, ZAA       -M . .                       .
f    10'                  '}  '                                      4'6'[ 'i~'   ' / < |       ' ''-9 %     <   '
AA'S
.<  -    .~f         t     ipJ         .         -.o - L.






WORLD BANK LATIN AMERICAN
AND CARIBBEAN STUDIES
Viewpoints
SECURING OUR
FUTURE IN
A GLOBAL
ECONOMY
by
David de Ferranti
Guillermo E. Perry
Indermit S. Gill
Luis Serven
with
Francisco H. G. Ferreira
Nadeem Ilahi
William F Maloney
Martin Rama
THE WORLD BANK
WASHINGTON, D.C.



Copyright � 2000
The International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development/THE WORLD BANK
1818 H Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A.
All rights reserved
Manufactured in the United States of America
First printing June 2000
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author(s) and should not be attrituted in
any manner to the World Bank, to its affiliated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they repre-
sent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility whatsoever for
any consequence of their use. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this volume do nct imply
on the part of the World Bank Group any judgment on the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such bo.sndaries.
The material in this publication is copyrighted. Requests for permission to reproduce portions of it should be sent to the Office of the
Publisher at the address shown in the copyright notice above. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally give
permission promptly and, when the reproduction is for noncommercial purposes, without asking a fee. Permission to copy porrions for class-
room use is granted through the Copyrighr Clearance Center, Inc., Suite 910, 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, Massachusetts 01923, U.S.A.
David de Ferranti is vice president and Guillermo E. Perry is chief economist in the World Bank's Latin America and the Caribbean
Regional Office. Indermit S. Gill is lead economist and Luis Serven is lead specialist in the World Bank's Latin America and the Caribbean
Regional Office. Francisco Ferreira is professor of economics at the Pontifical Catholic University-Rio de Janeiro, Brazil. Nadeem Ilahi is an econo-
mist with the International Monetary Fund. William E Maloney is senior economist in the World Bank's Latin America and the Caribbean
Regional Office, and Martin Rama is senior economist in the World Bank's Development Research Group.
Cover design by Janelle Welch/The Magazine Group
Cover photography: Globe: NASA Goddard Space Flight Center; inset photos, clockwise from top: Catherine de Torquat/Sygma; Bill
Pogue/Stone; Robert Frerck/Stone; Margo Pinkerton/Liaison Agency.
de Ferranti, David.
Securing our future in a global economy
Guillermo E. Perry.
p. cm. - (World Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies.
Includes bibliographical references.
ISBN 0-8213-4730-6
Library of Congress pending



Contents
Acknowledgments ..................................................................                                                                      ix
Acronyms and Abbreviations ................................................................. xi
Chapter 1: Opportunity and Risk in a Globalized Latin America and the Caribbean ............................ 1
Latin America and the Caribbean's Performance Improved in the 1990s                                    ..................................... I
Opportunities and Risks ...................................................................... 1
Why Economic Insecurity? .                   ..................................................................... 3
This Report ......................................................................... .... 6
LAC's Volatility is High-But has not Risen in the 1990s                                                   ..                                     6
Dealing with Economic Insecurity Requires a Comprehensive Insurance Approach  ...........................                 .                      7
LAC's Volatility Arises from Multiple Sources-Domestic and Foreign                                               ..                              7
Governments Can Do Much to Reduce Volatility-Even in a Globalized Economy ..........................                      .                      7
External Risks Can Be Reduced by Diversification and Liquidity Management .. .................                                                   8
Anticyclical Macroeconomic Policies Ease Adjustment to Shocks ....... ...............                                                            8
Deeper and Stronger Financial Systems Are a Key Part of Social Protection Policies                                       ..                       8
Deep Crises are Particularly Damaging for the Poor                                                    ..                                         8
The Poor Try to Protect Their Long-Term Welfare in Crises-As Long as Their Assets Permit                                        .       .         9
New  Income Support Programs for the Unemployed Need to be Established .                              ...............................            9
Administrative Capacity and Labor Policies are Key in the Choice of Instruments ..................                                               9
Self-Insurance for Slow-Reforming Economies                    .....................................................  10
Unemployment Insurance for Advanced Reforming Economies                                                     ..                                  10
Public Works Programs Provide Insurance Support for Informal Sector Workers                                           ..                        10
Targeted Programs for the Poor Need to be Better Protected in Downturns                                            ..                           10
Save in Good Times to Finance Social Spending in Bad Times ..................                                   ....................... 10
Supranational Action and the Role of the International Financial Institutions ...........                       ..11................. 1
Myths and Realities About Economic Volatility                               ..1............................ 11
Securing Our Future ................................................................. 11
Notes              ..                      ...............................................................  11
Chapter 2: Economic Insecurity in Latin America and the Caribbean: The Stylized Facts ....................... 13
Methodological Considerations . ................................................................ 13
Aggregate Volatility in Latin America ............................................................. 15
Volatility in Aggregate Output ................................................................ 15
Volatility in Aggregate Consumption .                  .......................................................... 15
Differences in Volatility Across Countries Within the Region ............................................ 16
Regional Trends in Economic Volatility  .                  ........................................................ 18
Transmission of Aggregate Volatility to the Labor Market ............................................... 21
Are Latin American Workers Facing More Risk? ..................................................... 23
Changes in Earnings Volatility .           ............................................................... 23
Trends in Unemployment Rates .                .............................................................. 24
Changes in Turnover Rates ................................................................... 26
Rise in Informality .....................................................................                                                       27
iii



SECURING OUR FUTIURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
The Deterioration  in  Prospects of Older Workers ................................................... 31
Changes in  Income Distribution  .........                                        ....................................................  32
C onclusion               . . . . . . .. . . . . . .. . .. . . .. . .. . .. . . .. . .. . . . . . .. . . . . . .. . .. . . . . . .. . .. . . .. . .. . .. . . .. .  32
N otes   . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   35
Chapter 3: Designing Social Policy When People Face Risk: A Conceptual Framework ......................... 37
The Need for Sound Analysis .                            .................................................................. 37
Approach and Implications .                         .................................................................... 38
Advantages of a Disciplined  Approach ............................................................. 39
Clearer Rationale  for Government Action  ........................................  ............... 42
Useful Insights   .           ......................................................................... 42
A Powerful Tool for Organization .                              .............................................................. 43
C onclusion    . . .. . . .. . .. . . . . . .. . . . . . .. . .. . . . . . .. . .. . . .. . .. . . .. . .. . . . . . .. . .. . . . . . . .. .. . . . . .                                  43
N otes                  . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .  4 4
Chapter 4: Macroeconomic Volatility in Latin America and the Caribbean: Causes and Remedies ................ 45
Sources of Aggregate Volatility  in  LAC  ............................................................ 45
External Shocks ...........................................................................   45
Macroeconomic Policy Volatility ............................................................... 49
Absorption  and  Amplification  of Shocks: The Importance  of Financial Markets  ............................... 50
Weak  Links with  World  Financial Markets  .......................................................  52
Shallow   Domestic Financial Markets ...............                                               ............................................ 53
The Combination  Increases the Likelihood  of Economic  Crises ......................................... 54
Other Amplification Mechanisms .                                .............................................................. 57
Summary .............................................................................     61
Policies to  Deal with  Aggregate  Volatility  in  LAC  .                                            ................................................ 61
Terms of Trade Risk ........................                                          ............................................... 65
Capital Flows ............................................................................. 66
The Financial System   ....6.................................................................  67
Fiscal Policy ........................................................................... . 67
Monetary  and  Exchange  Rate  Policy  .......                                       .................................................... 67
Supranational Action  .                  ......................................................................  68
A n n ex       I   . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .              68
N otes   . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                 70
Chapter 5: The Response of LAC Households to Economic Shocks ...................................... 73
The  Risk  of Unemployment: Who  is Most Affected?  ..................................................  73
Are the Poor Most Likely  to  Become Unemployed? .................................................  73
Are Older, Less-Educated  Men  More Likely  to  Become Unemployed? .................................... 73
Is There  No  Unemployment in  the  Informal Sector?  ................................................ 74
Who  Becomes Unemployed  and  for How  Long?  ................................................... 76
Household  Responses to  Income  Shocks: Findings of Panel Studies ........................................ 76
Do  Aggregate Shocks Hurt the  Poor More than  the  Rich? ............................................ 78
Does Ownership of Assets Reduce Vulnerability to Aggregate Shocks? ............ ...................... 79
Do  the Poor Engage  in Self-Destructive or Myopic Coping? ...........                                                     ................................  81
Are All Downturns the Same in their Effects? ...................................................... 83
Conclusion ..........................................................                                                                                                                     85
Notes ..........................................................                                                                                                                          86
Chapter 6: Helping Workers Deal with the Risk of Unemployment ....................................... 89
A Typology of Programs .                           .......................................................... 90
Main Findings ...................................................... . .. 92
Who Is Covered by these Programs? .......................................................... 95
How Much Do the Programs Cost? ......................   96
What Are the Efficiency Effects and Insurance Benefits? ...........................................  .. 97
What Are the Main Weaknesses of these Programs? ................................................. 98
Policy Implications ........................................................... 98
Self-Protection: The State of Labor Markets  .........................................................   99
Self-Insurance: Individual Savings Accounts ......................................................... 99
lv



CONTENTS
"Market-Type" Insurance: Risk-Pooling Programs ................................................... 101
Severance Pay Provisions as Insurance for Unemployment ............................................ 102
Public Works Programs as Insurance for Unemployment ............................................ 102
"Conventional" Unemployment Insurance ....................................................... 103
C onclusion  .........................................................................                                         107
Notes       ......................................................................... 108
Chapter 7: Helping Poor Households Deal Better with Economic Crises .................................. 111
Social Spending Over Economic Cycles .             .......................................................... 113
How Do Governments Vary Spending Over the Economic Cycle? ...................................... 113
The Importance of Political Factors .         ........................................................... 114
The Quality of Social Services Over the Cycle .................................................... 116
Targeted Spending During Booms and Busts ...........                   .....................................  ...... 119
Designing Economic Policy Under Political Constraints ........................................ ...... 121
The Long-Term Goal of Social Policy Must be to Improve the Distribution of Assets ........................ 122
Targeted Programs Should be Permanent and Better Protected During Crises ............................ 122
Keeping Increases in Social Spending Moderate in Good Times is Important Too ........................... 122
International Financial Institutions Can Help Overcome Political Constraints to Insurance ................... 122
Conclusion .......................................................................... 123
Notes ..................................................................... 125
Bibliography .....                                                                                                                127
Boxes
Box 2.1  Defining and Measuring Insecurity .14
Box 2.2       Trends in Aggregate Volatility in Latin America and the Caribbean .20
Box 2.3    Why Might Workers Prefer to be Precarious or Unprotected? .31
Box 2.4  Income Mobility and Risk in Two Countries .34
Box 3.1       Market Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Protection: Distinguishing Features and Examples .39
Box 3.2  A Theory of Comprehensive Insurance .40
Box 3.3  The Framework in "Real Life" Situations .41
Box 4.1   Excess Sensitivity to Disturbances: The Case of Chile .52
Box 4.2   Weak Financial Markets and Volatility: A Framework .59
Box 4.3       The Welfare Cost of Volatility and the Gains from International Risk-Sharing .62
Box 5.1       Informal Self-Employment: Precarious Workers or Voluntary Entrepreneurs? .75
Box 5.2  Data Sets and Methodologies Used .77
Box 5.3  Where Does Time Go During a Crisis? .83
Box 5.4    Do Families Mortgage Their Children's Future' Other Evidence .86
Box 6.1   Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Main Features .91
Box 6.2  Data Sources and Methodology .94
Box 6.3   Labor Markets: Latin America's "Forgotten Reform .100
Box 6.4       Combining Mandated Self-Insurance and Market-Type Unemployment Insurance .102
Box 6.5   Who Really Pays for Unemployment Insurance? .105
Box 6.6   Some Guidelines for Countries that Have Unemployment Systems .107
Box 7.1    How Do Pro-Poor Governments Vary Spending Over the Economic Cycle? .114
Box 7.2       Data Sources and Classification into Targeted and Social Spending .115
Box 7.3       Social Spending Over Economic and Political Cycles in Latin America .116
Box 7.4       Colombia's Healthcare Reform                                             .                                       118
Box 7.5       Mexico's Progresa Program: Works Well, But Would it Do as Well in Crises? .120
Box 7.6       Social Programs, Entitlements, and Countercyclicality in the U.S .124
Tables
Table 1.1  Per Capita GDP Growth in Latin America (Percent).                                                                      2
Table 1.2      Per Capita Private Consumption Growth in Latin America (Percent).                                                  3
Table 1.3     Survey Responses in Latin American Countries on Expected Changes in Living Standards
(Percentages Unless Otherwise Noted).                                                                            4
Table 1.4     Survey Responses to Social Insurance-Related Questions in 14 Latin American Countries,
by Socioeconomic Category (Percentages Unless Otherwise Noted) .............................. 4
Table 1.5  Economic Insecurity: Twelve Myths . ............................................ 12
v



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Table 2.1    Long-Term Volatility in Latin America (Standard Deviations of Growth Rates, Percent) .....        ......... 16
Table 2.2    Volatility in Latin America Over Time (Standard Deviations of Growth Rates by Decade, Percent) ....... 21
Table 2.3    Real Wage Grown Volatility in Latin America and the Caribbean, Percent ........................ 24
Table 2.4    Average Unemployment Rates in Latin America and the Caribbean, Percent ....................... 25
Table 2.5    Labor Turnover, LAC and OECD Countries ..................     I            ........................... 28
Table 2.6  Income Inequality Measures by Country, 1986-96                                ..                           33
Table 3.1    Government Policies and Their Effect on Individual Comprehensive Insurance ........           ............. 44
Table 4.1    Volatility in Terms of Trade Shocks for Selected Latin American Countries ........ ..        .............. 47
Table 4.2    Estimated Welfare Gains from Diversification (Latin America and the Caribbean,
Percent of Private Annual Consumption) ................................................ 63
Table 4.3    International Portfolio Diversification (Ratios to Total Wealth) ................................. 64
Table 4.4    An Overview of Policies to Deal with Aggregate Volatility .............     ..       .................... 65
Table 4.A. 1  Empirical Determinants of GDP Growth Volatility (Dependent Variable: Standard
Deviation of GDP Growth, 1975-99) .......................................... ....... 69
Table 5.1    Unemployment Rates by Household Income and Consumption Quintile ......................... 74
Table 5.2    Unemployment Rates by Age, Education, and Gender ....................................... 74
Table 5.3    Annual Probability of Becoming Unemployed from Formal and Informal Work (Percent) ....            ......... 75
Table 5.4    Income Variance of Formal Salaried vs. Self-Employed Workers (Theil Index) ...................... 76
Table 5.5    Unemployment Duration, in Years ......... ...............               .........................  ... 76
Table 5.6    Metropolitan Brazil: Percentage Income Changes by Head's Wage Bracket ........ ..          .......... ... 79
Table 5.7    Mexico: Proportional Income Change by Income Quintile, 1995-96 ............................. 80
Table 5.8    Rural El Salvador: A Dynamic Decomposition of Poverty Changes, 1995-97 ....... ..            ............. 80
Table 6.1    How Various Income Support Programs for the Unemployed Work ..........          ..       ................. 92
Table 6.2    Contrasting the Brazilian and U.S. Unemployment Insurance Systems ........................... 93
Table 6.3    Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Beneficiaries Across Population Groups ....          .......... 95
'rable 6.4    Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Costs per Beneficiary                   ..                   97
Table 6.5    Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Effects on Employment, Earnings, and Consumption .... 98
Table 6.6    Costs of Unemployment Insurance: Burden-Sharing Among Workers, Employers, and Government ..... 104
Table 6.7    Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Summary of Findings and Policy Implications .... .... 106
Table 7.1    Targeted Public Spending per Poor Person in Argentina and Mexico, 1994-96 .................... 113
Table 7.2    Elasticities of Spending to Growth, by Type of Spending .................................... 116
Table 7.3    Changes in Latin American Social Protection Spending, 1970-95 (Broad Spending Categories) .... .... 117
Table 7.4    Main Characteristics of Targeted Conditional Transfers ...................................... 119
Figures
Figure 1.1  Per Capita GDP Growth (Regional Medians)                                   ..                              2
Figure 1.2   Per Capita Private Consumption Growth (Regional Medians)                          ..                      3
Figure 2.1   Long-Term Volatility of Real GDP Growth         .......................         ....................... 15
Figure 2.2   Long-Term Volatility of Real Private Consumption Growth ...... ............. .                           15
Figure 2.3   GDP Growth Volatility and Country Size         ......................       .......................... 17
Figure 2.4   GDP Growth Volatility and Per Capita Income ....................               ........................ 17
Figure 2.5   GDP Growth Volatility and Private Consumption Growth Volatility           ..18............... I
Figure 2.6   Volatility of Real GDP Growth by Decade (Regional Medians) ............        ..       .................. 19
Figure 2.7   Volatility of Real Private Consumption Growth by Decade (Regional Medians)              .      .         19
Figure 2.8   Volatility of Growth of GDP and Private Consumption in Latin America
(Ten-Year Window, Regional Medians) .............................................. .. 20
Figure 2.9   The Links Between Aggregate and Microeconomic Volatility    ...............          ................... 22
Figure 2.10  Long-Run Own Wage Elasticities, 1980-95, Chile    ..................           ....................... 22
Figure 2.11 Wage and Unemployment Okun Coefficients                   ..23
Figure 2.12 White- and Blue-Collar Wage Volatility, Mexico               ..24
Figure 2.13 White- and Blue-Collar Wage Volatility, Argentina              ..25
Figure 2.14 Unemployment Rate and Expected Duration, Montevideo                ..26
Figure 2.15  Unemployment Rate and Expected Duration, Interior Uruguay .26
Figure 2.16a Unemployment Rate and Expected Duration, Greater Santiago             ..27
Figure 2.16b Labor Turnover, LAC and OECD Countries                 ..28
Figure 2.17 Evolution of Turnover in Chile, 1980-95                ..28
Figure 2.18 Evolution of Turnover in Colombia, 1980-91                ..29
Figure 2.19 Expected Tenure in Current Job, Montevideo (Months)              ..29
vi



