/- per cwt. i:.l per cwt. 11. Corned beef II 5% of selling price 10% 12. Enamelware II 5% II II II 10% 13. footwear (leather) II 2/- per pair 3/6d per pair (non-leather) II 6d. II II 1/6 II II 14. Piece goodsa knitted II 3d per lb. 2/6 per lb. Cotton,bleached or unbleached " 2d per sq. yd. 2d per sq. yd. Other II 6d per·st,J.. yd. ., 6d per sq. yd. 15. Plastioware II 5% of selling price 10% 16. Soap and soap products II 5% II II II 15% J ..'{. Spirits (potable) · II i:. 7 per gal. e 7.10s per gal. 1 R. Tires (pneumatic) II 10% 15% 19. Yarns and threads II 10% of selling price 15% ,20. Apparel ahirt.s II 9d each 1/-eaoh singlets II 6d. each ~each 21. Apparel socks II not produced 10% 22. Butter, margarine and. oth.Pfts II 10% of selling price 15% of selling pricE 23. Gramophone records 10 _% II 10% II " II II II II Source: Federal Ministry of Finance. Table 14: REVENUES FROM EXCISE TAXES, IMPORT DUTIES, AND EXPORT DUTIES 1965/66 TO 1970/71 (£N million) o a Federally collected Excise taxes Import duties Export duties revenues 1965/66 21.5 74.9 15.9 158 ..7 1966/67 36.0 58.5 14.0 159.6 1967/68 24.8 53.3 15.0 145.3 1968/69 28.2 58.0 14.8 145.8 1969/70]./ 38.0 69.1 19.7 187.6 1970/713./ 54.2 69.7 22.1 273.0 (% of total Federally collected revenues) 1965/66 13.5 47.1 10.0 100 1966/67 22.5 36.6 8.8 100 1967/68 17.1 36.7 10.3 100 1968/69 19.3 39.8 10.2 100 1969/70 20.3 36.8 10.5 100 1970/71 19.9 25.5 8.1 100 2/ Revised Estimates. 5/ Approved Budget Estimates. Source: Federal Ministry of Finance. Table 15: INDUSTRIES RANKED BY THE NUMBER OF PROJECTED NE}l FIRMS NIGERIA, 1970 Ranking Industq 1• Spinning, Weaving and linishing Textiles 2. Manufacture of Metal Products except Machiner.r ). Manufacture of Articles of Pulp Paper and Paper Board 4. Electrical Apparatus and Appliances 5. Miscellaneous Metal and Electrical Products 6. Cordage, Rope and Twine 7. Canning and Preserving of Fish and other Sea Foods 8. Leather Products except Footwear 9. Cocoa, Chocolate and Sugar Contectioner,y 1 o. Miscellaneous Clt.emical Products 11 • Printing and Publishing 12. Glass and Glass Products 13. Furniture and Fixtures 14. Miscellaneous Products of Petroleum 15. Footwear 16. Canning and Preserving ot Fru1ta and Vegetables 17. Grain Mill Products 18. Paints, Varnishes and Lacquers 19. Pulp and Paper 20. Rubber Products 21. Structural Clay Products NOTES: Industry Data Used in Calculating Effective Rate of Protection, etc. The input-output and the tariff data used in calculating the effective rates of protection as well as the wage costs and original book value of fixed assets required in the profitability calculations are pre- sented in this Annex. All the data relate to 1968. Tariffs of 20 percent have been used for fuel and electricity costs and 33 1/3 percent for other and unspecified costs. 3231 - Tanneries and Leather Finishing All 7 reporting firms were used in the analysis of this industry. Employment in these firms was 591. (LN'OOO) Output Excise - 58 Processed skins, raw skins 2,141 and products of hides Inputs Raw skins 1,132 Chemicals and others 235 1,367 Fuel costs 3 Electricity costs 19 Other costs 116 Total costs - excise 1,563 Wage costs 140 Book value of fixed assets 392 The export tax on processed and raw skins was 10 percent. The tariff on chemicals and other inputs (assumed) was 35 percent. The export taxes are legal rates but collected duties are the same. Actual value added was LN 578 thousand while calculated free trade value added was LN 808 thousand. 