CONTENTS
Figure 2.20   Expected Tenure in Current Job, Interior Uruguay (Months) .................................. 30
Figure 2.21 Expected Tenure on Job, Greater Santiago .30
Figure 2.22 Self-Employment versus Industrial Productivity, OECD and LAC .31
Figure 2.23 Growth and Income Mobility in Argentina .34
Figure 2.24 Growth and Income Mobility in Mexico .35
Figure 4.1    Volatility in Terms of Trade Growth (Regional Medians) ..................................... 46
Figure 4.2    Share in Total Exports of Four Most Important Commodities (Selected LAC Countries) ....                                ........... 46
Figure 4.3    Volatility of Terms of Trade Shocks by Decade (Regional Medians) .............................. 47
Figure 4.4    Median Private Gross Capital Flows to Latin America (Percent of GDP) .......................... 48
Figure 4.5      Spread of Foreign-Currency-Denominated Sovereign Debt Instruments (bps)
(Selected Major Latin American Countries) .............................................. 48
Figure 4.6    Coefficient of Variation of Gross Private Capital Flows (Percent of GDP, Regional Medians) .... .                        ...... 49
Figure 4.7    Volatility of Reserve Money Growth (Regional Medians) ..................................... 50
Figure 4.8    Volatility of Public Consumption Growth (Regional Medians) ................................. 50
Figure 4.9    Monetary Volatility and Fiscal Volatility ................................................. 51
Figure 4.10 Fiscal Volatility and Terms of Trade Volatility .51
Figure 4.11 Chile's Excess Sensitivity to Shocks .52
Figure 4.12 Copper Prices and Chile's Current Account .53
Figure 4.13 Average Private Domestic Credit (Percent of GPD, Regional Medians) .54
Figure 4.14   Stock Market Capitalization and Turnover Ratios (Regional Medians in Percent, 1990-98) .54
Figure 4.15   Stock Market Capitalization and Turnover Ratios for Selected LAC Countries, 1995-98, Averages .55
Figure 4.16   Stock Market Illiquidity (Regression Coefficient of Absolute Price Changes on Trade Volume) .55
Figure 4.17 GDP Volatility and Credit Depth .56
Figure 4.18 Credit Crunches in Argentina .57
Figure 4.19   Credit Crunches in Brazil ...................................  ........................ 57
Figure 4.20 Credit Crunches in Mexico .............................. 58
Figure 4.21 Fire Sales ..............................                                                                                           60
Figure 4.22 Excess Vulnerability ..............................                                                                                  60
Figure 4.23  Why is Latin America More Volatile than Industrial and East Asian Countries? .61
Figure 5.1    Income Gains and Losses in Seven Episodes of Volatility in Brazil ............................... 79
Figure 5.2    El Salvador: Cumulative Distributions of Real Income Per Capita, 1995 and 1997  .................. 81
Figure 5.3    Brazil: Moves Into and Out of Poverty, by Level of Education
a. Into Poverty During Growth  .              ..................................................... 82
b. Into Poverty During Recession . ..................................................... 82
c. Out of Poverty During Growth ..................................................... 82
d. Out of Poverty During Recession .               ................................................... 82
Figure 5.4    Change in Housework Time Due to Labor Force Entry ....................................... 83
Figure 5.5  Brazil: Probability of School Dropout .                  ................................................... 84
Figure 5.6    Brazil: Probability of Repeating a Grade at School .......................................... 84
Figure 5.7    Brazil: Probability of Child Aged 10-15 Starting Work ...................................... 84
Figure 6.1    Workers Pay for UI even Though the Contributions are Levied on Firms ........................ 105
Figure 6.2    Workers and Firms Share Ul Costs even Though Contributions are Levied on Firms ....                                 ............ 105
Figure 7.1      Targeted Social Spending Over the Economic Cycle ........................................ 112
vii






Acknowledgments
HIS REPORT IS THE RESULT OF A COLLECTIVE EFFORT BY A WORLD BANK TEAM COORDI-
nated by the Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean region and
led by Guillermo Perry. Main authors by chapter were Guillermo Perry (Chapter 1),
Indermit S. Gill (Chapters 1, 3, 5, 6, and 7), Luis Serv6n (Chapters 1, 2 and 4), William F.
Maloney (Chapters 2 and 5), Nadeem Ilahi (Chapters 3 and 7), Francisco H. G. Ferreira
(Chapter 5), and Martin Rama (Chapter 6).
At the World Bank, major contributions were made by Wendy Cunningham, Gabriel Gonzalez, Emily
Gustafsson-Wright, Norman Hicks, William Jack, Pedro Olinto, Bernadette Ryan, Guilherme Sedlacek,
Rashmi Shankar, Mark Thomas, and Quentin Wodon. Outside contributors included Carlos Arango
(University of Illinois), Ricardo Caballero (MIT), Jonathan Conning (Williams College), Adriana D. Kugler
(Universitat Pompeu Fabra), Donna MacIsaac (consultant), Alejandra Mizala (Universidad de Chile),
Marcelo Neri (Fundacao Getulio Vargas), Martin Ravallion (Universite des Sciences Sociales, Toulouse),
Dani Rodrik (Harvard University), Pilar Romaguera (Universidad de Chile), James M. Snyder (MIT),
Alvaro Trigueros (Universidad Centroamericana, San Salvador), and Irene Yackovlev (MIT).
Valuable comments were received from Ian Bannon,    The report team was advised by a Steering Committee
Suman Bery, Francois Bourguignon, Ariel Fiszbein,   consisting of Robert Holzmann, Gobind T. Nankani, and
Marcelo Giugale, Gillette Hall, Emmanuel Y Jimenez,   Dani Rodrik. Xavier Coll, Ana-Maria Arriagada, Charles
Steen Jorgensen, Homi Kharas, Kathie Krumm, Klaus   Griffin, and Donald R. Winkler also provided guidance
Schmidt-Hebbel, and Michael Walton.                 and support.
The report also benefited from the comments and sug-  However, any errors or omissions in the report are the
gestions provided by participants at the Forum on Poverty,   sole responsibility of the authors and should not be attrib-
Vulnerability, and Inequality held in Lima in August   uted to any of the above individuals or the institutions they
1999. Special thanks to Katherine Bain for facilitating the   represent.
report team's participation at the Forum. Valuable com-  Finally, Diane Stamm, Christopher Neal, and Lee
ments were also received at the Latin America Economists'   Morrison made a superb effort to see this publication
Retreat held in Baltimore in November 1999.        through the final stages of production.
ix






Acronyms and Abbreviations
ECLAC          Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean
EDS            Encuesta de Desarrollo Social
ENEU           National Urban Employment Survey
ENH            Encuesta National de Hogares
EPH            Permanent Household Survey
FDI            Foreign direct investment
FGTS           Fundo Garantia por Tempo de Servicio
FHIS           Social investment fund
FONASA         Fondo Nacional de Salud (formerly SERMENA)
GDP            Gross domestic product
GNP            Gross national product
IA             Individual savings accounts
IBGE           Brazilian Statistical Institute
IDB            Inter-American Development Bank
IFI            International financial institution
IFPRI          International Food Policy Research Institute
ILO            International Labour Organisation
IMF            International Monetary Fund
ISAPRE         Instituciones de Salud Previsional
LAC            Latin America and the Caribbean
LSMS           Living Standards Measurement Survey
NIC            Newly industrialized country
OECD           Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
PETI           Programa de Erradicacao do Trabalho Infantil
PME            Monthly Employment Survey
PNAD           Pesquisa Nacional de Amostra de Domocilios
PRAF II        Programa de Asignacion Familiar, Second Phase
PW             Public works
SP             Mandatory severance pay
SIMCE          Sistema de Medicion de la Calidad de la Ensenanza
SUS            Sistema Unico de Saude
TG             Training for the unemployed
UI             Unemployment insurance
xi






CHAPTER 1
Opportunity and Risk
in a Globalized Latin America
and the Caribbean
Latin America and the Caribbean's Performance Improved in the 1990s
I   N THE 1990S LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN (LAC) BEGAN TO RESURFACE FROM THE "LOST
decade" of the 1980s. Real per capita income, as measured by gross domestic product (GDP) per per-
son, grew at about 1.5 percent per year,1 after having declined in the 1980s. Granted, the pace of eco-
nomic expansion in the 1990s was, like in earlier decades, still slower than that of the seven "East
Asian miracle" countries. It also fell short of the growth rates achieved in the 1960s and 1970s in
Latin America, during which real per capita GDP grew at over 2 percent per year. But this growth decline
relative to the pre-1982 performance affected all world regions, industrial and developing-with the excep-
tion of only South Asia (see Figure 1.1).
The incipient growth recovery was punctuated by episodes of regionwide financial turmoil-such as
Mexico's Tequila crisis of 1994-95 and the worldwide fallout from the East Asia and Russia crises in 1997
and 1998-and was uneven across the region. As Table 1.1 shows, the majority of Latin America's larger
economies-those with populations above 1 million in 1995-shared in the resumption of growth relative
to the 1980s.2 Chile, the earliest reformer in the region, achieved rapid growth, well above historical levels.
Other reforming countries such as Argentina, Bolivia, El Salvador, and Peru also grew faster in the 1990s
than in previous decades. At the other extreme, several countries that have lagged behind in structural
reforms (Ecuador, Haiti, Jamaica, Paraguay, and Venezuela)   Jamaica and Venezuela the only countries-among those
witnessed a decline in per capita GDP relative to the   for which the information is available-to experience a
1980s. Finally, Brazil's growth rate declined compared to   decline in private consumption per person relative to the
the 1980s, reflecting the adverse effects of macroeconomic   1980s (see Table 1.2).
imbalances and financial market turbulence during much
of the 1990s.                                        Opportunities and Risks
Rising incomes were duly reflected in improving living   The improvement in LAC's economic fortunes followed a
standards in the majority of LAC economies, as measured   sustained reform effort by many countries in the region
by per capita private consumption growth, which   aimed at enhancing the role of market forces and increas-
rebounded from the negative rates of the 1980s. As with   ing the region's real and financial integration into the
GDP, however, the performance of consumption fell short   global economy. The incipient economic upturn of the
of the pace witnessed prior to the debt crisis of 1982, and    1990s suggests that this strategy has started to generate
remained considerably behind the pace of the East Asian   new opportunities for LAC in the global scene, especially
miracle economies (see Figure 1.2). Nevertheless, the   for earlier and deeper reforming economies. In spite of bet-
upturn in consumption reached most countries in the   ter opportunities, however, perceptions of economic inse-
region, with Chile and El Salvador the star performers, and   curity run high in the region. Indeed, there is a widely held
I



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 1.1
Per Capita GDP Growth
(Regional Medians)
7-
6- 0                                                                                                                    1960      _
5                                                                                                                  U    1970;
4-                                                           .                                                             .  .....        0000000019980s'
v3  -._   1 990!i
U   2 - .il_^-                                  ^^1 ~           ^^        i         _        _ 
-2
Industrialized     East Asia 7     Latin America and   Middle East and     South Asia     Sub-Saharan Africa   Other Easr Asia
Economies                          the Caribbean      North Africa                                             and Pacific
TABLE 1.1                                                                view  that economic insecurity3 has become so Fervasive
Per Capita GDP Growth in Latin America                                   that it could undermine social and political support for the
(Percent)                                                               ongoing reform  process, and even bring it to a halt.4
COUNTRY                    1960s      1970s      1980s      1990s           That insecurity is a major concern for large segrments of
Argentina*                   2.4       1.2       -2.4        3.0        LAC's population is vividly illustrated by recent opinion
Bolivia                      0.7       1.7       -2.5         1.8        surveys in  the  region. In  a large  cross-country  survey
Brazil                       2.9       5.7        0.8        0.4         undertaken  in  1999, for example, nearly  two-thirds of
Chile                        2.0       0.6        2.5        4.7
Colombia                     2.0       3.3        1.2        0.6         respondents said that their parents had lived better than
Costa Rica                   2.3       3.4       -0.8        2.0        them, while less than  half thought that their children
Dominican Republic           1.2       5.2        1.5        2.2
Ecuador                      1.0       5.8       -0.3        -0.3        would have lives better than their own (see Table 1.-3). This
El Salvador                  2.4       1.2       -3.2        2.8         pessimistic view  about the future affected not only coun-
Guatemala                    2.5       3.0       -1.6         1.4
Honduras                     1.6       2.4       -0.7        0.3         tries experiencing major economic and social difficulties,
Haiti                      -1.4        1.8       -1.5       -3.1        such as Ecuador or Venezuela, but also others that had seen
Jamaica                      2.6      -0.4        0.1        -0.2** 
JaMeica                      2.6      30.4        0.0       10.2         a marked improvement in their economic performance in
Mexico                       3.4       3.3        0.0         1.5
Nicaragua                    3.9      -3.2       -3.7        -0.5       the 1990s, such as Argentina, Mexico, and Peru. Indeed,
Panama                       4.8       1.9       -1.4        3.3         even in these countries, a relatively small percentage of
Paraguay                     1.7       4.9        0.8       -0.2
Peru                         2.2       1.1       -2.4         1.9        respondents--43 percent in Argentina, 30 percent in Mex-
Trinidad and Tobago         4.2        4.7       -1.0         1.3       ico, and 37 percent in Peru-anticipated a better future for
Uruguay                      0.2       2.3       -0.2        3.0        their children.5
Venezuela                    1.2       0.4       -2.8        -0.2
Mean                         2.1       2.4       -0.8        1.2            Along with  this heightened  concern about economic
Median                       2.2       2.3       -0.8         1.4       insecurity, there are also strong signs of unsatisfied demand
Small Countries                                                         for social insurance. The same survey mentioned  above
Bahamas                      5.3      -0.7        1.5        -2.1
Belize                       2.2       4.2        2.6         1.7       found  that three-quarters  of the  respondents  favored
Barbados*                    5.7       2.9        1.7        0.2        increased spending on unemployment insurance. All even
Guyana                       1.1       0.8       -3.5        4.0
Mean                         3.6       1.8        0.6        1.0         hgher number supported  icreased  spendig  on  social
Median                       3.7       1.9        1.6         1.0        security (see Table 1.4). Moreover, the extent of support for
Unweighted average          2.3        2.3       -0.6        1.2        these programs varied little with the respondents' income
Overall nedian              2.2        2.3       -0.7        1.4        and education  level, or even with  the economic perfor-
Wei gheed average*          2.5        3.5       -0.1        .1.
mance  of the  different countries.  In  high-performing
*Weighted averages use 1995 population.
Note Decades are defined as 1961-69, 1970-79, 1980-89, 1990-99. Sample period is  Chile, for example, 85 percent of the respondents favored
defined as 1961-98. Exceprions: Bahamnas (1961-95), Barbados (1961-95), Guyana  increased unemployment insurance, and over 90 percent
(1961-95), Peru (1966-99). For Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru,
and Venezuela, figures are updated to 1999.                              supported greater pension expenditures.
2



OPPORTUNITY AND RISK IN A GLOBALIZED LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN
FIGURE 1.2
Per Capita Private Consumption Growth
(Regional Medians)
7-
6                                                                                                                        1960s
5-                                                                                                                       1970s
4-                                                                                                                       1980s
rv 3-X ~ | * . . * 19905
3-
2-2
-2-   Industrialized       East Asia 7    Latin America and   Middle East and      South Asia     Sub-Saharan Africa   Other East Asia
Economies                          the Caribbean      North Africa                                             and Pacific
TABLE 1.2                                                               Why Economic Insecurity?
Per Capita Private Consumption Growth in Latin Amenca                   What lies behind these perceptions of insecurity and social
(Percent)                                                               insurance demands? There are several factors. On the one
COUNTRY                    1960s      197()s     1980s      1990s       hand, the unprecedented severity and duration of the crisis
Argenrina*                   2.2       1.1       -1.7        4.0         unleashed  in  1982-reflected  in  a sharp  and  long-lived
Bolivia                      .4         .4       -1.3        1.0        decline in per capita incomes from which LAC has taken many
Brazil                       2.4       6.4       -0.6        1.9
Chile                       4.7        0.2        0.5        5.8        years to recover-left a profound imprint across the region's
Colombia                     2.6       3.2        0.7        1.4         social fabric concerning the dangers of economic instability.
Costa Rica                   1.4       2.7       -1.7         1.2
Dominican Republic           3.1       4.6        1.0        0.9            On the other hand, the incipient recovery from  the "lost
Ecuador                      1.8       3.9       -0. 1       0.2        decade" of thel980s came along with a radical change in eco-
El Salvador                  1.7       0.9       -3.4        5.2
Guatemala                    1.9       2.6       -1.2         1.5        nomic strategy in many LAC economies-a shift away from
Honduras                     1.1       1.6       -0.1        0.2        the protected government-led development model of previ-
Haiti                       -2.6       1.1       -0.7
Jamaica                      1.0      -0.3        2.4        -2.8        ous decades, and toward a new  paradigm  of strengthened
Mexico                       2.8       2.5        0.0        1.1
Nicaragua                    3.6      -3.5       -4.6        0.0         domestic and foreign market forces in the context of a global
Panama                        ..        .,        3.6        3.0        economy. Barriers sheltering domestic economies from global
Paraguay                     3.3       3.0        1.0        3.2        trade and financial trends were lowered, obstacles to compe-
Peru                         4.0       0.9       -2.1        1.5
Trinidad and Tobago          4.6       4.9       -2.1         1.5       tition in domestic markets were removed or substantially
Uruguay                     -0.4       0.8        0.2        4.1
Venezuela                    ..        6.1       -1.6        -0.6       weakened across LAC, and governments reduced consider-
Mean                         2.2       2.3       -0.6         1.7        ably their direct involvement in economic activity.
,Median                     2.3        2.5       -0.6        1.4            These  reforms deserve  much  of the credit for LAC's
Small Countries
Bahamas                      ..       22.7        2.3                   expanding economic opportunities in the 1990s. However,
Belize                        ..        ..       -2.3        2.1        while the reforms assigned a greater role to the action of
Barbados*                    ..         ..         ..        0.9
Guyana                       1.3      -0.3       -3.6        5.8        domestic and global market forces, they also led to the weak-
Mean                         1.3      11.2       -1.2        2.9        ening  of major components  of the  rudimentary  and
Median                       1.3      21.2       -2.3        2.1         inequitable traditional social protection system. The weak-
Unweighted average          2.1        3.3       -0.5        1.7
Overall median               2.2       2.5       -0.6        1.5         ening of extensne barriers to domestic and foreign competi-
Weighted average**          2.3        3.7       -0.5        1.7        tion made it harder to sustain a generous provision of public
*Consumption figures for Argentina and Barbados correspond to total, and not pri-  sector jobs and stringent firing restrictions that had resulted
vate, consumption. Argentina: 1961-98, Barbados: 1967-94.
**Weighted averages use 1995 population.                                in virtual lifetime employment for formal sector workers.
Note: Decades are defined as 1961-69, 1970-79, 1980-89, 1990-99. Sample period is  Th   r     f  h      o
defined as 1961-98. Exceptions: Bahamas (1978-87), Barbados (1967-94), Belize  e remova  o  these old mechanisms icompatible
(1981-98), Bolivia (1961-79,1981-98), Guyana (1961-88), Haiti (1966-90), Hon-  with  the new  market-oriented  economic model has not
duras (1961-97), Nicaragua (1961-96), Panama (1981-98), Peru (1966-98), and
Venezuela (1975-98).                                                     been matched by the development of a new social protec-
3



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 1.3
Survey Responses in Latin American Countries on Expected Changes in Living Standards
(Percentages Unless Otherwise Noted)
WHOLE SAMPLE                                                    COUNTRY
N               %            ARGENTINA          BOLIVIA           BRAZIL           CHILE           COLOMBIA
14,839           t00              1,200             794              1,00()           1,200            1.200
Taking everything into consideration, would you say that your parents lived better, the same, or worse than how you live today?
Better              9,081            61.2               63               51                64              45                78
Same                3,261            22                 22               31                 9               32               14
Worse               2,139            14.4               12               16                25               22                8
No answer            358              2.4                3                3                 2                1                1
And regarding your children, do you believe that they will live better, rhe same, or worse than how you live today?
Better              6,843            46.1               43               56                58               61               36
Same                3,071            20.7               22               20                12              22                .1
Worse               3,261            22                 20               13                21               11               38
No answer           1,664            11.2               16               11                 9                7                6
Source: Mirror on the Americas poll, 1999, Wa/l StreetJournal.
TABLE 1.4
Sufvey Responses to Social Insurance-Related Questions in 14 Latin Amefican Countries, by Socioeconomic Category
(Percentages Unless Otherwise Noted)
WHOLE SAMPLE                           AGE                                  EMPLOYMENT
SELF-                     PRIVATE
N            5N           18-29         30-49         50+        EMPLOYED  GOVERNMENT    SECTOR
Unemployment Insurance
No answer                      551          3.7            3             4            4             4             5             3
Spend more                  10,088         73.4           74            73           73            74            69            74
Spend less                   2543          17.1           18            18            16           17            19            17
Don't know                    857           5.8            5             5            7             5             7             6
Pensions
No answer                      172          1.2            1             1             1             1            2             1
Spend more                  12,426         83.7           83           83            86            83            84            84
Spend less                   1861          12.5           13            13           10            13            12            13
Don't know                    380           2.6            3             3            3             3             2             2
Defense and the Armed forces
No answer                     623           4.2            4             5            5             4             6             3
Spend more                   4810          32.4           33            31           34            34            28            29
Spend less                   8359          56.3           58            57           53            56            59           61
Don't know                   1047           7.1            5             7            9             6             7             7
Source: Mirrow on the Americas poll, 1999, Wall Street Joarnal.
tion and insurance system more suited to the changed eco-                In addition, the improving economic environment in
nomic environment. Thus, while households and workers                 LAC relative to the 1980s may itself be partly responsible
in LAC's reforming economies have gained access to new                for the heightened social insurance demand. Perhaps para-
economic opportunities, they may have been left more                  doxically, economic analysis-this report shows-suggests
exposed to new  risks as well. Growth resumption in the               that in better times, when individuals have more to lose
new  economic environment entails faster job creation in              and can afford more of the costs of protecting against risk,
expanding industries, and thus new opportunities, but also            they may also demand more effective protection and insur-
job destruction in declining sectors, and hence new risks.            ance mechanisms. All these factors make economic insecu-
4



OPPORTUNITY AND RISK IN A GLOBALIZED LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN
COUNTRY
COSTA RICA      ECUADOR    GUATEMALA           MEXICO        PANAMA        PARAGUAY          PERU         URUGUAY       VENEZUELA
1,00()         1,200         1 ,I1(10        1,200          1,0(0          6011           1,(45          1,200          1,200
56             67            57              43             52             75             80             59             70
26             20            31              35             24             14             12             18             19
14             10            11              20             21              6              6             20             10
5              2             1               3              3              5              2              3              2
52             34            51              30             48             48             37             46             53
25             21            23              23             20             26             19             22             17
11             29            17              41             21             13             26             19             19
12             16             8               6             12             13             19             13             12
EMPLOYMENT                                      EDUCATION                                 INCOME
UNEMPLOYED    RETIRED    HOUSEWIFE    STUDENT           PRIMARY        HIGH       UNIVERSITY       HIGH        MIDDLE         LOW
3            4             4            3             4            3             4             4            4             3
80            74           73            74           74           75            71            72           73            74
13            16           17            19           16           16             19           19           17            17
3             6            7             5            7            5             6             4            6             6
1             1            1             1            1            1              1            2            1             1
88            88           84            82           83           85             83           83           85            83
9             9           12            15           13           12             14           14           11            13
1             2            3            2             3            2             2             2            2             3
3             5            4             3            4            4             5             5            5             3
36            33           35            32           37           33             27           32           31            34
56            54           52            6(0          50           57            62            58           56            57
5             8            9             5            8            7             7             6            8             7
rity one of the major unresolved items in LAC's policy               of moving down or being left behind-hence the concern
agenda.                                                              with insecurity and inequality.
Inequality  stands as the region's other big pending                 The social costs of insecurity should not be downplayed.
issue. Indeed, as noted earlier, inequality and insecurity are       Uncertainty about future employment and income has a
related. Increased economic opportunities tend to enhance            direct adverse impact on welfare, because most households
income mobility-the chances of moving up or down the                 and workers care not only about the level of their standard
distribution ladder. Thus, these added opportunities for    of living, but also about its certainty-as the survey evi-
economic improvement may come along with greater risks               dence above clearly illustrates.
5



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Further, economic uncertainty itself can hamper real   households react to economic insecurity, the policy chal-
income growth, a fact confirmed by extensive empirical   lenges these responses present, and the policies that are
research focusing on LAC and other regions.6 In essence,   best suited for countries in the region are based on recent
high degrees of uncertainty tend to discourage growth-   empirical and theoretical research conducted at the World
enhancing long-term commitments, such as investment in    Bank and elsewhere, on economic volatility and social risk
physical and human capital, as individuals attempt to    management, drawing on the experiences of countries in
retain extra flexibility in order to deal with a volatile envi-   Latin America and other parts of the world.9
ronment.' As a result, the choice of investment projects   This report begins by stating the facts concerning eco-
and production technologies is biased by inefficient "short-   nomic insecurity in LAC (Chapter 2). It then sets out a
termism" that leads to a diminished growth potential for   general analytical framework to help organize the various
income and living standards.                            options available to individuals and governments for deal-
Finally, there are reasons why economic insecurity is   ing with economic insecurity (Chapter 3). Using this
particularly damaging for the poorer segments of the pop-   framework, the remaining chapters focus on measures to
ulation. On the one hand, the poor often lack the means to   deal with risks. First, the causes of macroeconomic or
protect themselves from adverse income and employment   aggregate volatility are examined and some remedies sug-
shocks-means such as accumulated financial assets or   gested (Chapter 4). This report then examines how these
access to credit. For the very poor, this implies that unfa-   risks affect individuals and households, and their responses
vorable temporary shocks may result in drastic declines in   to economic shocks (Chapter 5). The risk of becoming
consumption, bringing it down below subsistence levels   unemployed is of concern in the region and elsewhere, and
and permanently damaging their well-being. On the other   public responses to help workers deal with this risk take up
hand, growth in income of the poor is primarily deter-   a full chapter (Chapter 6). Finally, the subject of appropri-
mined by overall economic growth (Dollar and Kraay    ate social insurance and social protection against the risk of
2000).5 As economic volatility hampers aggregate growth,   poverty is considered in some detail (Chapter 7). We sum-
it also hurts the growth of income of the poor and their   marize the findings of these chapters here.
chances to rise out of poverty. In fact, a 1999 World Bank
study shows that economic insecurity ranks high among    LAC's Volatility is High-But has not Risen in the
the concerns expressed by the poor in LAC and across the    1990s
world (Narayan and others 1999).                        Like most developing regions, LAC suffers from high eco-
nomic volatility, well above the levels experienced by
This Report                                             industrial economies. Furthermore, living standarcls-as
The purpose of this report is to assess the extent, causes, and    measured by per capita consumption-are more volatile
effects of economic insecurity in LAC and identify policies   than real incomes, a feature shared with much of the devel-
and institutions that can help reduce the degree of insecu-   oping world but not with most OECD countries. This
rity faced by workers and households in the region, while   reflects a lack of adequate instruments for consumption-
allowing them to take advantage of the enhanced economic   smoothing in developing countries.
opportunities brought about by the reforms of recent years.  Contrary to a widely held view, however, there is no evi-
Insecurity is a broad topic, however, and this report can-   dence that volatility has increased following the region-
not cover all of its many aspects. Thus, the report leaves   wide shift toward a market-oriented economy and the
aside issues related to crime and violence and insecurity   increased integration of LAC into global markets. On the
caused by natural disasters, to focus on the specific issue of   contrary, the volatility of income growth has declined in
insecurity caused by economic fluctuations. Within this    most of the region's economies, and in a number of them it
narrower area, social security and pensions, which have    has fallen below the levels of the 1970s. To a lesser extent,
more to do with life-cycle considerations than economic   the volatility of private consumption has also declined. In
fluctuations, are also excluded from the discussion.    addition, there is no evidence that the income and employ-
This still leaves a wide range of issues to be addressed in    ment uncertainty faced by the majority of workers and
the chapters that follow. The analysis of how workers and    households in the region has changed for the worse-
6



OPPORTUNITY AND RISK IN A GLOBALIZED LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN
although economic insecurity must surely have risen for   Although the 1990s have witnessed a decline relative to
specific groups of workers adversely affected by the reforms    the 1980s in the volatility arising from  each of these
in some countries, especially some elder workers in the for-   sources, the region faces larger terms of trade volatility
mal sector, whose skills may have been rendered obsolete   than most other developing regions. Likewise, the volatil-
by economic restructuring.                                ity of capital inflows and domestic policies is also higher in
LAC than in industrial economies and the more stable
Dealing with Economic Insecurity Requires a               developing regions, such as the East Asian miracle
Comprehensive Insurance Approach                         economies.
There are three major options available for dealing with    Further, the economic impact of disturbances is magni-
risk: market-type insurance, which involves sharing of   fied by the region's weak links with international financial
risks among individuals (or countries); self-insurance,   markets and the insufficient development of domestic
which typically entails precautionary saving or accumula-   financial systems, which lag behind those of other world
tion of assets in good times to shelter consumption in bad    regions. In theory, domestic and foreign financial markets
times; and self-protection, which involves the adoption of   should play a major role in facilitating risk diversification
measures to reduce the likelihood of adverse shocks. In    and easing the adjustment to shocks. In practice their
general, effective risk-management strategies should   imperfections make them have the opposite effect-they
employ all three types of instruments. The more instru-    amplify aggregate shocks and are themselves a source of
ments are available, the better the chances of sheltering liv-   volatility.
ing standards from economic insecurity.                     Thus, for example, developing countries should be able
This general perspective illustrates the role of public   to diversify terms of trade risks by hedging in international
policies in dealing with risk. Government interventions are   financial markets. In practice, however, these markets are
warranted by the presence of incomplete or imperfect    not deep enough, and capital flows behave procyclically
domestic insurance markets that lead individuals to costly    with respect to trade shocks, amplifying the international
and inefficient self-insurance or self-protection decisions,   business cycle. More generally, in spite of recent progress
such as distress sales of assets or reduced investments in    with the development of new  international financial
human capital (for example, taking children out of school)   instruments such as contingent credit lines, world markets
at times of crisis. Government interventions, in the form of   still offer few possibilities for risk diversification and insur-
social insurance and social protection, attempt to remedy these    ance against aggregate disturbances. Hence, as discussed
market failures, augment the availability and scope of mar-   below, there is a role for supranational policy actions aimed
ket insurance and efficient instruments for self-insurance,   at the creation of missing markets and the enhancement of
and buttress the self-protection efforts by individuals that   instruments for international risk diversification.
pay off only if sustained for some time. As with other types
of insurance, the design and implementation of these pol-    Governments Can Do Much to Reduce Volatility-Even
icy interventions must deal with the serious challenges   in a Globalized Economy
posed by adverse selection and moral hazard.              Governments possess a broad range of possible measures to
This conceptual framework also shows how increased    reduce aggregate volatility, that can improve risk-sharing,
demand for social insurance may indeed result from an    enhance economywide self-insurance, and reduce the like-
improvement-rather than a deterioration-in the eco-   lihood of adverse aggregate shocks. Given the rudimentary
nomic environment, a factor that might be partly behind    state of international insurance markets, the main options
the results of LAC opinion surveys mentioned above.       left to governments involve self-insurance and self-protec-
tion mechanisms. Many such mechanisms have already
LAC's Volatility Arises from Multiple Sources-            been adopted by various countries in the region, and all
Domestic and Foreign                                      entail economic costs. Thus, the policy mix best suited to
LAC's macroeconomic volatility reflects both external dis-   each economy is largely dependent on country-specific fac-
turbances-in international goods and financial markets-   tors shaping the cost-effectiveness of the various policy
and volatile domestic fiscal and monetary policies.   options.
7



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
External Risks Can Be Reduced by Diversification and      like in others, faces a fundamental tradeoff between credi-
Liquidity Management                                      bility and flexibility. Rigid exchange rate pegs without the
Nevertheless, some clear general principles emerge from   option of an independent monetary policy may enhance
the analysis. To deal effectively with terms of trade volatil-   credibility, but can also make adjustment to shocks more
ity, countries can resort to risk diversification and hedging    painful in the presence of inflexible labor markets or inad-
in  international commodity  markets, self-insurance    equate fiscal policy. Floating exchange rate arrangements
through commodity stabilization funds, and self-protec-    with active monetary policy may offer enhanced flexibility
tion through trade diversification. Facilitating foreign    to deal with shocks, but can erode credibility unless clear
direct investment (FDI) is another way of diversifying    and transparent rules for monetary policy-possibly con-
risks, and FDI also yields other benefits such as innovation    tingent on developments in world goods and financial mar-
spillovers, enhanced corporate governance, and higher    kets-are publicly announced and strictly followed by the
investment. Allowing domestic investors to hold foreign    authorities. Intermediate options such as adjustable pegs,
assets also improves their own risk diversification strategy    crawling pegs, and exchange rate bands probably offer the
and increases the resilience of the economy as a whole.   worst of both worlds without the advantages of either one.
In turn, facing up to capital flow volatility in a context of
limited international insurance possibilities requires holdings    Deeper and Stronger Financial Systems Are a Key Part
of liquid assets and a prudent debt management strategy, and    of Social Protection Policies
avoiding excessive short-term  liabilities, "bunching" of   Development of deeper capital markets and strong bank-
repayments, and currency mismatches between assets and lia-   ing systems is a major priority to allow them to play their
bilities. Capital controls may offer another self-protection    intended role of shock absorbers and hence mitigate the
tool to limit exposure to international financial disturbances,   economic impact of disturbances. Enhanced capital and
but their effectiveness remains under debate. They may affect   liquidity requirements for banks-perhaps set in a pro-
the composition of flows-discouraging volatile short-run    cyclical manner-under adequate supervision, and preven-
transactions if properly designed-but they seem powerless   tion of currency mismatches can go a long way toward
to alter their volume beyond the near term.               strengthening the banks, so that they can contribute effec-
tively to self-insurance against shocks. Strong and deep
Anticyclical Macroeconomic Policies Ease Adjustment to   financial systems are of paramount importance to facilitate
Shocks                                                    savings and market insurance against microeconomic risks.
In most LAC economies, fiscal policy has failed to play its
intended stabilization role. Governments have generally    Deep Crises are Particularly Damagingfor the Poor
adopted an expansionary stance in booms and a contrac-    How are households affected by adverse economic condi-
tionary stance in recessions. To some extent, this reflects   tions, and how do they respond to crises? To answer these
constraints from worl(d and domestic financial markets. It   two questions, this report systematically used household
has also resulted, however, both from the failure of govern-    panel data for Argentina, Brazil, El Salvador, and Mexico
ments to provide for bad times by saving in good times,   in both rural and urban settings. Several findings emerge
and the lack of a sufficiently diversified fiscal revenue base,   that should make us reconsider some commonly held
which in several countries in the region is excessively    beliefs about how households respond and when, how, and
biased toward natural resource revenues. Tackling these    how much governments should help them.
two issues should be a policy priority, along with the adop-  First, economic contractions differ significantly in their
tion of contingent fiscal rules that can facilitate the    effects on poverty and human capital investments: in deep
response to shocks and make it more transparent, and the    recessions the poor suffer greater proportional losses in
implementation of a prudent public debt management   income than the wealthy. In moderate recessions, the oppo-
strategy along the lines mentioned earlier.               site appears to happen-in many cases, the greatest pro-
Finally, adequate monetary and exchange rate policies    portional income losses were borne by the rich, and some
can also make an important contribution to the absorption    groups often thought to suffer disproportionately-such as
of shocks. The choice of specific policy rules in this area,   the elderly or single mothers-do not appear to be espe-
8



OPPORTUNITY AND RISK IN A GLOBALIZED LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN
cially badly affected, although this is not true in every cri-  in employment contracts. In the old economic environ-
sis and in every setting. For example, the findings differ   ment, these schemes effectively pooled unemployment
between countries or, for the same country, between rural   risks over a greater population because consumers actually
and urban areas. On the whole, however, the conventional   subsidized potentially bankrupt firms through higher
wisdom that the poor invariably are affected more severely   prices. But with globalization and reduced barriers to
during recessions needs to be qualified.                trade, this is no longer possible: prices are determined by
Second, the poor seem to have gained more during    world markets, so the pooling of unemployment risk
growth periods than is generally acknowledged. This does   becomes restricted to the firm. These provisions have also
not mean that the poor should not be helped; it merely   proved to be contentious, complicated to enforce, and judi-
implies that from the perspective of poverty alleviation,   cially burdensome.
growth-oriented policies must be given a high priority,   With neither economic efficiency nor administrative
regardless of concerns of high inequality in the region.  ease to recommend mandated severance pay, some coun-
tries in the region have moved away from it, and others are
The Poor Try to Protect Their Long-Term Welfare in      contemplating change. This report considers the experi-
Crises-As Long as Their Assets Permit                   ence of both reformers and nonreformers in this regard, and
Third, the poor-like those with more wealth-are reluc-   also employs theoretical principles to provide guidance to
tant to permanently compromise their family's future dur-   countries in the region. In deciding whether to move
ing economic crises perceived to be temporary. This is  toward government-mandated self-insurance-through
especially true of parental decisions about their children.   schemes such as individual savings accounts to be accessed
The poor do not, for example, frequently pull their chil-   in case of unemployment-or to forms of unemployment
dren out of school during bad times-although they do   insurance that involve the pooling of risk, several factors
when the recession is severe. But the fact that some educa-   must be considered.
tional and health outcomes are hurt during especially bad
times may be as much the result of the government's   Administrative Capacity and Labor Policies are Key in
inability to maintain the quality of social services as the   the Choice of Instruments
household's decision to invest less during crises.      The first critical issue is the administrative capacity of gov-
Finally and unsurprisingly, access to "reserves"-such as   ernment. While administrative capacity can always be
assets and underused family labor-reduces a household's   built over time, it does limit the options of government in
vulnerability to shocks, in the sense of having to adjust   the immediate future. However, a blend of practicality and
through reduced consumption or critical investments such    analytical rigor can help countries devise strategies that
as schooling and health. Assets may be the key factor for   efficiently bridge immediate action and long-term vision.
explaining differences in the responses of poor versus rich  The second critical issue is the nature of labor markets,
households in large versus moderate economic contrac-   which influences the level and nature of risks faced by
tions. In brief or mild contractions, even the limited assets   workers. The logical first step is to do more to reduce the
of the poor can help weather the crisis; in more severe or   likelihood of adverse employment shocks. Most LAC
recurring crises, the poor may eventually exhaust their   economies have high levels of informal employment, and
assets and be forced to suffer drastic declines in their well-   many have high rates of formal unemployment as well.
being, with adverse long-term  effects. Hence policies   While these phenomena have diverse causes (for example,
aimed at strengthening the human capital of the poor (edu-   high rates of taxation, overregulated labor markets, poor
cation, health) can enhance their self-insurance and self-   macroeconomic policies that impede growth), labor policy
protection efforts.                                     changes are widely regarded as lagging other economic
reforms in the region. For governments that wish to facili-
New Income Support Programs for the Unemployed         tate comprehensive insurance decisions by their workers
Need to be Established                                  and households in a rapidly changing global economy,
The common form of public unemployment support in   labor policies should receive a high priority on the reform
much of LAC has been mandatory severance pay provisions   agenda.
9