3720 - Non-ferrous Metal (tin) Only the one large scale export firm reported in this industry. Because of the confidentiality rule of the Federal Office of Statistics, the details of the cost breakdown can therefore not be presented. There was no export tax on tin ingots, a ten percent tax on tin alloy, and a 4 percent tax on the export of tin slag. - 2 - 3115 -_Vegetable and Animal Oils and Fats There were 17 firms reporting in this industry. Employment was 3,817. (I.N 1 000) Value of output 21 ,648 Excise 569 Cost of raw materials 14,337 Fuel costs 119 Electricity costs 228 Other costs ~28 Total costs incl. excise 16,1RO Wage costs 657 Book value of fixed assets 2,438 Value added was hN 5,268 thousand. The effective rate of protection and profitability calculations were based on five firms with employment of 1, 221~. (llN'OOO) Excise 570 Groundnut oil 'J '964 Groundnut cake 5,446 Ground nuts 360 Palm oil 3,619 Palm cake 912 Total 20,301 Palm kernels 3,221 Ground nuts 9,Y93 Groundnut shells 26 Containers 8 Total 13,249 Fuel costs 103 Electricity costs 209 Other costs _2,833 Total costs incl. excise 16,394 (~age costs 325 Book value of fixed assets 1,281 - 3- Taxes on the processed products were all 10 percent. Since these products are handled by marketing boards, inputs are obtained at export prices despite the 10 percent export tax on the unprocessed commodities. There was a 25 percent tariff on the imported containers. Actual value added was bN 3,907 thousand and value in world market prices was bN 4,922 thousand. 3311 - Sawmills and Other \.Jood Mills The calculations were based on one large firm producing output valued at over EN 2.2 million. By the confidentiality rule, the details on the firm cannot be given. The export tax was 10 percent on plywood, 4 percent on logs, and 2.5 percent on lumber. 3550 - Miscellaneous Rubber Products All 17 reporting firms in this industry were used in the calcula- tion of effective rates of production and profitability. Employment was 4,342. (t.N'OOO) Out nut Crepe and sheet rubber 3,460 Rubber and foam products 510 3,970 Inputs Raw rubber 1, 772 Chemicals 240 2,012 Fuel costs 74 Electricity costs 20 Other costs 751 Total costs incl. excise 2,933 Wage costs 660 Book value of fixed assets 4,436 Export taxes were 10 percent on the final products. Inputs of raw rubber are purchased at export prices. A 33 1/3 import tariff is applied on imports of chemicals. Actual value added was bN 1,037 thousand while value added at world market prices was bN 1,287 thousand. - 4 - 3131 - Distilling, Rectifying and Blending Spirits There was only one firm in this industry. Because of the con- fidentiality rule, the details of this firm cannot be given. The tariff on imported spirits was 100 percent plus 7 1/2 percent surcharge. 3529 - Miscellaneous Chemical Products Four of five reporting firms were used in the calculations. Employment was 483. (I:.N'OOO) Output Excise 344 Matches 1 ,071 Candles 300 1,371 Chemicals 16 Splints 101 Skillets 97 Paper 25 Cardboard 5 Paraffin wax 138 Wicks 10 Other 50 443 Fuel costs 14 Electricity costs 4 Other costs 95 Total costs incl. excise 900 Wage costs 99 Book value of fixed assets 261 The tariff on matches was based on actual duty collected, 55 percent. The tariff on candles was 33 1/3 percent. The tariff on chemicals, paraffin wax, and wicks was 33 1/3 percent. The tariff on splints and skillets was 10 percent. The tariff on paper and cardboard was 15 percent. Actual value added was UN 471 thousand and value added at world prices was I:.N 462 thousand. - 5 - 3522 - Drugs and Medicines Five of six reporting firms were used in the calculations. Employment in these firms was 515. (I:!N'OOO) Output Excise 29 Drugs 429 Inputs Chemicals 130 Packing material 28 158 Fuel costs Electricity costs 12 Other costs 73 Total costs incl. excise 270 Wage costs 215 Book value of fixed assets 526 The tariff on drug imports was 20 percent. Chemicals are imported freely by exemption. The tariff on packaging materials was 25 percent. Actual value added was I:.N 158 thousand, while value added at world prices was I:!N 135 thousand. 