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Self-Insurance for Slow-Reforming Economies            Targeted Programs for the Poor Need to be Bether
Countries that have not yet pursued comprehensive eco-   Protected in Downturns
nomic-especially labor market-reforms may be better   The region has improved the poverty impact of social
advised to rely more on self-insurance-type schemes such as   spending through reform over the last decade by, for exam-
individual capitalization funds. Their "insurance funda-   ple, replacing generalized subsidies with programs specifi-
mentals" favor such schemes: self-insurance is the preferred    cally designed to help the poor. However, during crises,
option when losses are frequent, it is less demanding in   spending on tightly targeted programs for the poor does
terms of administrative capacity, and the schemes entail   appear to suffer more than general social expenditures.
low labor market efficiency costs and low fiscal costs. The    Governments could do better to protect these programs
weakness of these schemes is their low attractiveness to   from cuts. Experience in the region and in the U.S. shows
poorer workers, for whom forced saving may have high   that a successful strategy requires explicitly accounting for
costs, some of which could be lowered through risk-pool-   political economy factors that make programs resilient to
ing or government subsidies.                           both political and economic changes. Such factors may
include deliberately building in some features t.hat have
Unemployment Insurance for Advanced Reforming          been associated with long-lived government interventions.
Economies
LAC economies that have reduced the risk of unemploy-   Save in Good Times to Finance Social Spending in Bad
ment through comprehensive economic and labor reforms   Times
should consider conventional unemployment insurance.   Governments in the region do appear to have behaved in a
While administrative considerations are always important,   pro-poor manner in the most general terms, especially
this capacity can generally be built. Carefully designed   since the return of democracy to the region. While author-
unemployment insurance schemes that involve pooling but   itarian and democratic regimes in LAC appear to have
keep efficiency losses low-for example, by keeping bene-   responded similarly to economic crises-both cut social
fits frugal and mimicking the market as much as possi-   spending sharply and about equally-greater increases in
ble-are likely to increase welfare. Besides helping work-   social spending take place under democratic regimes. In
ers deal with idiosyncratic risk, insurance schemes that   fact, social spending increases only when there is both
involve pooling of risk have-when designed well-also    democratic rule and a nonshrinking economy. BurF this is
shown their worth as "automatic fiscal stabilizers," which    also where governments run the greatest danger of adding
governments in the region have lacked.                 policy risk to economic risk. Well-intentioned govern-
Political opposition to labor market flexibilization is   ments or those under political pressure to sharply increase
almost always related to the perception of higher unem-   spending on social programs during growth episocles only
ployment risks in downturns. Hence, a sequencing option   to have to reduce spending in the next contraction both
to overcome political constraints may be to adopt labor   raise risk and sow the seeds of social discontent.
market reforms simultaneously with efforts to strengthen  There is considerable room for improving the design of
unemployment insurance.                                targeted programs, especially how they relate to the eco-
nomic cycle. While meeting many of the goals they were
Public Works Programs Provide Insurance Support for    designed to accomplish in both rural and urban settings,
Informal Sector Workers                                targeted conditional transfer programs such as Mexico's Pro-
Those who cannot be reached through such contributory   gresa and Brazil's Bolsa Escola may not be particularly well
schemes should be assisted through programs that implic-   suited to assist those who become poor duing economic
itly pool risks such as public works programs, and share   downturns. Through their innovative links with human
some other characteristics with good unemployment insur-   capital accumulation, these programs may be better suited
ance, principally keeping benefits frugal. Such schemes   than earlier interventions for addressing structural poverty
should be thought of as insurance-not emergency-pro-   concerns. However, the broad political support they enjoy
grams, the difference being that insurance programs are   make them a resilient policy instrument to offset cyclical
permanent while emergency programs are temporary.      swings in the quality of education and health services. Even
10



OPPORTUNITY' AND RISK IN A GLOBALIZED LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN
if more conventional instruments such as public works pro-    Latin America and the Caribbean. Uncertainty about future
grams-when designed well-are better safety nets, tar-    living standards is a major concern for workers and house-
geted conditional transfer programs offer a strong option to    holds in the region, and the report shows that there are
form  the third leg of a comprehensive social safety net-        good reasons for this. LAC, like other developing regions, is
along with social security for the aged and income support    subject to much larger economic fluctuations than indus-
for the unemployed.                                              trial economies, and has fewer instruments available to pro-
tect consumption levels from economic shocks.
Supranational Action and the Role of the International              However, contrary perhaps to popular perception, the
Financial Institutions                                           trend toward globalization in the 1990s has not made mat-
The global economy also poses risks that cannot be effec-    ters worse. Growth has risen and volatility has declined in
tively addressed by individual countries on their own.    the majority of economies in the region, and several that
Imperfections in international insurance and financial mar-    pursued strong reform  policies have enjoyed both higher
kets prevent national economies from properly diversifying       growth and lower volatility than in earlier decades, while
terms of trade risks, and typically lead to a withdrawal of    countries whose reform  drive lagged behind have been
financial support when it is most needed-that is, at the    among the worst performers in the 1990s. The lesson is that
time of adverse shocks. In this context, just as national    with globalization, good policies can reap larger rewards
governments have a major role to play because of incom-    than before, but bad policies may be more severely punished.
plete or imperfect domestic insurance markets, the imper-           This report shows that to face the new situation, adequate
fections of international markets provide a rationale for    macroeconomic policies and structural reforms need to be
supranational action. It would aim  at improving the self-    matched with the development of a social protection and
insurance and self-protection choices available to individ-    insurance system  suited  to  LAC's changed  economic
ual countries that may entail too high a cost in terms of    environment.
economic efficiency and growth, and provide insurance by
making available financing during bad times. IFIs can help       Notes
developing economies efficiently deal with risk by leading          1. The figures mentioned in this section refer to the regional
the way in developing new financial markets and instru-    median growth rate-that is the race of per capita GDP or con-
ments, such as contingent credit lines and borrowing guar-    sumption growth in the region's "typical" economy.
2. It is Important to note that available GDP growth data reach
antees. In addition, by deploying their financial resources    up  o 1999 fotr the major eight Latin American economies
anticyclically, that is, reducing their lending in good times    (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, and
and increasing it in bad times, they can partially counter-    Venezuela). The discussion in the text and the figures in the tables
act the procyclical behavior of private capital flows and        are based on this updated information. In contrast, private con-
cushion the adjustment to disturbances.                          sumption growth information only reaches up to 1998. Preliminary
forecasts for 1999 alter somewhat the performance of specific coun-
tries, but paint a broadly similar regional picture.
Myths and Realities About Economic Volatility                       3. These concerns with insecurity may reflect in part concerns
In the light of the report's analysis, Table 1.5 shows how       with (in)equity, as not all groups of economic actors have shared
some widely held notions about economic volatility and its    equally in the upturn, and some specific groups may have lost out
effects in LAC should be reassessed and qualified. In a nut-    with the reforms, at least in the short term.
shell, volatility, though still high, does not seem to have         4. The following discussion draws from Rodrik (1999).
worsened, governments can do much to reduce it even in a            5. The just-released 1999-2000 poll from Latinbarometer shows
a slightly less pessimistic picture, with 58 percent of the respondents
global economy, and closer scrutiny reveals that households    regionwide expressing the view that their parents lived better, and
and governments do not always respond  to economic    52 percent anticipating a better future for their children.
shocks in stereotypical ways.                                       6. The Inter-American Development Bank (1995) presents a com-
prehensive study of the causes and consequences of volatilty in Latin
Securing Our Future                                              America, as part of which the GDP growth cost of the region's "exces-
sive" volatility (relative to industrial economies) is estimated at over 1
We hope this report will succeed in calling to the attention
percent per year. Empirical studies with a cross-regional focus include
of policymakers the problem  of economic insecurity in           Ramey and Ramey (1995) and Aizenmann and Marion (1993).
11



SECURING OUR FUT[ RE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 1.5
Economic Insecurity: Twelve Myths
MYTH                                       REALITY
1. Aggregate volatility has increased in LAC. Volatility of output and consumption is still much higher in LAC than in industrial countries, but it
appears to have declined in the 1990s in many of the economies in the region.
2. Workers in LAC face higher uncertainty  Microeconomic data show no conclusive pattern-likely a general improvement, but a possible
now than ever before.                   deterioration for some groups of workers in specific countries.
3. A greater demand for social insurance is    As countries become wealthier, demand for overall insurance may go up even if risk does not. Demand
unequivocal proof of greater economic risks. for insurance involving risk-pooling may rise even if overall risk declines.
4. Globalization means that countries are  Governments can do a lot to reduce volatility through policies such as trade diversification, comrnodity
powerless to reduce aggregare risk.     stabilization funds, precautionary fiscal targets, deepening of the financial sector, and strengthening bank-
ing systems.
5. Expanding global financial markets leave   IFls have a major role to play in the development of instruments and markets to facilitate international
no room for supranational action.       diversification of risks, and to ease the adjustment to shocks through countercyclical financing and
contingent credit lines.
6. The rise of democracy in the region has  Both autocratic and democratic governments in LAC reduce spending during economic downturrs.
not helped the poor much.               However, poverty-related programs have expanded much more under democratic governments.
7. Governments in the region have not been   Governments have not been successfiul at protecting social spending in downturns. In part the reason is that
pro-poor                                poverty-related programs may have grown too quickly in good times, to levels difficult to mainta.n in bad
times.
8. The poor are always hurt more than the  The poor are hurt more than the rich when economic contractions are deep and persistent. Moderate
rich during economic contractions,     fluctuations usually hurt the rich more than the poor, although even these smaller losses suffered by the
poor may be socially troublesome.
9. Poorer families respond to economic crises  The poor adiust co crises by trying to protecr their long-term interests to the excent thar their assets-
in ways that are harmful to their longer-   including human capital-permit. In particular, they do not pull their children out of school during
term well-being.                        contractions, except when the downturns are long or deep.
10. OECD-type unemployment insurance is    Countries that have raised growth and lowered unemployment through comprehensive economic reforms
unsuitable for all LAC economies.      should seriously consider these schemes; countries that are only beginning labor reform should view them
as a longer-term goal.
11. The informal sector is a safety net for  The intersecroral flow goes both ways. Informal sector workers often join the pool of the unemployed.
unemployed formal workers. Informal
workers never become unemployed.
12. Public works programs are just an      Public works programs should be viewed as insurance for informal sector workers, and should be
emergency device for times of crisis.   maintained in good times-but their nonlabor content should be strongly procyclical.
7. For example, regarding physical investment in developing             9. Much of this research was carried out in the context ofa World
countries, the adverse impact of uncertainity is documented by Servcn   Bank regional study on "Social Risk Management in Latin America,"
and Solimano (1993), Pindyck and Solimano (1993), Aizenmann and         conducted at the Office of the Chief Economist of the Latin Akmerica
Marion (1993), and Serven (1999).                                       and the Caribbean region under the supervision of Indermrir Gill.
8. It is worth noting that chis applies both to upturns and down-   Other major contributions ro this report include Rodrik (1999),
turns, and to recent years as well as the 1970s and 1980s.              Caballero (2000), and Snyder and Yackovlev (2000).
12



CHAPTER 2
Economic Insecurlty in Latin
America and the Caribbean:
The Stylized Facts
ATIN AMERICA SUFFERS FROM A HIGH DEGREE OF ECONOMIC VOLATILITY A HISTORY OF
repeated booms and busts has made economic insecurity a major concern for workers and house-
holds across the region, and especially for the poorer segments of the population, who are more
exposed to the consequences of income and employment variability.
Drawing on both macroeconomic and microeconomic information, this chapter sets the
stage for the analysis in the rest of the report by reviewing the major trends in economic volatility in Latin
America over the last three decades. The objective is to establish the facts concerning (a) Latin America's
performance over time and relative to the international experience in terms of aggregate volatility-that is,
the variability of key economic variables such as consumption and income; and (b) economic insecurity
from the perspective of individual workers and households-that is, the fluctuations in employment,
unemployment, and labor earnings.
Methodological Considerations
How does the economic risk faced by workers and households arise? The answer to this question provides
the organizing framework for this chapter. Here, risk may be measured by the variability of the real earn-
ings of employed workers; the level, incidence, and duration of unemployment; the rate of turnover in jobs
or, inversely, the average job tenure; and the quality or pre-   tions. Second, risk faced by households may arise from
cariousness of available jobs (a concept often related by   microeconomic or sectoral volatility-namely, such factors
observers to informality). In addition, the inequality of   as the changing allocation of resources across economic sec-
income distribution could be seen as a measure of the risk   tors and the rapid obsolescence of skills-unrelated to
of faring poorly relative to others in society. This deserves   aggregate disturbances (see Box 2.1). This chapter is orga-
mention here because increased inequality may lie behind    nized around the following three factors: aggregate risk,
the concern with economic insecurity that appears to have   the transmission of aggregate risk to households, and
spread across the region.                             microeconomic risk.
The risks faced by households arise from two sources.  Assessing Latin America's performance along these
First, they may reflect just aggregate volatility-itself due   three dimensions poses serious methodological challenges.
to external shocks from global goods or financial markets,   Beyond basic national income aggregates, there are few
volatile fiscal or monetary policies, and other factors. The   broadly available labor market and microeconomic indica-
speed and extent with which aggregate shocks are trans-   tors that permit comparisons across countries or that can
mitted to household income and employment outcomes   give a regional perspective on the key issues. Some, such as
depends on factors including the sensitivity of labor   unemployment rates, differ sharply in magnitudes in ways
demand to wages, and labor market policies and institu-   that suggest differences in data collection or definitions.
13



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
BOX 2.1 
Mning artdIf Zasuring hise*i~
In this report we extensively use terms such as economic   Strictly speaking, then, volatility and uncertainty are
inseurit, unertwint, variabiy, and voit  in theory,   not exactly synonymous: the former refers to the overall
these conepts are not identical, but in practice they are   variation of a variable, while the latter refers only to the
closely related.                                        unpredictable part of that variation. In practice, however,
the two usually go hand in hand: volatile variables are
Definitions                                             also had to predict. For this reason, this report focuses on 1
Economic insecurity refers to the uncertain environenet   measuring volatility as a tough approximation to uncer-
faced by workers and households due to erratic movements   tainty and insecurity.
in key economic quantities and prices, sch as empoy-
ment, income, and real wages, These variables change,   Measurement
sometimes abruptly, fom one month or year to the next,   How should volatility be measured? Idelly, we need some
and the ucertaity surrounding their fiture values is the    summry indicator of the extent and fequency with
essence of economic insecurity. In the economics literature,   which a variable teads to depart from its central trend. A
this is commonly referred to as unranty or r            nuber of such measures are available from statistical the-
It is impportant to distinguish between wo kinds of   ory, and in this report we use the standard deviation most
risks. Aggregte or ommon risks affect equally most or all eco-   often, which quantifies the extent to which a variable typ-
nomic actors. For example, the risk posed by fluctuations in   ically departs from its average or mean value. Since our
worldwide economic activity is common to all developing    variables of interest are in many cases expressed as per- i
countries, while that posed by fltuations in domestic eco-   centas, their standard deviation is also a percentage,
nomic activity is common to all workers agnd firms in the  While the standard deviation is the most commonly
national economy. In contrast, other risks are idda     used measure of dispersion, it iS by no means the only
(equivalently, microeconomc) or idhey afct only   one, ad other measures may be more apprpriate in spe-
specific individuals or particul groups of econoric acts.   cific contexts. For example, the coefficient of variation-
For example, fluctuating demand fbr swel is primarily a   defined as the standard deviation of a variable divided by
risk specific to the steel industry and its workers; uncerain   its mean-might be preferable when the mean and stan-
world cofee prices are a source of idiosyncratc risk for cof-   dard deviation tend to move together, as is usually the
fee-exporting countries but not for the rest.           case with variables that display rising or falling trends.
Vola       r variabilt-ers in turn to the varia-   Other "robust" measures (such as the interquartile range)
tion of a magnitude around some central tred (typicaly    may be superior in the presence of infrequent, large devi-
its average or median value), for exampe, the movement   ations of a variable from its central value. Using some of
of oil prices relative to their historical average. In some    these alternatives rather than the standard deviation to
cases, part of the variation of certain economic variables    measure volatility would change quantitatively some of
may be predictable; for example, prices of agricultural   the empirical findings in the report, but would leave
goods typically rise before the harvest and fal afterward.   them qualitaively unchanged.
Others, such as labor turnover, are available only for a few    economies. In our framework, households could face
countries. In many cases, therefore, the discussion has to be   increased risk due to larger aggregate shocks, strengthened
guided by what can be learned from a few case studies.   channels of transmission, higher microeconomic risks, or a
It is likewise difficult to identify the links between the    combination of all three. Reforms may have affected all
evolution of economic insecurity in Latin America over the   three of these ingredients, but disentangling their impact
last two decades and the process of economic and institu-   is no easy matter. In many dimensions, the postreform his-
tional reform  undergone by many of the region's   tory is too short to allow distinction between transitional
14



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
effects derived from intersectoral resource reallocation and    the volatility of GDP growth in the typical (median)
permanent impacts on economic volatility faced by house-    industrial country over the last four decades was just above
holds-a distinction that is critical for the design of social    2 percent. In contrast, it exceeded 4 percent in Latin Amer-
safety nets. Moreover, radical reform  policies are often    ica, higher than the levels seen in the most stable develop-
implemented along with stabilization measures, so that the    ing regions-the seven East Asian miracle economies and
permanent effects of the former are difficult to separate    South Asia. Sub-Saharan Africa (which comprises mainly
from the largely temporary consequences of the latter.          low-income economies), the Middle East, and North Africa
(largely consisting of oil-exporting economies whose per-
Aggregate Volatility in Latin America                           formance tracks closely the vagaries of world oil prices),
Like other developing regions, Latin America faces a high    and the rest of East Asia2 experienced even higher GDP
degree of volatility  of the major economic aggregates    growth volatility than Latin America.
related to national income, expenditure, and consumption.
Volatility in Aggregate Consumption
Volatility in Aggregate Output                                  Latin America also suffers high volatility in real private
Over the last four decades, the volatility of real output    consumption growth-an aggregate which provides a more
growth as measured by the standard deviation of the    accurate measure of the change in the standard of living of
growth rate of real GDP' in Latin America has been twice    the population of each region. Using the standard deviation
as high as in industrial economies. Figure 2.1 shows that    of consumption growth as the yardstick, Figure 2.2 shows
FIGURE 2.1
Long-Tenm Volatility of Real GDP Growth
9-
8       [   Population-weighted average
7 -   L     Region  median
6
3-
12 -           einlmda           
Industrial Economies  East Asia and   Latin America and  Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa  Other East Asia
Pacific 7     the Caribbean   North Africa                                      and Pacific
FIGURE 2.2
Long-Teffn Volatility of Real Private Consumption Growth
16 -
14 -      E   Population-weighted average
12 -       *   Regional median
10 
8 8
4
7
02
Industrial Economies  East Asia and    Latin America and  Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa  Other East Asia
Pacific 7     the Caribbean    North Africa                                     and Pacifit
1 5



SECURING OUJR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
that volatility in Latin America is three times higher than         TABLE 2.1
in industrial economies, well above the levels of South Asia        Long-Tenn Volatility in Latin America
and on par with those witnessed in the Middle East and              (Standard Deviations of Growth Rates, Percent)
North Africa.                                                                                                          PRIVATE
COUNTRY                       GDP              CONSUMPTION
Dfflerences in Volatility Across Countries Within                   Argentina*                     5.4                    5.5
Bolivia                       4.0                   2..7
the Region                                                          Brazil                         4.3                   'i.l
The LAC  region comprises a large number of different               Chile                          5.2                  11.5
economies, and  their respective performance from  the              Colombia                       2.4                   2.7
Costa Rica                    3.4
point of view  of economic volatility  has been equally             Dominican Republic             5.5                    ,.8
diverse (Table 2.1). The volatility of annual GDP growth            Ecuador                        4.8                   2. 7
has been highest in Nicaragua (with a standard deviation            Guatemala                      2.7                   62
exceeding 7 percent) and the Bahamas (8 percent), and               Haiti                          4.6                   4 5
lowest in Guatemala and Colombia (with standard devia-              Honduras                       3.0                   3.8
Jamaica                        4.6                  IC.I
tions around 2 percent). These two countries, along with            Mexico                         3.7                   4.0
Bolivia and Ecuador, the data of which do not yet reflect           Nicaragua                      7.5                  12.4
Panama                        4.6                   10.4
the 1999-2000 crisis, also possess the best record in terms         Paraguay                       3.7                   8.5
of long-term  stability of real private consumption growth.         Peru                           5.5                   6.3
At the other extreme, the largest variability in consump-           Trinidad and Tobago            5.6                   12.3
U ruguay                      4.2                    6.3
tion growth rates, in excess of 10 percent, was suffered by         Venezuela                      4.4                   5.2
several of the  smaller economies  in  the  region-the              Mean                           4.5                   6.5
Bahamas, Belize, Guyana, Nicaragua, and Trinidad and                Median                         4.6                   5.5
Tobago-as well as Chile.                                            Smaller countries
The regional and country experiences in Figures 2.1 and          Bahamas                        8l1                   1 8
Belize                        3.7                   11.8
2.2 and Table 2.1 illustrate three general points. First,    Barbados*                             4.6                   4.8
lower-income  economies  typically  suffer from   higher            Guyana                         5.8                  19.5
macroeconomic volatility. This is apparent from  the fact    Mean                                  5.5                  12.4
macroeconomic                                     ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Median     5.2                  12.6
that in all developing regions volatility is considerably
higher than in industrial economies. This largely reflects           Unueighted Average            4.6                    7.4
Overall median                4.6                   6. 3
the fact that lower-income economies often possess less             WeightedAverage55              4.2                   5.1
diversified  productive  structures  than  more  advanced           *Cf,sumprion figures for Argentina and Barbados correspond to mrat, and nor pei-
economies, which increases their exposure to risk; more-            vare, consumption. Argentina:1961-98; Barbados:1967-94.
*aWeigh,cd av-rages usc 1995 poplation.
over, once shocks happen, lower-income countries are less           Note: Sample Period: 1961-98. Exceptions: GDP: Bahamas (1961-95), Barbados
ablc to weather them  than richer countries, due to their    (1961-95), Guyana (1961-95), Peru (1966-99) Foe Argentina, Brazil, Chle, Colom-
bia, Ecuador, Peru, and Venezuela, figures are updated to 1999. For consuarnprion:
more limited access to external financing and their less-           Bahamas (1978-87); Barbados (1967).
developed domestic financial systems.
The second stylized fact, apparent from Table 2.1, is
that with few exceptions smaller economies tend to suffer              These two facts are summarized by Figures 2.3 and 2.4,
higher  volatility  than   bigger  economies.  Smaller    which plot the volatility of GDP growth against per capita
economies are typically much more open to trade than                income and country size (as measured by the logarithm  of
larger ones, and yet they cannot diversify their production         population) for a large number of countries. As can be seen,
as much as the latter. This makes them  more vulnerable to    in each case a negative relation emerges. It is worth noting
terms of trade shocks (Easterly and Kraay 1999). Moreover,    that for industrial countries actual volatility tends to fall
many of them  are located in regions prone to hurricanes            short of what could  be expected on the basis of their
and other natural disasters, as is the case of the Caribbean        income and size alone-that is, in the figures they tend to
subregion.                                                          cluster below the line of best fit.
16



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2 3
GDP Growth Volatility and Country Size
16
14                                                                         NC
12
C
g  10
Y                           ~~~          ~          ~        ~ ~       ~     ~~~~~BHS  #Q *MN*MW*CH
5)   8                                                                                                                                        * CNN
�    6  MLI  MDG                                           MWI
6N                                             GUY-  *TT                                         A SDTDM4,   OW
*o  CV     4 DN AC   AR,          IR
KWTB             *BEN   JAM       ALA     L  GAT EUL
ALRB                         A      PNA*CRD*  CAOGAU C  N IS       Ym EA
ISL   *LUX        *GAB       SGP+R                      My*  TC         L                              TUNAA K  *MYS  *CD  TEA  4 JPN
*IRL HND 4CHEGTM      *TWN  *EP A   EGY
A*NK SAEN tED ALA *CAN   *ITAA         OLKA
*NOR   GAA        4860    C0L  ABA
0                          I                        I                        I                        I
10                      12                       14                       16                       18                      20                       22
Log of Population (1995)
FIGURE 2.4
GDP Growth Volatility and Per Capita Income
0.16
0.14                                  MAR
0.12
N (;MR
0.1
>                             Bl DZA
0.08                                C               a                                a
S                                 E2NM~~~~~~~~~~~~~~WI  IEl NC              SE"N
A 0.06 -                                                    CLG            ADG  CA     F
0                                 *~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~A PE*  IT SNCG fl   NAW
KWT      MMFFJI 4GARE                           LSOECH
EN~~~~~~~~~~~ A
0.04 -EUORY                                                               EN NR   MENEB    A
Cs                  AMLwar                       UMAL                                KO
MSAU  AB MYS         *       OVEX   SDGP HEK                           AGRAC  J.PN
RM HND  CEGYIND     TNRIRL                     IAK ETWN           PETV
0.02                                            RLKA            Au        NAV OF       NCA                                                R IA
ROAGD     GMA        SAB AE  A                   A
4                    6                    8                   10                   12                   14                   16                   18
Log of Real Per Capita GDP
17



SECURING OUR Ft-TtJRE IN A GLOIBAL ECONOMY
These relationships between volatility and country size   industrial world, to protect their consumption fromf fluctua-
and volatility and per capita income are weak, however.   tions in income through mechanisms such as asset depletion,
Together, the latter two variables account for less than 10    borrowing, or countercyclical public sector policies. The
percent of the observed variation in volatility across coun-    result is that the impact of economic fluctuations on the wel-
tries, which implies that its causes have to be found else-   fare of households is likely much more severe in Latin Amer-
where. Indeed, Chapter 4 will show that the main roots of   ica and other developing regions than in OECD economies.
volatility lie in trade and financial shocks, policy volatility,
and underdeveloped financial systems. These factors account    Regional Trends in Economic Volatility
for the bulk of macroeconomic volatility and-once they are    World regions experienced marked changes in economic
taken into consideration-income level and country size are    volatility over the last four decades, and LAC has been no
no longer significantly associated with aggregate volatility.    exception (see Figure 2.6). In industrial countries (as well as
The third fact apparent from  the region and country    Sub-Saharan Africa), median GDP  and consumption
comparisons above is that in LAC, as in almost all develop-    growth volatility peaked in the 1970s, largely a reflection of
ing regions, the volatility of consumption is typically larger   the global impact of the oil shocks of the 1970s. In LAC, in
than that of income or production (this is the case in 21 of   turn, volatility increased further in the 1980s-as the debt
the 25 economies in Table 2.1). This is in contrast with    crisis and the ensuing macroeconomic and financial turmoil
more developed economies, where the volatility of con-   threw many of the region's economies into disarray. The rise
sumption growth is similar to or smaller than that of real   in the variability of macroeconomic aggregates was signifi-
income growth. This phenomenon is summarized by Figure    cant for LAC: the median standard deviation of real GDP
2.5, which presents volatility measures for both developing    growth rose from 3.5 percent in the 1970s to just under 5
and industrial countries. Industrial countries typically clus-    percent in the 1980s, while that of private consumption
ter on or above the 45-degree line along which private con-    growth rose to 6.1 percent, a level surpassed in that decade
sumprion and real GDP growth are equally volatile. Devel-    by only the low-income economies of Sub-Saharan Africa.
oping economies, however, tend to cluster below  the           In the 1990s, however, the rising trend in aggregate
45-degree line, reflecting their higher consumption volatil-    volatility in Latin America was partially reversed. Contrary
ity, and LAC economies are no exception to this rule.       perhaps to popular perception, the available information on
This regional contrast reflects the more limited ability of   GDP (that reaches up to 1999 for the region's largest
consumers in developing economies, relative to those in the    economies3) shows that the variability of real GDP growth
FIGURE 2.5
GDP Growth Volatility and Private Consumption Growth Volatility
16
a     Latin America and the Caribbean
,, 14 - |Industrial         Others
- 12
0 10
C                                                                                   x 
2 6
0 
0%,          2%            4%           6%            8%o          10%          12%           14%          16%
Standard Deviation of Private Consumption Growth
18



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2.6
Volatility of Real GDP Growth by Decade
(Regional Medians)
El  1960s        1980s
5      D   1970s       1990s
A: - |1      LII
2
Industrial     East Asia and    Latin America and   Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa   Other East Asia
Economies        Pacific 7      the Caribbean    North Africa                                        and Pacific
FIGURE 2.7
Volatility of Real Private Consumption Growth by Decade
(Regional Medians)
10 -_
9-       j  1960s        1980s
87-      D   1970s     1990s
7-
6-
5
4-
3-
2 
1                                                         ,l1 1  
0                                                                    T
Industrial      East Asia 7    Latin America and  Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa  Other East Asia
Economies                      the Caribbean     North Africa                                      and Pacific
declined substantially across the region, to levels comparable      It is worth emphasizing that this cycle of rising eco-
to (and in a number of countries, lower than) those witnessed    nomic instability followed by declining economic instabil-
in the 1970s. This decline in growth volatility was shared by    ity in Latin America is readily apparent in the macro-
other developing regions, with the major exception of the    economic data, and is not a result of the breakdown of the
East Asian miracle economies. In turn, the volatility of pri-    period of analysis into subperiods (decades) used here. The
vate consumption growth (on which data are only available    same pattern arises with alternative period definitions,4
though 1988) declined as well relative to the 1980s, but to    and even if annual rather than decade-based measures of
a more limited extent than that of GDP growth.                   volatility are used, as shown in Box 2.2.
19



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TheS  3 de linein      7 GDP gothii'x'S volatiity5  6'1g'in"6i th   1990  Regard 'in}8g privt  cosmto   grwh  pefomac
afece   moB E  lg} st glg contism in<�g o@the> regio  (2  ou  of the 25  wa  mor mied InS  a nube ofcutisih ein(
FI  SGUE 2.8
6o -
4....... #                                          4              Ii    L
3
2-------- p
0   3 -1--lC-                       3                                   l                          -   -  3        -  ------
g    g   03  i    3    i  W  '~~                                                              ~,,
The0 declin  in     7 GDPgrwt  voltiit  in8 the         2    194    1986Reard8n privat   conumpio   growt   performanc
affected most  countrie    s; in theregion (20 out of the 25        was more mixed. In a n           of countries in the region (1333Yea
shown in TableKR   2.2)QK3WX3  with the exception of ag.  fe,2�3 zw,     Caribbean  out of the 25 in Table 2.2),volatilitydecli
ecnme  (th  Doiia_eulc    at,adTiia                                  eaie  ote18s   u   oei   oeo   h ags
Th    eln   nGPgrowth volatility in the 1990s thanairtheng7 sraverae consumption voatliy               oasmuh, meroremodes
ecolatiet ofGothe DomiGnPcand PRiaepulc Conumtion ind LTrinia Am ricatv tohe18sburseisme ftelagt
(Ten-Year Window, Regional Median)
9-^--- rvt osmto ---w-................... -----. .-- 9---.-----  .----.----------.--  --..-<---w. .............  --   .- 
1970    197        197      197     198      18        92      18        96     188      19        92      19       96      19
Year
20



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN THE STYLIZED FACTS
TABLE 2.2
Volatility in Latin America Over Time
(Standard Deviations of Growth Rates by Decade, Percent)
GDP                                               PRIVATE CONSUMPTION
COUNTRY                          1960s          1970s          1980s          1990s         1960s           1970s          1980s          1990s
Argentina*                        5.4            4.3            5.6            5.5            4.3            5.2            5.9            5.7
Bolivia                           6.2            2.5            2.9            1.0            ..             ..             3.3            0.5
Brazil                            3.5            3,2            4.6            3.0            3.6            4.9            4.4            4.9
Chile                             2.5            6.7            6.4            3.5           12.0           16.8            9.4            3.4
Colombia                          1.4            1.7            1.5            3.3            4.1            1.8            1.2            1.9
Costa Rica                        3.1            1.9            4.5            2.4            4.5            3.7            6.1            3.2
Dominican Republic                8.8            4.4            2.7            4.4           10.8            6.7            4.5            8.7
Ecuador                           2.0            5.3            4.5            3.4            2.1            2.0            2.5            0.3
El Salvador                       2.8            3.1            5.7            1.9            4.2            6.3            6.0            6.9
Guatemala                         2.0            1.6            2.7            (.8            1.1            1.4            2.4            1.0
Honduras                          2.4            3.7            2.5            2.4            2.4            6.3            3.1            1.9
Haiti                             4.3            3.8            2.9            6.4            4.3            4.8            4.4
Jamaica                           2.3            7.1            4.3            2.2            3.9            9.5            7.6           16.5
Mexico                            2.4            2.1            4.4            3.6            1.9            1.8            4.9            5.1
Nicaragua                         3.3           12.2            5.4            2.3            4.9           11.7           15.8           14.4
Panama                            1.6            3.0            6.5            2.6            ..             ..            11.3           10.2
Paraguay                          2.3            2.3            5.3            1.5            3.8            4.5           11.2           12.5
Peru                              2.5            2.6            8.4            5.2            2.8            6.7            8.3            4.6
Trinidad and Tobago               3.5            4.8            5.7            6.8            6.6            8.7           14.0           17.6
Uruguay                           2.7            2.6            6.6            2.8            5.6            3.1            9.4            5.4
Venezuela                         3.3            2.8            4.8            5.0            ..             3.4            3.5            4.7
Mean                              3.3            3.9            4.7            3.3            4.6            5.8            6.6            6.5
Median                            2.7            3.1            4.6            3.0            4.1            4.9            5.9            5.0
Smaller countries
Bahamas                           0.8           12.9            5.7            1.8            ..            15.8            9.7
Belize                            0.8            3.5            5.8            3.0                                         16.1            4.9
Barbados*                         4.8            4.0            4.3            4.0                                          ..             4.8
Guyana                            7.0            4.1            5.2            4.2           30.3           12.4           19.5            8.6
Mean                              3.3            6.1            5.2            3.2           30.3           14.1           15.1            6.1
Median                            2.8            4.1            5.4            3.5           30.3           14.1           16.1            4.9
Unweighted Average                3.3            4.3            4.8           3.3             6.0           6.6             7.7            6.4
Overall median                    2.7            3.5            4.8            3.0            4.2            5.2            6.1            4.9
Weighted Average**                3.2            3.1            4.6            3.5            3.5            4.4            4.9            4.7
Notes: See Table 2.1. Decades are defined as 1961-69. 1970-79, 1980-89, 1990-99.Weighted averages use 1995 population.
than that in median consumption volatility. In over half                   goods demand to product prices and, as a result, also the
the  countries, consumption  volatility  remained  in  the                 sensitivity of labor demand to wages (see Rodrik  1997,
1990s above the levels of the 1960s and 1970s.                             for example). This would imply that any given aggregate
shock would lead to larger movements in wages or
Transmission of Aggregate Volatility to the Labor                          employment than previously. Estimates of labor demand
Market                                                                     equations for Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and
Even  if aggregate  volatility  had  remained  unchanged,                  Uruguay, however, do not suggest that this has been a
reform  and stabilization measures may have led to tighter                 strong effect to date.' As an example, Figure 2.10 plots
linkages between macroeconomic shocks and labor markets                    the  own  wage  elasticities  for blue- and  white-collar
through multiple channels, some of which appear on the                     workers  for  Chile  during   1980-1995,  a  period  of
left-hand side of Figure 2.9.                                              increased protection (1984-87) and then increasing inte-
Increased product competition brought about by mar-                     gration. Although  the series is volatile, neither casual
ket-oriented  reforms  may  increase  the  sensitivity  of                 observation  nor  statistical  tests  suggest  any  trend
21



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 2.9                                                  when economic conditions demand it. Recent research on
The Links Between Aggregate and Microeconomic Volatility    labor market reform suggests that government-mandated
reductions in firing costs had a negligible impact on labor
Macro Volatility              Global Integration     demand in Brazil, Colombia, Peru, and Uruguay, but did
reduce tenure to a greater or lesser degree.6 Though in all
cases overall employment may rise as a result of these
Channels of Communication   Channels of Communication     reforms, workers may be more exposed to layoffs than pre-
Labor Demand Elasiciries    Technological Change          viously. The ambiguous impact on risk also arises From the
Labor Market Reform         Direct Investment Flows       diminished power of labor unions that has occurred either
Inflation Reduction
because of greater competition or the political evoLution of
the 1970s and 1980s. Weaker collective bargaining in
Uruguay, for example, is associated with lower unemploy-
ment, but also more wage volatility and higher labor
Measures of Risk                       demand elasticities than in the past (Allen, Cassoni, and
-Wage Volarility                       Labadie 1997; Cassoni 1999).
-Unemployment                             The successful fight against high inflation rates in the
-Turnover
-Informaliry                            region, and the resulting reduction in the ability to adjust
-Distributicn                          real wages through inflation, have led labor markets to
adjust through employment instead. Given the absence of
unemployment insurance in most countries, workers may
increase during the period of study (see Fajnzylber and    feel more at risk, even if the shocks to labor demand are no
Maloney 2000).                                              larger than before. Figure 2.11 suggests an inverse relation
Trade liberalization, and the labor market reform mea-    between how much real wages fall with a shock to CGDP and
sures thought to be a necessary complement to it, have    how much unemployment rises with the same GDP shock
loosened the relationship between firm and employee. To    (Gonzalez 1999). Studying the impact over the last 20 years
start, in a highly competitive environment, the traditional    reveals ambiguous although broadly similar results. As
promise of a lifetime labor contract is simply less realistic   inflation falls, Argentina, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela do
than in the past. More generally, competing firms need    appear to adjust less through wages, but only Colombia and
greater flexibility to reallocate or reduce their work forces    Mexico adjust more through unemployment as predicted.
FIGURE 2. 10
Long-Run Own Wage Elasticities, 1980-95, Chile
0.7 -
-    Blue Collar
0.6-
-.6  -<  White Collar
0.2 -     /\
0.1
0
1982   1983   1984   1985   1986   1987   1988   1989   1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1)95
22