3112- Dairy Products All five reporting firms were used in the calculations. Employment was 383. (I:!N'OOO) Output Excise 6 Ice cream 230 Butter 62 Milk 200 Other 163 655 - 6 - Inputs Milk powder 154 Containers 107 Sugar 6 Butter 35 Other 105 407 Fuel costs 20 Electricity costs 23 Other costs 47 Total costs incl. excise 504 Wages 88 Book value of fixed assets 587 The tariff on butter imports was 72 percent and on milk 70 percent. Actual duty collection on milk powder was 4 percent, on sugar 70 percent, and on containers and wrapping the tariff was 25 percent. Actual value added was bN 151 thousand and value added at world market prices was LN 124 thousand. 3133 - Beer and Stout All four reporting firms were used in the calculations. Employ- ment was 1 , 884. (hN'OOO) Output Excise 4,800 Beer 11,362 Stout 5,364 Soft drinks 360 17,086 Inputs Bottles 1,381 Malt 912 Hops 155 Sugar 103 Packaging 178 Other 224 2,955 - 7- Fuel costs 375 Electricity costs 98 Other costs 3,057 Total costs incl. excise 11,285. Wages 10,088 Book value of fixed assets 8,372 Price comparisons yield a tariff equivalent of 75 percent for beer. Actual tariff collections on soft drinks were 82 percent. Bottles are imported free by exemption. Tariff on malt and hops was 33 1/3 per- cent. Collected duty was 70 percent on sugar. Concentrates are imported duty free by exemption while a 25 percent tariff is applied to packaging materials. Actual value added was aN 5,801 thousand whil~ value added at world prices was ~N 4,555 thousand. The excise tax estimated is based on revenue collected from the beer industry. 3140 - Tobacco Products Only two firms in this industry reported and only one was used in the calculations. Because of the confidentiality rule, the details cannot be given. A price comparison was used for cigarettes indicating a 133 percent difference between domestic price and CIF price. 3412 - Paper Containers, Boxes and Paper Boards All six firms reporting in this industry, were used in the calculations. Employment was 702. (aN'OOO) Output Excise 54 Cement bags 435 Cardboard and paper board 840 Labels, cigarette slides 307 Paper bags 33 Cartons 381 Wax paper 61 2,057 Inputs Kraft papers 792 Papers 270 Glue 41 Ink 85 Other 134 1, 323 - 8 - Fuel costs 5 Electricity costs 17 Other costs 229 Total costs incl. excise 1 ~628 Wage costs 233 Book value of fixed assets 1 ~ 117 The tariff on final products of this industry was 25 percent. The tariff on kraft papers was 10 percent. Actual tariff collection on papers was 19 perc~nt and on ink 12 percent. The duty on glue was 33 1/3 percent. Value added was bN 430 thousand while vulue added at world prices was bN 327 thousand. All six firms reporting were used in the calculations. Employ- ment was 394. (bN'OOO) Excise 54 Paints 1 ~563 Inputs Pigments, solvents~ resins, and chemicals 706 Packing materials 141 847 Fuel costs 0.6 Electricity costs 10 Other costs 255 Total costs incl. excise 1,166 Wages 178 Book value of fixed assets 589 The tariff on final products was 40 percent and on the inputs 33 1/3 percent. Value added was bN 397 thousand while at world market prices it was bN 283 thousand. - 9 - 3233 - Travel Goods All four firms reporting were used in the calculation. Employ- ment was 448. (I:IN'OOO) Output Excise 41 Suitcases and bags 405 Input P.V.C. sheets 55 Fiber boards 70 Metal fittings 140 Skins 4 Other 6 275 Fuel costs 0.03 Electricity costs 2 Other costs 42 Total costs incl. excise 360 Wages 80 Book value of fixed assets 125 The tariff on travel goods was 40 percent. The tariff on P.V.C. sheets was 33 1/3 percent, on fiber boards 15 percent, on metal fittings 33 1/3 percent. Skins are purchased at 10 percent below export prices because of the export duty. Actual value added was I:JN 45 thousand, value added at world market prices was I:JN 25 thousand. 3699 - Non-metallic Mineral Products All six firms reporting were used in the calculations. Employment was 838. (I:IN'OOO) Output Excise: nil 'l i Concrete products 1,512 - 10 - Inputs Wire and iron reinforcement 30 Cement 270 Gravel 21 Asbestos 253 Other 92 667 Fuel costs 1 Electricity costs 22 Other costs 145 Total costs incl. excise 835 Wages 238 Book value of fixed assets 1,336 The tariff on concrete products was 33 1/3 percent. The tariffs on wire reinforcement, asbestos and gravel were 10 percent. The tariff on cement was 40 percent. Actual value added was bN 677 thousand and value added in world market prices was ~N 452 thousand. 3692 - Cement There were three firms reporting in this industry all of which were used in the calculations. Employment was 1,290. (~N'OOO) Output Excise 524 Cement 5,598 Inputs Limestone and clinker 920 Gypsum 230 Cement bags 381 Other 53 1,584 Fuel costs 406 Electricity costs 451 Other costs 468 Total costs incl. excise 3,433 Wage costs 553 Book value of fixed assets 10,626 - 11- The tariff on cement was 40 percent, on clinker 20 percent, on gypsum 10 percent, and duty collected on bags was 16 percent. Actual value added was LN 2,165 thousand and value added at world prices was LN 1,378 thousand. 3813 - Structural Metal Products There were 21 firms reporting of which 18 were used in the analysis. Employment in these was 1,603. (I:!N'OOO) Output Excise: nil Trailer and trucks 801 Tanks and trailers 421 Structural steel 635 Doors and windows 706 Furniture 12 Steel structures 325 Other 389 3,289 Input Metals (iron and steel) 1 ,331 Pipes, tubes and beAms 153 Paints and chemicals 7 Miscellaneous parts 90 Other 639 2,221 Fuel costs 4 Electricity costs '32 Other coats 210 Total costs incl. excise 2,467 Wage costs 485 Book value of fixed assets 1 , 127 The tariff on all final products was 33 1/3 percent except for metal furniture where it was 75 percent. The tariff on all inputs was 33 1/3 percent except for metal where it was 28 percent. Actual value added was eN 822 thousand while value added at world prices was eN 490 thousand. - 12 - 3691 - Structural Cl~y Products All seven reporting firms, with employment of 279, were used in the calculations. (I!N'OOO) Output Excise: nil Tiles, blocks and plpes 330 Inpu~~ Colored cement 23 Cement 36 Marble chip 9 Sand 8 Other 3 79 Fuel costs 12 Electricity costs 2 Other costs 37 Total costs incl. excise 130 Wage costs 60 Book value of fixed assets 335 The tariff on final products was 50 percent. The tariffs on colored cement were 33 1/3, on cement 40 percent, on marble chip and' sand 10 percent. Actual value added was LN 200 thousand and value added at world prices was ~N 120 thousand. 3134 - Soft Drinks All six reporting firms, with employment of 865, were used in the calculations. (LN'OOO) Outputs Excise 368 Soft drinks 1,770 - 13 - Inputs Concentrates 193 Sugar 139 Cork 39 Carbon dioxide 24 Caustic soda 16 Bottles 8 Other 4 423 Fuel costs 22 Electricity costs 20 Other costs 297 Total costs incl. excise 1 t 130 Wage costs 157 Book value of fixed assets 1,837 The tariff equivalent on the final product was derived from an actual tariff collected ratio of 82 percent. Bottles and concentrates are imported free by exemption. The tariff on sugar was 70 percent, on cork and carbon dioxide 33 1/3 percent, and on caustic soda actual duty collected was 126 percent. Actual value added was bN 640 thousand and value added at world prices was bN 378 thousand. 3523 - Soap, Perfumes and Cosmetics There were twelve firms reporting with an employment of 2,866. (bN'OOO) Output 11,387 Excise 651 Inputs 6,296 Fuel costs 48 Electricity costs 63 Other costs 1,175 Total costs incl. excise 8,234 Wage costs 1,327 Book value of fixed assets 655 The calculations were based on two firms accounting for about 80 percent of output. Due to the confidentiality rule, the detailed breakdown is not presented. - 14 - 3540 - Miscellaneous Products of Petroleum and Coal All 4 firms, with employmeut of 740, were used in the calculations. (I:!N'OOO) Outpu~~ Excise 155 Asphalt !14 Lubricants 1,660 Bitumens and chemi.cal products ?.L.~.~~ 3,!19 7 Inputs Granite stone, dust and cement t.2 Base oils 618 Chemicals & bituminous materials !,057. 