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2.11
Wage and Unemployment Okun Coefficients
2.50 -
*Bolivia
* Mexico
2.00                                                                                          n
f
Peru
< 1.50                                                                                            U
* Paraguay           * Costa Rica                                                  t
:  1.00 -             *Argentina            * Uruguay
O                             Brazil         Venezuela
0.50 *-                                        * 
Chile             UNITED STATES
* Panama
0.00 - 
Colombia
-0.50-
0.00                     0.20                     0.40                     o.60                      0.80
Unemployment Okun Coefficients
Brazil, Bolivia, and Uruguay show either counterintuitive    tion of the inflationary surge experienced by many Latin
or insignificant coefficients (Galindo and Maloney 2000).  American economies in the 1980s, which resulted in a gen-
Finally, as depicted by the right side of Figure 2.9, the    eralized rise in the variability of real wages during that
general reduction in global barriers to direct foreign    decade, followed by a decline derived from the success of
investmenr may also make it easier for foreign investors to   inflation stabilization. As a result, in the 1990s real wage
relocate production in response to modest movements in    volatility was broadly similar to, or even lower than, in the
wages.7 There is ample anecdotal evidence of such footloose    1970s. The decline in the variability of real wages in the
industries, particularly in Central America, though the    1990s was particularly marked in Argentina, Bolivia, and
findings of research on firm entry and exit behavior in    Chile. Brazil and Peru also witnessed a substantial decline
Chile and Colombia are ambiguous.8 More generally, being    in wage volatility, although its average level in the 1990s
more tightly linked to the process of technological advance    was still high, reflecting the persistence of inflation in the
may create more dynamic industrial sectors in the region,   early years of the decade.
but also require workers to retrain and find new jobs more   It could be possible, however, that individual workers
frequently.                                               face higher idiosyncratic wage risk than disappears in
aggregation. Calculating the variance of individual wages
Are Latin American Workers Facing More Risk?               across a year from  panel labor force data, Arango and
Despite the falling trend in macroeconomic volatility, the    Maloney (2000a) find no trend in Mexico since 1987, and
mixed evidence on changes in transmission mechanisms,   a downward trend in Argentina, consistent with the aggre-
and the possibility of direct microlinkages, the question    gate data above. Since workers may be particularly con-
remains as to whether, overall, workers are facing more risk    cerned about negative shocks, Figure 2.12 transforms the
than in the past.                                         changes (by taking the squared values), but again does not
reveal a worsening trend. In Mexico, the size of negative
Cbanges in Earnings Volatility                            shocks for skilled workers rose and then fell. In Argentina
Wage or earnings volatility captures a central dimension of   it is difficult to tell because of cyclical fluctuations, but
income volatility. At the aggregate level, Table 2.3 pre-   there appears to be an upward trend.
sents this information for 14 countries in the region. The   Still, it may happen that even if income shocks for the
cycle of rise and fall in volatility tracks closely that found    mean or median worker change little or not at all, workers
in the macroeconomic aggregates. This is mainly a reflec-    could be more exposed to large catastrophic shocks that
23



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 2.3                                                        (see Figure 2.13). This evidence suggests that workers are
Real Wage Growth Volatility in Latin America and the Caribbean,  not being hit particularly harder by catastrophic shocks
Percent                                                          than prior to the reforms.
ENTIRE
COUNTRY        1970s        1980s       1990s       PERIOD       Trends in Unemployment Rates
Argentina      15.8         15.0         2.1         12.2        In sum, workers are not facing higher volatility in real
Bolivia        14.5         31.9         3.9         20.3
Brazil          8.7         26.2        10.2         16.8        wages. However, as suggested above, this may only reflect
Chile          20.6          6.0          1.1        12.0        a new reality in that, because of a fall in inflation without
Colombia        6.7          3.1         2.5          3.9        deep reforms of labor market institutions, adjustments
Costa Rica      6.9         16.3         3.3         11.2
Ecuador         6.1         10.7         6.4          8.6        occur largely  through  fluctuations in  unemployment.
El Salvador     7.1         14.1        13.0         11.7        Since, in the absence of insurance, unemployment implies
Guyana          5.9         15.4        13.3         11.8
Mexico          3.2         10.2         7.9          8.1        a catastrophic fall in income, this is clearly a central
Paraguay        4.3          5.1         6.6          5.1        dimension of the risk that workers face. Table 2.4 presents
Peru (CEPAL)    7.0         23.5         9.3         16.1        decade averages of the unemployment rate for 1]3 Latin
Peru (1IL0)    11.2         28.9        10.2         19.3
Uruguay         6.4          9.1         4.3          7.5        American economies. The trend that the table reveals is
Venezuela       3.3          6.2        10.6          8.0        broadly similar to that already identified from the macro-
LAC Mean        8.5         14.8         7.0         11.5        economic aggregates. Unemployment rates rose in the
LAC Median      6.9         14.1         6.6         11.7        1980s in almost all the countries in the table, with the
exception of only Brazil and Mexico. In the 1990s, how-
such measures will miss. One way to rectify this is to exam-    ever, the rise was partially reversed: average unemployment
ine changes in the shape of the full distribution of income    declined in 7 out of 13 economies, although it did increase
shocks, and not just those at some average such as the    in some major economies such as Argentina.
median. When we examine the 25th quantile (the point at             The net result is that in the 1990s average unemploy-
which 25 percent of income shocks are lower and 75 per-    ment rates still remained above the levels of the 1970s in
cent higher), we find trends similar to those found at the       7 of 12  economies. The  increase was substantial in
median for Mexico, and no significant trend in Argentina         Argentina, Paraguay, and Venezuela, and  the dlata for
FIGURE 2 12
White- and Blue-Collar Wage Volatility, Mexico
0 High Schooling                                           a Low Schooling
.8   -
.6                                                                 0
C3                 C2 0                                013
.4 -
0                                                                                 O
o~~~~~
.2                                                                                        o
0                          10                          20                           30                          40
Cohort
Annual Log Differences of Real Wages Squared
24



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2.1 
White- and Blue-Collar Wage Volatility, Argentina
O  High Schooling                                        A  Low Schooling
.2
0
.15
.1-
0
0~ ~ ~~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~
934         939         944         949        954          959        964        969          974          979
Cohort
Annual Log Differences Df Real Wages Squared
Colombia and Uruguay conceal falls in the early 1990s that    Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, and Uruguay experienced his-
were dramatically reversed by the end of the decade: booms    torically unusual periods of growth with limited formal
in  the  nontradables sector, particularly  construction,    sector employment creation.9 This is especially striking in
absorbed labor and partially obscured the dislocations in    Uruguay in the late 1990s, where unemployment was at
the restructuring tradables sector. The end of these booms    levels similar to those of the debt crisis years in the early
both displaced workers, and revealed the higher industrial    1980s, despite apparently healthy economic growth.
sector unemployment. More generally-and perhaps cen-               Behind these numbers lie numerous phenomena that are
tral to the stated feeling of insecurity in the region-    fundamentally transitory: the dislocations due to industrial
TABLE 2 4                                                       restructuring, the temporary real exchange rate overvalua-
Average Unemployment Rates in Latin America and the             tions accompanying necessary stabilization plans, contam-
Cadbbean, Percent                                               ination effects from  the Tequila, Asian, and Brazilian
crises, and in Colombia's case, a rise in rural violence. Nei-
ENTIRE
COUNTRY        1970s       1980s        1990s       PERIOD      ther theory, nor the experiences of the Asian newly indus-
Argentina       4.1         4.8         12.3          6.9       trialized countries and of Chile suggest that openness
Bolivia         6.3         7.7          4.8          6.3       implies higher long-term  rates of unemployment. How-
Brazil          6.6          5.4         5.4          5ever, lower inflation rates may imply more frequent adjust-
Chile          10.5         14.4         7.0         1037
Colombia        9.6         11.3        10.7         10.6       ment through quantities that push up unemployment rates
Costa Rica      5.0         6.9          5.3          5.9       during downturns, and hence imply more risk for workers.
Guyana          0.5         0.3          n.a.         0.4
Honduras        n.a.        4.5          3.4          3.7          In addition, the nature of unemployment may change
Mexico          7.0         47           3.8          5.0       even if the level stays the same-either a higher propensity
Paraguay        7.3         11.8        14.2         10.7       to become unemployed or longer unemployment spells
Peru            7.4          7.4         8.5          7.7
Uruguay         9.2        10.6          9.8          9.9       may be interpreted as riskier by workers. Neither effect
Venezuela       5.7         8.8          9.7          8.0       enjoys strong empirical support. Probit analysis using the
LAC Mean        6.6          7.6         7.9          7.0       Argentine and Mexican panel data, for example, does not
LAC Median      6.8          7.4         7.8          6.9       suggest secular increases in the probability of becoming
25



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
unemployed. In both countries, skilled workers in non-    related with rising unemployment, which makes it diffi-
tradable or protected sectors show lower probabilities of    cult to postulate a permanent movement. Further, in Chile,
becoming unemployed, but also more difficulty in being    the duration of unemployment increases during  the
rehired after job loss. Colombia shows more substantial    restructuring period, but then falls essentially to its 1960s
swings in hiring and firing with given movements in GDP,    levels (Figure 2.16a)."
and exit rates out of employment and unemployment rose by
1 percent (Kugler 1999).                                      Changes in Turnover Rates
Neither Mexican nor Brazilian panel data suggest an    More generally, turnover among jobs, while a necessary
increase in duration across the 1990s. However, using    byproduct of the creative destruction that offers new
aggregate labor flow data, Figures 2.14 and 2.15 suggest a    opportunities to some workers, may also represent more
possible rise in duration of unemployment in the interior    uncertainty for others. As Table 2.5 shows, turniover is
of Uruguay'" relative to the early 1990s, and maybe a rise    higher (or the length of tenure lower) in LAC countries
in Montevideo. However, duration is always inversely cor-    compared to OECD countries. However, turnover depends
FIGURE 2.14
Unemployment Rate and Expected Duration, Montevideo
18.0 -
_    Unemployment (                                                    _
L4.0- 4 + ~~~~~~~~~~Duration (months)
14.0-
10.0-
6.0-
2.0-
1982  1983  1984  1985  1986  1987  1988  1989  1990  1991  1992  1993  1994  1995  1996  1997  1998
FIGURE 2.15
Unemployment Rate and Expected Duration, Interior Uruguay
14 -
1    Unemployment (X)|
| + Duration (months)                        
6
2
1986     1987     1988      1989     1990     1991      1992     1993      1994     1995     1996      1997     1998
26



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2.16A
Unemployment Rate and Expected Duraton, Greater Santiago
a rate                                                A  length
22.2 -0
a
a
1962                 1969               1975                 1982             1987      1990          1995
Year
on education, per capita income, and other demographic/   Mexico, tradables industries show  higher rates of
growth variables. Thus, for example, younger workers   turnover in Chile (Levensohn 1999). This suggests that,
change jobs more frequently, and lower levels of education    to the degree that trade liberalization expands the share
can imply lower levels of firm specific capital, and hence    of tradables in total output, it may lead to more churning
higher voluntary separations. In fact, in Mexican enterprise    in the job market.
surveys, over 80 percent of separations were reported to be    The aggregate labor flows data do find evidence of
quits, not fires (Maloney 1999; Maloney and Ribeiro    decreasing tenure in Uruguay (Figures 2.19 and 2.20).
1999). As Figure 2.16b suggests, once we adjust for these    However, these movements again parallel the sharp rise in
factors, the region does not show "conditionally" higher    unemployment, and therefore it is difficult to argue that
turnover. 12                                                they are permnanent: a sharp reduction in tenure also
However, a finding of increased turnover across the    appeared during the 1973-87 restructuring period in
period of liberalization may imply increased risk. But, as    Chile that, by 1995, had largely although not completely
in the industrial country literature, there is only mixed    reversed (Figure 2.21).
evidence that either greater trade liberalization or expo-
sure to technological change leads to greater turnover pRise in Informality
overall, beyond that discussed on the impact of firing COSt    Even if all the above indicators of stability and employ-
reductions mentioned earlier.23 Figures  2.17 and 2.18    ment showed no change, there is a concern that the quality
plot the evolution of turnover in the manufacturing sec-    of jobs available has fallen. In particular, the share of work-
tor  in Colombia during  1980-91, and Chile during    ers unprotected by labor legislation or benefits has risen as
1980-95, in both countries periods of increased trade    apshare ofLatin America's workforce.International Labour
protection and then may 'impyincr4 Disaggregated  into    Organisation and Inter-Ad rerican Development Bank
turnover due to birth and death of firms (BD) and    studies suggest that 80 out of 100 jobs created in the
turnover due to readjustments by continuing   firms    1990s were in the informal sector, and the Economic Com-
(Cont), there is no obvious pattern across time in either    mission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC)
country (Fainzylber, Ribeiro, and Maloney 2000). How-    reports thao the share of informal employment in the work-
ever, as with involuntary separations in Argentina and    force rose from 52 percent in 1990 to 58 percent in 1997.
27



SLCURLNG OUR FLTUltE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 2.5
Labor Turnover, LAC and OECD Countries
LAC            OECD
9 < 2 Years Seniority (Manufactures)         38.1            24.5
Average Tenure (ManufactuLres)               7.61            10.5
SoR-c Maloney (I 999b).
FIGURE 2. 16B
Labor Turnover, LAC and OECD Countries
.1                                                   Ven
(re
Ita
E 05                                      -Spr
Fin Bel
E
IlUK            Swit                             Lux
v)   0                                                              Ger                            Fou         P.,
AuHon Net  Pan              Fra
Den           Aui          S       n                                                               Jap
-.05
Bra
-.1
-4                            -2                              0                              2                            4
Adjusted Mean Tenure
Seouce. Maloney 1999b.
FIGURE 2.17
Evolution of Turnover in Chile, 1980-95
0 Total                                                           A  New and Dying Firms
E] Continuing Firms
0.31
0.04
1980                                                    Year                                                             1995
Chile: Gross Job Reallocation
28



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2.18
Evolution of Turnover in Colombia, 198I91
0 Total                                            A New and Dlying Firms
0 Continuing Firms
0.28
0.07
1980                                            Year                                                1991
Colombia: Gross job Reallocation
Some subtlety is necessary in interpreting these trends.   from 18 percent to 22 percent from 1987 to 1990 in Mex-
Recent work at the World Bank suggests that the conven-    ico, and 23 percent to 27 percent from  1988 to 1993 in
tional view of the sector as a residual for displaced formal    Argentina, at the same time that the premium  self-
sector workers is probably incomplete. In many ways infor-    employment enjoyed over formal salaried work rose from 0
mal self-employment behaves more like an unregulated    percent to 25 percent and 4 percent to 13 percent, respec-
entrepreneurial sector where, as in industrial countries, the    tively. The expansion of the sector makes sense if we
risks of entrepreneurship and lack of protection under indi-    believe that entrepreneurs prefer good times, such as the
vidual labor codes are voluntarily taken on (see Box 2.3).'5    construction booms in both countries, to start new busi-
After economic reforms, for example, informal self-    nesses.16 This is fully consistent with interview data from
employment as a share of the work force rose procyclically    both countries that suggest that roughly 70 percent choose
FIGURE 2.19
Expected Tenure in Current Job, Montevideo (Monthsl
110 -
90 
70 
30- -                                        l
1982                1985                 1988                 1991                1994                 1997
29



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 2.20
Expected Tenure in Current Job, Interior Uruguay (Months)
110 --
90 -.
70 
50 
30O-
1986                     1989                     1992                      1995                     1998
FIGURE 2.21
Expected Tenure on Job, Greater Santiago
89.7  -         0
0
ar a
a~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~l
ao                                                                                  a
n~~~~~~~~
00~~~~~~~~ \                 OX
34  -                                                          O
1962                1969                1975             1982          1987    1990         1995
Year
to be in the sector for reasons of independence and higher   share in self-employment, most of which is unprotected,
earnings, and are not looking for other jobs (Arango and   is no higher than that of OECD  countries or other
Maloney 2000).                                           regions.
This also suggests that the strong negative relation-    But developments in the sector in the later 1990s may
ship between formal sector productivity and the share of   also reflect undesirable increases in uncertainty. Informal
the workforce in self-employment (Figure 2.22) is due to   self-employment shows countercyclical behavior in Uruguay
the growing attractiveness of salaried jobs relative to self-   and perhaps in Peru and Mexico after 1992.17 Further, there
employment over the course of development. When   is a secular increase in the share of informal salaried workers
adjusted for income and other demographic variables,   in Mexico after 1992, and in Argentina and Uruguay after
Figure 2.16b again suggests that the LAC region's labor    1995, at the same time that their relative incomes were
30



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
turnover, only time will tell whether these are permanent
WhyVWluer5RflobesPN ftrb*sPtwo.*se~w~                  increases or related to the low rates of job creation and high
rates of unemployment experienced during restructuring.
It isX atmions!-formay Xwores tO desire to be 'tupro-
cetd if .te,ON S4          the pvided,bee   ass        The Deterioration in Prospects of Older Workers
much as te implicit taxt iidfo them. Worhebea-         Much of the reported dissatisfaction in the region may be due
efis are financed either hrogh explt taxes on work-    to workers laid off in the restructuring process and who have
ea, o implicty as lower waes. leficenldy povied        suffered substantial falls in income, or are experiencing diffi-
beriehw-poor medical sen!     a social security sys-   culty finding jobs. The privatization process has led to a fall
em  see as haxkmpt and unliable, or an unemploy-       in often privileged jobs in public employment from 15 per-
meat ntsurtce syem substtially di&iren from one        cent of the labor force in 1990 to 13 percent in 1998. More
workers wouldchose7-provid incentives,for woifers      generally, restructuring of the private sector, both in tradables
toIworkoff thn book. In his intervies with workers in  and nontradables, may have had the same effect. Studies find
Guda         ec, Robens (1989) 6nds that, "Many        an increase in subcontracting across the period that could be
infrmmns cited the deidutio  made for welfre as a      due to restructuring of firms where they now put their clean-
disadvantage offorml employmet, parictia.ly since.    ing and security services out to unprotected employees. Mex-
the servicedey Vceived were poor." In addition to      ico, for example, experienced a once-and-for-all 3 percentage
avidingonlP  izaxs and regtlation, inornm  work-       point increase in the share of the workforce in subcontracting
e   may he      d            ent "protection" (see.    in the mid-1990s. This was accompanied by a fall in relative
Amade, Glt and Neri (2000  adal.oey (19:.              incomes that suggests a deterioration in "job quality."
Older displaced workers may be particularly affected by
their inability to requalify themselves or by the unwilling-
falling. Uruguay also experienced a rise in what workers   ness of firms to employ them. While in both the formal
termed "unstable employment" during the 1990s.           and informal sectors, workers with primary education
In sum, there is evidence of an increase in uncovered    gained during the 1990s in Argentina, Brazil, and Costa
work in the region that may imply a degree of lack of pro-   Rica relative to those with more schooling, there are two
tection for a segment of the workforce. As with falls in job    notable exceptions in the case of Argentina (Arias 1999 in
FIGURE 2.22
Self-Employment versus Industrial Productiviy, OECD and LAC
.461                                Peru
Bot
EIS
Col          Ven
Hon Gua Par                 Uru
Arg    Gre
Pan   Chi MehFurk
CBr          Kor         Ita
Por
Spa
New        Ice
Ire   A6901
576 -NbN
I       I                 l        ~        ~~                ~~~~ II
6.63332                     Log of Industrial V.A./Worker             10.5322
31