1 , 7 17 Fuel costs 15 Electricity costs 41 Other costs 120 Total costs incl. excise 2,048 Wage costs 699 Book value of fixed assets 1,213 Tariffs on all the outputs were 33 1/3 percent. Tariffs on granite stone, dust and cement were 33 1/2 percent while base oils and chemicals entered duty free. Actual value added was ~N 1,849 thousand while value added at world prices was ~N 1,045 thousand. 3240 - Footwear except moulded rubber or plastic ware All 8 reporting firms, with employment of 1,434 were used in the study. (I:!N'OOO) Output Excise: nil - 15 - Shoes Inputs Leather 913 P.v.c. 600 Rubber 542 Chemicals 20 Packing materials 42 Other 300 2.479 Fuel costs 1 Electricity costs 49 Other costs 300 Total costs incl. excise 2,830 Wage costs 308 Book value of fixed assets 1,582 The tariff on shoes was 40 percent. The tariff on leather was 66 2/3 percent, on P.V.C. and chemicals 33 1/3 percent and on rubber minus 10 percent due to export taxation. Actual value added was ~N 645 thousand and value added at world prices was hN 364 thousand. 3117- Bakery Products The calculations were based on 5 of the 33 reporting firms. These five firms employed 775. (~N'OOO) Output Excise 80 Bread and biscuits 1,166 Inputs Flour 335 Sugar 44 Fats 8 Packaging 100 Other 139 626 - 16 - Fuel costs 20 Electricity costa 19 Other costs 67 Total costs incl. excise 812 Wage costs 126 Book value of fixed assets 983 1be tariff on the final product was 50 percent (40 percent for bread and l5 percent for biscuHs), on flour 15 percent equivalent based on duty collected, on sugar 40 percent, on fat~:> 33 1/3 pt!rcent, and on packaging 25 percent. Actual value added was +sN J54 thousand while value added at domestic prices was ~~ 184 thoudand. All three firms ceporting, with employment of 211, were used. (I,N'OOO) Excise: nil Batteries 207 Bulbs 49 256 Inputs Lead 45 Acids and chemicals 0.6 Battery components 48 Other 18 ill Fuel costs 2 Electricity costs 8 Other costs 15 Total costs incl. excise 137 Wage costs 34 Book value of fixed assets 79 The tariff on batteries was 50 percent and that on bulbs 33 1/3 percent. The tariff on all imports was 33 1/3 percent except for lead which entered free. Actual value added was ~N 118 thousand while value added at world prices was ~N 60 thousand. - 17 - 3811 -Cutlery, Handtools and Hardware Three of five reporting firms, with employment of 101, were used in the calculations. (:hN'OOO) Output Excise: nil Springs 90 Cutlery 39 Locks 159 288 Inputs Component parts for locks 128 Aluminum 25 Wire coils 54 Packing materials 2 207 Fuel costs 3 Electricity costs 2 Other costs 32 Total costs incl. excise 245 Wage costs 30 Book value of fixed assets 58 The tariffs on cutlery and locks were 50 per..::ent ~11d on ~pr.ings 40 percent. The tariff on lock components was 50 per~ent, on alumlnurn 20 percent, on wire coils 33 1/3 percent, and on packaging 25 percent. Actual value added was :hN 43 thousand while value added in world prices was &N 21 thousand. 3212 - Made Up Textiles Except Wearing Apparel All 7 reporting firms, with employment of 2008, were used in the calculations. (I!N'OOO) Outputs Excise 2n5 Tents and tarpaulins 370 Blankets 1, %R Towels 458 Other 102 2,298 - 18 - Inputs Canvas 235 Cottou yam 967 Dyestuffs and chemicals 17 Packaging material 6 Other 61 1,286 Fuel costs 3 Electricity costs 30 Other costs 158 Total costs :t.ncl. exctse 1,682 Wage costs 262 Book value of ftxed assets 906 The tariff on tents was 40 percent, on blankets and.other made up goods 50 percent. and observed tariff rate on towels was 108 percent. The tariff rates on canvas, cotton yarn, and packaging were 25 percent and on dyes 10 percent. Actual value added was LN 616 thousand while value 'added at world prices was J:,N 293 thousand. 3211 - Textiles Spinnin&, Weaving 1 Printing Titere were 41 firms reporting from this industry with total employment of 19,074. (&N'OOO) Output 38,200 Excise 4,583 Inputs 18,805 Fuel costs 787 Electricity costs 1,066 Other costs 799 Total costs incl. excise 26,040 Wage costs 3,871 Book value of fixed assets 21,361 The calculation of the effective rate of protection was based on 4 firms employing 5,005. The detailed breakdown for the four firms is as follows. - 19 - {I::.N'OOO) Outputs Excise 2,643 Grey baft 4,021 Prints and piece goods 14' 135 18,156 Inputs Cotton I, 327 Grey haft 6,826 Chemicals and dyes 825 Packaging 884 9,862 Fuel costs 238 Electricity costs 370 Other costs 889 Total costs incl. excise 14,002 Wage costs 1,156 Book value of fixed assets 4,291 Based on price comparisons, the tariff equivalent on final output of every baft is 60 percent hut the tariff levied on imports by a manufacturer was 48 percent. The observed tariff on printR was 75 percent. Chemicals were imported free by exemption while a tariff of 10 percPnt on dyes was in effect. Actual value added was I::.N 4,154 thousand whlle value added at world prices was I::.N 1,883 thousand. 3118 - Sugar Refinery Only 2 firms reported in this industry and only I was used. By the confidentiality rule, the details cannot he g:fven. The observed tariff on refined sugar was 83 percent while the tariff on raw Rugar was 40 percent. 3113- Canning and Preserving of Fruit and V~etahles All 3 reporting firms, with employment of 195, were used in the calculations. (I::.N'OOO) Outputs Excise 2 Fruit squash lR Citrus fruits 45 Fruit juices ... I 70 - 20 - Inputs Citrus fruits 7 Bottles 4 Sugar 2 Saccharin 0.5 Corks 0.2 Others 4.8 fa·- Fuel costs Electric!ty costa Other costs Total costs :incl. ~xcisP Wage costs 19 Book value of fixed assets 346 Tariffs on squash and fruit were 75 percent and on juices 66 2/3 percent. Tariffs on saccharin and corks were 33 1/3 percent, on sugar 70 percent, and bottles and fruits could be purchased at world prict!s. Actual value added was !:.N 39 thousand and value added at world prices bN 16 thousand. 3560 - Miscellaneous Plastic Products --------·-------- There were 41 firms reporting of whi~h 3, with employment of 638, were used in the calculations. {hN '000) Excise 17 Plastic footwear 415 Plastic bags 370 Plastic buckets 247 Other 24 1,056 Inputs Not specified 38 P.V.C. 109 Alkathene 28 Pigments 11 Polystyrene 99 Packaging 71 356 - 21 - Fuel costs 10 Electricity costs 30 Other costs 64 Total costs incl. excise 477 Wage costs 118 Book value of fixed assets 685 The tariff on plastic shoes was 86 percent, on bags and buckets 75 percent. The tariff on all the inputs was 33 1/3 percent. Actual value added was hN 580 thousand while value added at world prices was LN 241 thousand. 3891 - Fabricated Metal Products There were 16 firms reporting with employment of 4,835. (LN'OOO) Outputs 11,857 Excise 1 ,065 Inputs 6,035 Fuel costs 133 Electricity costs 121 Other costs ~ Total costs incl. excise 8,564 Wage costs 1,281 Book value of fixed assets 4,150 Of these, 7 firms with an employment of 2,89R wf:'re uned in the calc•J:ations on effective protection and profitability. (hN'OOO) Outputs Exc:i.se 947 Tins and drums 2,590 Steel rods. fencing. nails. wire 1,664 Enamelware 2,531 Galvanized sheets 2...1659 9,443 - 22 - Inputs Tinplate 930 Steel plates and sheets 3,765 Zinc and enamel 367 Other 183 5,245 Fuel costs 88 Electricity costs 76 Other costs 737 Total costs incl. excise 7,093 Wage costs 888 Book value of fixed assets 3,091 The tariffs on all outputs were 33 1/3 percent except for enamel, where the tariff was 75 percent. All inputs entered freely by exemption except for enamel where there was a tariff of 10 percent. Actual value added was bN 2,351 thousand and valu~ added at world prices was LN 966 thousand. 3111 - Slaughtering, Prepa,!ing and Preserving Meat The return of a firm accounting for more than a third of industry output was used in the calculations. Due to the confidentiality rule, the details cannot be given. Tariff on the meat product outputs was 50 percent. 3116 - Grain Mill Products There were 3 firms reporting of which 1 firm employing 638 was used for the calculations. Due to the confidentiality rule, the details cannot he given. The tariff on the major output of the firm, wheat flour, was 50 percent. 