SECURING OUJR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Cunningham and Artecona 2000). The first is that of those   is mixed. In Argentina (1988-97) and Brazil (1989-95)-
starting new informal businesses; many are older workers   both  liberalizing  economies-and  in  Costa  Rica
displaced from previous jobs. The second group is older   (1989-95), the gap between educated and primary school
informal sector workers who may have lost their market   workers declined, especially for women. Further, Chile, the
niche; repairing, for example, domestically produced cars   bellwether country for the region, experienced a harsh
or working in small print shops due to imports of new cars   deterioration in wage dispersion in the late 1980s, but a
and technologies. In Peru in the 1990s, older workers   reversal in the 1990s as returns to higher education fell to
experienced an increased probability of becoming informal   historically normal levels.'9
due to reduced restrictions on firing workers, and in both  What has not been carefully studied to date is whether,
Argentina and Uruguay, older workers suffered from    despite relatively constant inequality measures, there may
lengthening spells of unemployment.'8 In the bottom    be more movement of individuals within the distribution.
income quintile  group, the share of unemployed    Thus, for example, there may be increased earnings mobil-
Uruguayan workers over 40 years of age with unemploy-   ity or-looking at the other side of the coin-greater risk,
ment duration of over a year rose from 28 percent during    as a more open economy generates job opportunities in new
1982-86 to about 40 percent during 1999-2000, a period    industries and causes other industries to close. Box 2.4
with similar aggregate unemployment rates. In sum, for a   suggests that this probably is not the case in Argentina or
sizable segment of older displaced workers, the loss in    Mexico across their periods of trade liberalization: there
value of their human capital may have been substantial.  was little or no trend increase in labor income miobility
To a lesser degree, these difficult adjustments for mature   during the 1990s. What does emerge is that adjustment to
workers are likely to become a permanent feature of the    crises through unemployment exacerbated by wage rigid-
postreform landscape in Latin America. In the industrial   ity in Argentina leads to greater downward mobility than
countries, the rapid pace of innovation is thought to   adjustment through real wages in Mexico made possible by
require that workers retrain more than once during their   leaving the exchange rate peg. A generalized fall in wages
lifetime. The design of training and pension programs will  leaves the relative positions of individuals in the income
need to reflect this reality.                           distribution the same, whereas unemployment expeEienced
by a few radically changes their position.
Changes in Income Distribution
It is also possible that it is not uncertainty per se, but   Conclusion
changes in income distribution, that are creating the per-   As in other developing regions, macroeconomic volatility is
ception of insecurity. In broad terms, inequality increased    high in LAC, and this translates into volatility in aggregate
during the 1990s (see Table 2.6), though there is a wide    wage measures and unemployment rates. In most countries
range of country experience. Inequality in Brazil and Mex-   in the region growth volatility is lower today than it was in
ico increased between 1986 and 1989 before leveling off or   the 1980s, and major labor market aggregates, particularly
decreasing until the late 1990s. Chile and Paraguay expe-   wage volatility, and to a lesser extent unemployment,
rienced increasing inequality, although in Chile the low    appear to follow this trend. The evidence is mixed, however,
baseline for 1986 may compromise comparability. In   on whether volatility has become higher today than it was
Argentina, Colombia, Ecuador, Uruguay, and Venezuela   in the relatively normal 1970s, because the 1980s are
inequality has been relatively stable, with some indexes   rightly viewed as an unusually turbulent decade.
suggesting an increase, others a decrease. And in Bolivia,  What may be a central issue is the slow rate of job
the Dominican Republic, and Honduras there is a decrease   growth that has coexisted for relatively long periods with
in inequality over time. Overall, from  the aggregate   healthy economic growth rates, most clearly in Argentina,
indexes, it would be hard to argue that opening the econ-   Colombia, Mexico, and Uruguay. This phenomenon is
omy, as in Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, and Mexico, led to   associated with lower job tenure, higher unemployment
a permanent worsening of aggregate inequality.          duration, growing levels of informality and insecure jobs,
The ILO and ECLAC find evidence of increased wage    and difficulty of reinsertion of laid-off older workers. 'raken
dispersion throughout the region, but again, the evidence   together, these developments suggest that employrnent-
32



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
TABLE 2.6
Income Inequality Measures by Country, 1986-96
THEIL            GINI          ATKINSON                           THEIL             GINI         ATKINSON
Argentina                                                         Ecuador
1986               0.51             0.50            0.68          1986                0.47            0.49            0.46
1989               0.68             0.58            0.73          1989                0.36            0.44             0.33
1992               0.48             0.51            0.65          1992                0.48            0.50             0.44
1995               0.52             0.52            0.61          1995                0.53            0.51             0.46
1996               0.53             0.53            0.64          1996                0.50            0.51             0.54
Bolivia                                                           Honduras
1986               0.56             0.54            0.60          1986                0.64            0.59            0.62
1989               0.76             0.63            0.64          1989                0.8              0.6             0.58
1992               0.49             0.50            0.41          1992                0.63            0.57             0.58
1995               0.58             0.53            0.41          1995                0.67            0.58            0.57
1996               0.52             0.51            0.40          1996                0.62            0.55            0.53
Brazil                                                            Mexico
1986               0.74             0.59            0.52          1984                0.42            0.47             0.33
1989               0.89             0.64            0.59          1989                0.61            0.52             0.39
1992               0.71             0.59            0.59          1992                0.56            0.53             0.39
1995               0.74             0.61            0.59          1994                0.58            0.53             0.39
1996               0.75             0.61            o.60          1996                0.55            0.52             0.38
Chile                                                             Paraguay
1986               0.36             0.44            0.30          1986                0.41            0.47             0.33
1989               0.83             0.59            0.46          1989                0.32            0.43             0.27
1992               0.58             0.53            0.43          1992                0.35            0.44             0.34
1995               0.75             0.57            0.47          1995                0.45            0.49             0.35
1996               0.83             0.58            0.47          1996                0.47            0.47             0.32
Colombia                                                          Uruguay
1986               0.64             0.57            0.68          1981                0.35            0.43             0.29
1989               0.55             0.54            0.54          1989                0.36            0.42             0.27
1992               0.63             0.57            0.67          1992                0.33            0.42             0.27
1995               0.75             0.56            0.57          1995                0.33            0.43             0.29
1996               0.69             0.56            0.58          1996                0.35            0.44             0.30
Dominican Republic                                                Venezuela
1986               0.53             0.53            0.66          1986                0.49            0.50             0.57
1989               0.53             0.52            0.43          1989                0.41            0.47             0.51
1992               0.54             0.51            0.41          1992                0.38            o.46             0.49
1995               0.62             0.55            0.62          1995                0.43            0.48             0.40
1996               0.42             0.48            0.35          1996                0.48            0.50             0.47
Soure: Wodon (2000).
related uncertainty might have risen in some countries in    low-inflation environment leaves workers exposed to both
the region, and this may he a factor in the perceptions of    catastrophic falls in income against which they are not well
economic insecurity alluded to in Chapter 1. It is difficult    insured, and downward mobility relative to the rest of soci-
to establish whether these and other adverse developments    ety. The growing infeasibility of lifetime labor contracts in
documented here represent a permanent rise in economic    the face of global competition, labor market reforms that
risks faced by workers and households, or are merely the           reduce firing costs, and weakening union power, all have led
transitional costs of the extensive restructuring and stabi-    to higher turnover rates. Workers in more exposed tradables
lization policies implemented in the 1990s.                        sectors face higher probabilities of displacement, more
However, even if these developments are transitory, and        turnover, and more wage volatility than in the past. How-
if aggregate volatility were to remain unchanged, there is    ever, the data do not suggest that such risks affect the labor
some evidence that the magnitude of labor market risk may    force as a whole. In addition, they are likely to be higher in
have risen-or its form  may have changed-for certain    the short term, while the economy completes its adjust-
groups of workers. The need to adjust to shocks through            ment to the increased role of global market forces, than in
unemployment rather than through falling real wages in a    the long term.
33



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Income Mobility and Risk In Two Counties
linome mobility can be used as a measure of risk which    * MoiiW   is negatively Associated with growth in
takes into accowt not only the abslue level of income      Argentina, and positively associated with growtin
of individush, but also their ranking in the ovealldis-    Mexico. The positive correlation in Mexico is as
tribution of income; that is, their relative deprivation.  expect  in tha growth provides opporunities, mda
Figures 2.23 and 2.24 give the trend in the Gini index of  thu results in a more dynaric and mobile labor market.
labor income mobility for adult men in Argentina and       The negative corlion in Argentiam may be due to the
exico using panel data. The main findtings are:           fiat that the Agentine labor marker adjusts to shocks
b* Laor income mobility as measured by this index is       throuh quantes (unemployment) ather than prices
high in both countries at about 0.3 in Mexico and 0.4   (rea wages). In Mexico, adjusnments tale place through 
in Atgentina. It is higher in Argentina, in part         prc. Employmen losses rst in more rerankis in
because the length of time separating observations fr    the distribution of income, and therefre higher mobil|
the individuals in the panels is greater (a s ster ver-  ity than we losses. The difrences betwveen Agentina
sus a quaer). k both countries, the level of mobility    and Mexico ma alterativey or additionally be due to
suggests that traditional one-period measures of         dirent exchange re regimes, with pegged exchange
inequality areoverestimated. The resuls also suest       rates leading to employment losses, while flexible
that short-tem  safty nets should help to offset fre-    exchange rates lead to real wages losses.
quent income losses.                                  * Finally, althoug  this is not shown in Fiures 2.23
* There is no trend toward highet or lower mobility        and 2.24, it can be shown that income mobility is
over tine. That is, contrary to what popular beliefs     associaed with individual-level charaeristics such as
would suest, the resuls do not suggest a large           age (the young are more mobile) and education (the
increase in risk over timne.                             less eduated are more mobile, at least in Mexico).
FIGURE 2.23
Growth and Income Mobility in Argentina
0.6 -
0.4 5
' 0.3 -___                                                        _   ___
a   0.2   -                                 -
0. 
0 -
-0.1I  - - . - - -  -    -  -    - -_ _                                   __               _
-0.2_-             I              I 
93-2          94-1          94-2           95-1          95-2           96-1          96-2
Year
34



ECONOMIC INSECURITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: THE STYLIZED FACTS
FIGURE 2.24
Growth and Income Mobility in Mexico
0.55 -
0.45                            -      Mobility
A       ~~~- Growth
-0.25
-o 015-
0.05-
-0.05-
-0.15-
88-1       89-1       90-i       91-1       92-1       93-1       94-1       95-1       96-1
Year
As Chapter 1 showed, many countries in LAC are facing            5. Fajnzylber and Maloney (2000) find only mixed evidence of an
an incipient recovery, offering enhanced economic oppor-    impact of trade variables in Chile, Colombia, and Mexico. Paes de
tunities. These may entail increased risks for some groups    Barros, Corseuil, and Gonzaga (1999) find no impact in Brazil; and
of workers and households-but the available evidence    Cassoni, Allen, and Labadie (1999) find a reduction in long-run elas-
ticities (absolute value) in Uruguay.
does not show a generalized increase in economic insecurity         6. Cassoni, Allen, and Labadie (1999, 2000) for Uruguay; Paes de
in the 1990s. Nevertheless, both the increased economic    Barros and others (1999) for Brazil; Cardenas and Bernal (1999), and
risks that those groups may be facing, and the still high        Kugler (1999) for Colombia; Saavedra (1999), and Saavedra and
levels of aggregate volatility in the region, provide ample    Torero (2000) for Peru.
justification for rethinking and strengthening social pro-          7. In the U.K. and Germany there is evidence of strong effects on
labor demand from the falling barriers to direct foreign investment
tection measures.
in Europe.
8. Hatzius (2000) finds evidence that the long-run labor demand
Notes                                                           elasticity may have risen substantially across the period of increased
1. Gross national product (GNP) is in principle a better measure    direct foreign investment. Fajnzylber, Ribeiro, and Maloney (1999),
of national income than GDP. However, we use the latter because of    however, find limited evidence that the own wage elasticity of firm
greater availability of data. Using GNP instead would make the con-    entry and exit, a component of which is foreign, has increased in
trast between Latin America and other regions even starker, but    Chile and Colombia with liberalization.
would force us to work with a smaller country sample. For this rea-  9. For Brazil, see Gonzaga (1998); for others, World Bank
son, we focus on GDP.                                            calculations.
2. In Figure 2.1, as well as in other figures below, East Asia shows  10. Kugler (1999) for Colombia; Cassoni, Allen, and Labadie
a large discrepancy between the regional median and the population-    (2000) in World Bank poverty assessment for Uruguay.
weighted value. This reflects the large weight of China in the latter  11. Derived by Gill, Haindl, Montenegro, and Sapelli (2000)
value, and the fact that China experienced extremely large volatility    using Haindl's (1996) methodology for generating labor flows from
in the 1960s.                                                    repeated cross-sectional data.
3. Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru,    12. See Maloney (1999). Plot is ofresiduals ofregressions ofshare
and Venezuela.                                                   of self-employment and job tenure on industrial productivity, share
4. For example, the qualitative results are similar when using    of young people in the work force, the level of education, and the
instead an alternative breakdown guided by developments in the    level of interest rates.
world economy: 1960-72 (pre-oil shock); 1973-81 (oil shocks);       13. Dunne, Roberts, and Samuelson (1989) found no strong
1982-90 (debt crisis and its aftermath); and 1991-present (postdebt    trend in plant-level turnover in U.S. manufacturing from 1963-82,
crisis and reform period).                                       a period of substantial tariff reduction and technological progress.
35



SECURING OUR FUTUJRE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh (1996) found no relationship    Mexico outstripped those of formal sector workers during 1987-96.
between U.S. job flows and either import penetration or export share,    See Arias (1999), Saavedra (1999), and Cunningham and Arrecona
although Klein, Schuh, and Triest (2000) found that the responsive-    (2000).
ness of job flows to the real exchange rate varies with the industries'  16. Cassoni, Allen, and Labadie (2000) for Uruguay; and discus-
openness to international trade.                                sions with Jaime Saavedra (Peru).
14. Using firm level panel data for Latin America, Roberts and   17. Arias (1999) for Argentina; Saavedra (1998) for Pleru; and
Tybour (1996) found high turnover in Chile, Colombia, and Morocco    Cassoni, Allen, and Labadie (1999) for Uruguay.
relative to the U.S. (Davis and Halriwanger 1992), but no obvious   18. Arias and Saavedra in Cunningham and Artecona (2000);
relation with trade reform. Tybout (1996) did find very high exit    Montenegro (1998) for Chile.
rates following the Chilean liberalization. However, Roberts (1996)  19. These figures are from Wodon (2000). Most measures of
found that in Colombia during 1983-85, average entry and exit   income mobility in the literature have been developed independently
actually rose with trade restrictions, compared to the previous period    of the concept of inequality. Yet, there are links between mobility
of relative openness.                                            and inequality. Yitzhaki and Wodon (2000) have propose.] a Gini
15. It might also explain why, wich the exception of women in   index of mobility to provide for an explicit link between inequality
Brazil, wage gains of informal workers in Argentina, Brazil, and    and mobility.
36



CHAPTER 3
Desi g ning Social Policy When
Peop e Face Risk: A Conceptual
Framework
S ALREADY DISCUSSED, DURING THE 1990S THERE WERE ECONOMIC REFORMS IN LATIN
America and the Caribbean which resulted in its rapid integration into world markets. There
appears to be growing concern, however, that the social insurance and social protection mech-
anisms existing in most LAC economies are inadequate to deal with heightened economic
- t ~insecurity.' In the popular press and opinion polls, there are sentiments voiced in favor of
expanding the role of government in countering growing economic insecurity through, for example, intro-
duction or expansion of formal unemployment insurance programs, government-sponsored health insur-
ance, and safety nets for those not covered by labor market-related programs. Governments appear to be
puzzled about how best to help people manage the risks they face.
In examining these claims more systematically, Chapter 2 found that, in many LAC countries, aggregate
risk actually appeared to have declined in the 1990s relative to the 1980s, and even relative to the 1970s.
Microeconomic risk also shows no clear trend; some indicators of volatility, such as real wage fluctuations,
have indeed registered sharp declines. In most countries economic growth has picked up over the last decade.
These developments-falling economic risk and increased wealth, combined with a clamor for greater
social insurance-may appear to be contradictory. More carefiul study using a structured analytical frame-
work, however, shows that this is not so. The economics of insurance indicate that, other things being equal,
the demand for all types of insurance will rise as incomes   (1972), which provides an elegant treatment of an individ-
rise. The overall demand will also rise as the potential loss  uial s optimal insurance decisions when faced with the
faced by individuals becomes greater, and the demand for   options of market insurance, self-insurance, and self pro-
certain types of insurance may rise even when the world   tection. This report attempts to systematically derive from
becomes less risky. This chapter provides an overview of   solid economic foundations the public policy implications
this approach and illustrates its usefulness in formulating    of the potential inability of individuals to insure or protect
effective but minimalistic social policy strategies to deal   themselves effectively (see Gill and Ilahi 2000).
with socioeconomic risks.                               The framework used here allows us to address problems
that preoccupy policymakers around the world; that is,
The Need for Sound Analysis                           changes in the demand for insurance due to globalization,
The main danger of approaching the problem of risk with-   economic growth, or increased uncertainty, and the likely
out sound analysis is that it results in serious confusion   effects of social safety nets created in response to these
about the role of government policy.2 There is considerable   changes. The approach is versatile enough to distinguish
analytical work on the economics of insurance, which stud-   between the policy implications of economywide (aggre-
ies how individuals and families react when faced with   gate) and idiosyncratic (microeconomic) shocks, between
risk. This report relies on the work of Ehrlich and Becker   catastrophic (large and rare) and noncatastrophic (small and
37



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
frequent) losses, and between good and bad instruments for   loss. Both involve expenditures. Market and self-insurance
insurance and protection against these shocks. The    serve to transfer income from the good to the bad state of
approach yields insights that can-with some additional   the world, but do not reduce the likelihood that these trans-
work-lead to rigorous strategy formulation at the country   fers will be required. Self-protection, on the other hand,
level.3                                                   only reduces the probability of the bad state of the world,
In this chapter, we illustrate how a theory of individual   doing nothing to the size of the loss in the event it occurs
insurance and self-protection can be extended to identify    anyway. The critical difference between market insurance
"market-augmenting" roles of government (Olson 2000).   and self-insurance is that the former uses pooling to spread
Under one rather strict interpretation, the public policy    risk across individuals.
analogs of the individual's insurance and self-protection    Individuals or families attempt to smooth consumption
problem are social insurance (government actions to aug-    over the good and bad states of the world. If both market
ment market insurance and self-insurance) and social protec-   insurance and self-insurance opportunities are present, the
tion (government actions to augment self-protection).     individual sees them as substitutes (see Box 3.2). The pro-
vision of market insurance likely will reduce self-insurance;
Approach and Implications                                 thus, for example, the availability of unemployment insur-
A systematic approach to social policy formulation should    ance will reduce precautionary saving. The problem  of
begin by understanding how individuals or families behave    "moral hazard" results if the purchase of market insurance
when confronted with risk. Fundamentally, there are two    reduces self-protection; thus, for example, if unemployment
actions that an individual or family can take: insure, that is,   insurance is available, people may become more likely to
transfer incomes from good to bad states; and self-protect,   shirk.4 The most common outcome if moral hazard is acute
that is, lower the likelihood that the bad state occurs. Nei-   is that private insurance markets may not exist, or may
ther is without cost. A comprehensive framework would   involve prohibitively high premiums.
allow for all types of insurance and self-protection deci-   The key features of and insights obtained from  this
sions. Any constraints on individuals taking these actions    framework are:
effectively would be of social policy interest, and the prob-
lem then becomes one of deciding whether and how gov-        * Levels of risk, incomes, and prices or costs of risk-
ernments can help remove these constraints.                     management instruments all are important in deter-
In addition to clarifying basic concepts, a good analyti-    mining how much individuals spend on insurance
cal framework for risk management should have three             and protection.
attributes. First, it should cover all the major instruments  * Market insurance and self-insurance are substitutes,
for managing risk and be sensitive to the relationships         in that greater availability or lower prices of one lead
between these instruments. Second, it should afford guid-       to reduced expenditures on the other. Self-insurance
ance on how individual efforts to insure and protect against    and self-protection are also substitutes.
risk can be improved; that is, the circumstances that pro-   * Market insurance and self-protection may be substi-
vide cause for governments to intervene. Third, working         tutes or complements; a lower price of self-protection
through the structured framework should formalize exist-       increases self-protection and lowers risks, hence
ing thinking about the subject of risk but-even more            reducing demand for both insurance and self-insur-
important-yield insights additional to those that we            ance. In overall equilibrium, however, lower risks
began with.                                                     may also reduce the price of market insurance and,
The "comprehensive insurance" approach is especially         thus, lead to an increase in the demand for market
well suited for these goals. As formalized by Ehrlich and       insurance.
Becker (1972), the insurance problem of the individual is    * An increase in the difference between crisis and non-
characterized as one of determining the levels of expendi-      crisis income levels (the "income at risk") coul(d lead
ture on market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protec-      to an increase in demand for insurance. Thus, indi-
tion (see Box 3.1). The premise is that individuals can         viduals may be richer (in that their expected incomes
either insure against loss or lower the probability of the      are higher) but may still demand more insurance.
38