3121 - Miscellaneous Food Products There were 4 firms reporting with employment of 600. (LN'OOO) Output 1,245 Excise: nil Inputs 784 Fuel costs 0.1 Electricity costs 7 Other costs 417 Total costs incl. excise 1,208 - 23 - Wage costs 108 Book value of fixed assets 234 Only 1 of these firms was used for the calculations and by the confidentiality rule the details cannot be given. The tariffs on the major products, tea and coffee, were 71 percent. 3843 - Motor Vehicle Assembly There were 6 firms reporting of which 4, with employment of 1,405, were used in the calculations. (LN'OOO) OUtputs Excise: nil Assembled vehicles (lorries, buses, trailers) 8,162 Inputs Vehicles unassembled 6,653 Paints 220 Other 157 7,030 Fuel costs 4 Electricity costs 25 Other costs 446 Total costs incl. excise 7,505 Wage costs 469 Book value of fixed assets 1,322 The tariff on assembled vehicles was 33 1/3 percent and on unassembled vehicles 28 1/2 percent. The tariff on paints was 33 1/3 percent. Actual value added was LN 657 thousand while value added at world prices was LN 215 thousand. 3812 - Metal Furniture and Fixtures There were 10 firms reporting with employment of 1,458. - 24 - (LN'OOO) Output 2,654 Excise 191 Inputs 1,352 Fuel costs 9 Electricity costs 12 Other costs 935 Total costs incl. excise 2,494 Wage costs 227 Book value of fixed assets 1,605 The calculations were based on 2 firms, so by the confidentiality rule the details cannot be given. The tariff on metal furniture was 66 2/3 percent. 3320 - Furniture and Fixtures Except Pri.marily of Metal There were 31 firms repor~ing of which 3 firms, employing 743, were used in the calculations. (J:,N'OOO) Output Excise 16 Furniture 515 Inputs Timber 35 Plywood 89 Upholstery material 65 Formica 20 Paints and adhesives 25 Other 31 J 267 Fuel costs Electricity costs 7 Other costs 49 Total costs incl. excise 340 Wage costs 117 Book value of fixed assets 265 \ \ - 25 - The tariff on furniture was 75 percent. Lumber was purchased at prices 3 percent below world prices because of an export duty. The tariff on plywood was 30 percent, on upholstery 40 percent, and on formica 33 1/3 percent. Actual value added was bN 176 thousand while value added at world market prices was LN 45 thousand. 3610 - Pottery, China and Earthenware Only 2 firms reported in this industry so by the confidentiality rule, the details cannot be given. The observed tariff on the final product was 68 percent while all important inputs were subject to a tariff of 33 1/3 percent. 3220 - Wearing APparel Except Footwear There were 12 reporting firms producing many different items. Only 1 firm, producing singlets, was used for the calculations. Due to the confidentiality rule, the details for the firm cannot be given. The tariff on singlets was 116 percent. 3620 - Glass and Glass Products There were 5 firma reporting of which 2 were used in the calculations. Due to the confidentiality rule, the details cannot be given. The 2 firms used produced mirrors. The tariff on the final products was SO percent. 3832 - Radio, T.V. and Communications Equipment Assembly There were 7 reporting firms of which 5, employing 480, were used in the study. (I:!N'OOO) Output Excise 47 Radio and radiograms 1. 141 Record players 95 Television 80 Records 256 Lamps 81 Other 17 ""1;6 71 - 26 - Inputs P.V.C. and material for records 65 Components for radios, phonographs and T.V. 1,190 Packing materials 11 Other 5 1,272 Fuel costs 14 Electricity costs 7 Other costs 151 Total costs incl. excise 1 ,491 Wage costs 123 Book value of fixed assets 344 The following tariffs were applied to final products; 100 percent to radios, record players, and televisions; 66 2/3 percent to recorda; and 50 percent to lamps. All inputs had a tariff of 33 l/3 percent ex~ept packaging materials for which the tariff was 25 percent. Actual value added was iaN 180 thousand while value added at world market prices was minus LN 180 thousand.