DESIGNING SOCIAL POLICY WHEN PEOPLE FACE RISK: A CONCEPTUAL NETWORK
BOX 3 1
Market suramnce, Selfinsurance, and SefProtecton: DisinguIshing Featwes and Exampes
Market insurance transfers income or resources from  a      Two examples may help clarify these concepts. An
good state to bad but does not change probabilities of   individual, faced with the likelihood of damage to his car
good and bad states, it is available at an observable (mar-   in an accident, may purchase automobile insurance (mar-
ket) price, and al.vays involves pooling of risks.       ket insurance); he may buy a stronger-hence more
Self-insurance, like market insurance, also transfers   expensive but otherwise identical-car (self-insurance); or
resources from a good state to bad, and does not change    he may drive more cautiously, even though this increases
probabilities of good and bad states. It differs from mar-   travel time (self-protection). Again, faced with a higher
ket insurance in two ways: it has an imputed, not actual,   probability of being unemployed, a person may try to
price (called a "shadow price" by economists), and it does    purchase market insurance, may self-insure by increasing
not involve risk-pooling.                                savings over and above what she saves for relatively certain
I   Sef-protection is different from both market and self.   needs such as education of children and retirement, or
insurance in that it does not transfer resources from a good    engage in self-protection by studying to qualify for a pro-
state to bad, but lowers the probability of the bad state.    fession in which unemployment rates are lower.
It is often difficult to determine whether a decision    Note, however, that all three types of actions involve
should be classified as self-insurance or self-protection,   costs. market insurance requires a premium to be paid; self-
since many instruments do both. It can sometimes be dif-   insurance implies costs (because, for example, a stronger car
ficult even to classify informal insurance measures as mar-   costs more whether or not the accident occurs); and self-
ket insurance or self-insurance. In such cases, the key dis-   protection involves monetary or other costs (for example,
tinguishing feature should be the absence or existence of   schooling involves tuition fees, and driving slowly or
pooling,                                                 attending classes implies less time for other activities).
* Relatively rare (and large) losses may be better           self-protection are available but no self-insurance is
insured through market insurance, and relatively           possible. The individual would be worse off in this
frequent (and moderate) losses through self-insur-         case than where all three are available. The reason is
ance. Thus, for example, as individuals face lower         that for losses that are not rare, the individual would
probabilities of becoming unemployed, they may             still have to use market insurance. However, we
demand less insurance overall, but may also choose         know from the framework that market insurance is
to have relatively more market insurance and less          a less-preferred instrument than self-insurance for
self-insurance. At the level of the aggregate econ-        losses that occur frequently. Second, suppose that
omy, as countries improve their economic manage-           market insurance and self-insurance are available,
ment and regulations and reduce the likelihood of          but it is not possible to invest in self-protection.
crises, there will be a shift away from self-insurance     Individuals who are relatively efficient at self-pro-
(for example, fiscal stabilization funds) toward mar-      tection would be worse off because they cannot
ket insurance (contingent credit arrangements with         reduce the premium paid for market insurance by
world financial markets or the international finan-        reducing the risk they face through expenditures on
cial institutions).                                        self-protection. (See Box 3.3 for a fuller discussion of
* Individuals enjoy higher welfare when all three            these issues.)
instruments (market insurance, self-insurance, and
self-protection) are available than when one is miss-    Advantages of a Disciplined Approach
ing. This can be best explained by two examples.    There are three advantages of a disciplined, organized,
First, consider the case where market insurance and    comprehensive approach to the problem of risk. First, it
39



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
BOX 3.2
A Theory of Comprehensive Insurance
In the Ehrlich and Becker (1972) characterization, there    of substitution:
are two states of the world: bad (state 0) and good (state               - -       pU0(c*,s*,r*)
1). The bad state occurs with probabilityp, and the good             L' (e9) +I    -  P(l)(c*,s*,r*)     (3)
state with probability I-p. The endowed incomes (and
hence the consumption) of the individual in the two        Expenditures on self-protection reduce the probabilky
states are, respectively, ! and l , Thus, the expected    of the bad state. These expenditures are optimized at
utility of the individual is                           level r* where the marginal gain from redurcig the prob-
ability of loss equals the marginal loss in utility from
U = (l-p)U(I')+pUV(I)                (1)    having to pay r* fbr it in each period:
However, faced with risk, the individual may purchase
market insurance that involes paying a premium for 7rfbr      P                                           4 E   *   *  4
every peso of coverage, and paying s pesos if the bad state
occurs, The individual also spends resources on self-      There are three main results of tis characterization of
insurance (c), and self-protection (j') to smooth income    the individual's risk management decisions within a
over states. Each peso spent on self-insurance reduces the    comprehensive insurance model, which would be absent
loss in the bad state according to a "loss finction" L(L` c),   in treatmenrs that either take a piecemeal approach (for
where Le is the difference between endowed incomes in   example, examine only market insurance) or neglect to
the two states. Each peso allocated to self-protectioa low-   include prices. First, market insurance and self-insurance
ers the probability of the bad state according to the func-   are substitutes; fbr example, an increase in the price of
tion p(r). Just as a lower 7r allows the individual to buy    market insurance lowers the demand fbr it and increases
more market insurance with a given budget, increased   the demand fbr self-insurance. Second, the individual is
marginal productivity of self-insurance and self-protec-   likely to pTrefr market insurance over self-insurance for
tion allows the individual to get more at a given cost.  insuring relatively rare losses because the 'shadow price"
The individual chooses s, c, and r to maximize the    of self-insurance does not fall as the probability of loss
expected utility function before, the state of the world is   decreases, while the price of market insurnce does.
revealed (that is, the framework is ex ante):           Third, market insurance does not inevitably cause "'moral
U - LI - p(p'e, rjULIll- c -   - rj + p(pe,+r)U   (2) hazard," that is, reduce selfprotection, because of two
L(Le, c          ) - J2              countervailin  effects. On the one hand, market insur-
ance reduces the p eie loss, and thereifre, creates a
In the absence of market insurance, s is constrained to   tendency toward lower self- protection. On the other
zero, and the individual's choice is restricted to c and r.   hand, by reducing the probability f the bW  st#e, self-pro-
Analogously, the model catn accommodate situations   tection makes market insurance cheaper and, hence,
where self-insurance or self-protection are not possible,   increases the tendency to use the market fr insurance.
that is, where c=O or r=-O, respectively                   Since the 1970s the literature on inisurance has con-
The individual chooses the levels of market insurance    centrated mostly on the problem of moral hazard. For
(s*) and self-insurance (c*) where the price of market   social policy, however the coprvehensi  insrawn  aspects
insurance equals the shadow price of selfinsurance, and    of the theory-wich have been largely neglccted-may
they both equal the probability-weighted marginal rate   be as or even more relevant.
places individuals, households, and firms-not govern-   absence of well-functioning markets (for example, prohib-
ment-at the center and provides rationales for govern-   itively high prices) or the inability of some to use these
ment action that are not ad hoc but are based on the    instruments even at relatively low prices (for example,
40



DESIGNING SOCIAL POLICY WHEN PEOPLE FACE RISK: A CONCEPTUAL NETWORK
BOX 3.3
The Framework in 'Real Ufe" Situations
Increased Risk: Heightened Economic Insecurity         Proportional Increases in incomes in atl States:
Consider the case where only the probability of the indi-   Economic Growth
vidual being in the bad state (p) goes up. This may charac-   Economic growth can be simplistically characterized by a
terize the concerns in Latin America and East Asia, where   proportionate increase in 4 and I,; hence, the prospec-
it is believed that there is now greater econornic insecurity.   tive loss rises in the same proportion. Under quite gen-
The effect would be to increase the demand for overaLl   eral conditions, the demand for market insurance and
insurance in absolute terms, but also to change the mix   self-protection will increase. This example illustrates
between market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protec-   that-somewhat counterintuitively-an improvement in
tion. following our framework, an increase in p results ia a   wealth where incomes in both states go up proportionalLy
relative decline in market insurance, no relative change in    wiLl result in an increase in the demand for insurance.
self-protection, and an increase in self-insurance. This exer-   Better income prospects in the good state will have the
cise shows the importance of prices: what happens to the   same effect. The environment not becoming riskier and
demand for market insurance and self-insurance depends on    economic growth taking place-an unmistakably posi-
whether the market price of insurance adjusts to the   tive combination-should result in an increased demnand
increase in probability. If it does, then the optimal level of   for insurance, often associated with matters becoming
market insurance would be lower and self-insurance higher.   worse.
But if the price does not increase to reflect increases inp, an
"excess demand" for market insurance results, and demand   increases in Noncrisis Income Levels and Likelihood
for self-insurance does not increase as much.          of Crises: Globalization
Finally, consider the case of "globalization" as it is
Increased Expected Income During Crises: Provision     commonly stereotyped-when prospective income in
of Safety Nets                                         the good state increases (viewed somewhat pessimisti-
Suppose that the expected income in the bad state   cally, losses become more catastrophic), but so does the
increases because of, for example, a guararntee by the gov-   probability of the bad state (losses become more fre-
ernment that everyone will get a minimum income in the    quent)-that is, both C and p increase. Assuming that i
bad state which is higher than  Io. This reduces the   the price of insurance adjusts to changes in prospective
demand for matket insurance because the prospective loss   probabilities, the outcome for market insurance would
decreases, expenditures on self-protection fall for the same   be armbiguous because increases in probabilities of
reason, but its effect on self-insurance is uncertain because   crises weakens the tendency toward market insurance,
the fall in self-insurance due to the reduced tendency to   but increases in income in good times strengthens it.
insure may be offset by an increase in self-insurance   The effect on self-protection would be ambiguous, but
because it is preferred over market insurance as losses   probably positive. This example illustrates the diffi-
become less "catastrophic." This example illustrates that   culty of predicting how complex phenomena such as
individuals will not necessarily reduce self-insurance when    globalization affect the demand for insurance. Note
such a "safety net" is available, but it is more likely that   also that it is more likely-given the findings of Chap-
they will reduce self-protection. Thus, the provision of a   ter 2-that globalization imiples that p is no higher i
public works program will not necessarily reduce precau-   than before (or even lower), but losses are larger when
tionary saving by individuals, but would lower the effort   crises in fact do occur. Viewed this way, globalization is
to reduce the probability of being in the bad state by, for   essentially the opposite of the "safety niets" example
example, reducing investments in health and work skills.   given above.
41



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
poverty or low budgets). The analysis also yields not just a   described above is the lack of pooling. This category
menu of policies, but also some rules for establishing pri-    would include mandatory saving schemes such as
orities that are necessary for strategy formulation. Second,   employee  provident funds  in  Singapore  and
the relationships between instruments to deal with risk are    Malaysia, and individual severance funds in countries
not arbitrary, but are derived from  structured analysis,      such as Brazil and Colombia.
yielding clearer insights into how changes in the economic  * "Social protection" can be viewed as policies to aug-
environment affect the demand for insurance. Third, the        ment self-protection. The failure of markets to facil-
approach provides a logical framework for organizing the       itate self-protection by individuals or families that is
tools of social risk management and their likely effects.      optimal provides the rationale for government to
intervene. The feature that distinguishes these inter-
Clearer Rationale for Government Action                        ventions from the above two sets of policies is that
With an approach that is individual-centered, the need for     the aim of social protection policies would be to
government arises only where markets fail and social pol-      reduce the probability of occurrence of the loss, and
icy formulation is based on minimalistic and not ad hoc        not simply insure against it. Policies to facilitate the
principles. The role of government here-driven by effi-        acquisition of human capital (better health, educa-
ciency concerns in an environment of risk-is to augment        tion, and training) may constitute the core of social
markets; that is, to facilitate insurance and self-protection  protection.
by providing instruments if markets for them do not exist
(for example, in the case of unemployment insurance), or    Useful Insights
through interventions to improve the quality of instru-    The framework yields useful insights into questions central
ments if individuals are using inferior modes of insurance   to determining the scope and design of government policy.
(for example, savings in the form  of one or two assets    Three sets of implications are especially important.
instead of a diversified portfolio). Following this line of  Welfare is higher when more and better options for
reasoning:                                                insurance are available to individuals. As discussed
* "Social insurance" can be viewed as a policy to aug-    above, the availability of all three "insurance" instruments
ment market insurance. Failure of markets to effi-   (market insurance, self-insurance, and self-prctection) will
ciently insure because some risks are uninsurable or   improve welfare over a situation where one or more instru-
cannot be diversified, for example, or because moral   ments are not available. For example, making available
hazard problems are insurmountable for private   income support programs for the unemployed is likely to
insurers, creates the rationale for social insurance    be welfare-improving even when there are efficiency losses
policies. Government actions that help individuals   (though the magnitude of such losses can be reduced using
and families deal better with risk by facilitating    adequate instruments-see below). Making market insur-
transfers from good states to bad through risk-pool-   ance available would lower self-insurance, but would still
ing would be classified as social insurance. This   result in welfare improvements.
would include income-support programs for the          Moral hazard may not be an insurmountable problem
unemployed (such as unemployment insurance) and    if social insurance mimics the market as much as possi-
disability insurance.                               ble. The introduction of market insurance is usually
* Mandated savings schemes are policies to augment   thought to lower self-protection and raise the probability
self-insurance. The failure of markets to provide    of occurrence of the bad state ("moral hazard"), but our
"good" instruments for self-insurance is one rationale   framework and common sense indicate that much can be
for governments to intervene. Moral hazard prob-    done to limit this adverse side effect. For example, unem-
lems, such as the failure to save enough for retire-   ployment insurance that successfully discriminates among
ment in anticipation of a government bailout of the    workers by their risk factors (for example, using informa-
old-age poor, provide another justification for com-    tion on employment history, skill, or sector of occupation
pulsory saving. Again, the feature that distinguishes   to set insurance premiums) can lower this negative rela-
these policies from  "social insurance" of the type    tionship between market insurance and self-protection,
42



DESIGNING SOCIAL POLICY WHEN PEOPLE FACE RISK: A CONCEPTUAL NETWORK
and even reverse it under certain circumstances. Therefore,   A Powerful Toolfor Organization
the appropriate policy question may not be whether to pro-   The framework described above also helps in obtaining a
vide unemployment insurance-especially as governments   structured view of government policies and programs. The
implement reforms that make these risks less frequent-    policies and programs discussed in Chapters 4 to 7 should
but how to best design it and to determine how govern-    be viewed as government-sponsored actions to assist indi-
ments can most effectively develop the capacity to imple-   viduals and families attain insurance that is as comprehen-
ment it.                                                 sive as possible under the circumstances that exist in LAC
Financial market strengthening should be a central   countries. Table 3.1 shows how some of these policies can
component of social policy, because it can augment self-   be classified according to whether they help individuals
insurance, market insurance, and self-protection. Finan-    attain more efficient insurance (through pooling), self-
cial sector strengthening is one of the most important-   insurance, or self-protection.
but relatively underemphasized-policies for balanced,
market-augmenting social risk management. There are    Conclusion
four reasons.                                             This chapter proposes a relatively simple approach to the
First, financial markets facilitate risk-sharing. In well-   problem of risk, both in terms of individual decisionmak-
developed financial markets, individuals and firms can buy    ing and the possible role of government. The approach is
and sell assets with different risk profiles, diversifying their   quite general in that it includes the three major options
sources of income, and thus reducing their exposure to   available to individuals for dealing with risk: purchasing
adverse shocks affecting their particular industry or firm.   market insurance, self-insuring, and taking steps to lower
Financial markets also provide the most efficient channel to   the probability of incurring losses (self-protecting). The
promptly redirect resources toward those firms and sectors   role of government policy arises when some markets are
temporarily hit by adverse disturbances, easing their    missing and individuals cannot reach optimal levels of
impact on income, employment, and welfare.               insurance and self-protection. The government can aug-
Second, self-insurance involves precautionary saving.   ment individual or household efforts by providing market-
Without a strong financial sector, the poor may end up sav-   type insurance where markets fail (for example, unemploy-
ing through "bad" instruments such as cattle and land,   ment insurance), by facilitating  individual insurance
which are highly illiquid and the prices of which may fall   efforts through more efficient forms of self-insurance (for
sharply if the bad state of the world ("crisis") occurs.5   example, financial sector development and regulation), or
Financial sector strengthening can encourage the use of   by assisting or subsidizing self-protection (for example,
"good" instruments by savers; this is especially crucial   public education and health services).
where social insurance mechanisms such as unemployment      Using this approach, the chapter traced the implica-
benefits are difficult to establish.                      tions of changes in the environment, such as increased risk
Third, financial sector strengthening can result in low-   or increased wealth, on the demand for market insurance,
ering the probability of a crisis occurring, thus augment-   self-insurance, and self-protection. Combined with the
ing self-protection efforts by individuals and families. In    possibility that markets are missing or do not operate effi-
the countries of East Asia where the financial sector weak-    ciently, these findings suggest how the demand for social
nesses were a primary cause of the crises in the 1990s, this   insurance and social protection may arise when such
self-protection  augmenting  role of financial sector   changes take place as countries grow or face more or less
strengthening is especially important.6                  risky external environments. Some of the findings were
Fourth, financial sector strengthening will help create   expected. Others run counter to widely held views. Three
(more efficient) markets for insurance against catastrophic   of these findings deserve mention.
losses such as those due to poor health or natural disasters.  First, the demand for social insurance can increase even
Thus, private financial markets can provide life insurance,   when the environment becomes less risky and countries
disability insurance instruments, and insurance against   become more prosperous. This finding is surprising when
natural disasters, and can even contribute to insuring    market- or government-provided insurance is analyzed in
against macroeconomic crises.                            isolation, but is a natural outcome of analysis using a more
43



SECURING OUR FUTUlRE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TAOLE 3.1
Government Policies and Their Effect on Individual Comprehensive Insurance
MARKET INSURANCE               SELF-INSURANCE                             SELF-PROTECTION
REDUCING                     REDUCING
MICRO RISK                AGGREGATE RISK
Economywide Risks
Stable macro policies
Fiscal stabilization funds '
Foreign reserve holdings '
Financial sector reform                          N                             N                                                         V
Deposit insurance                                                              v
Risk of Becoming Unemployed
Unemplovment insurance                           N
Mandated severance                               N
Individual severance funds                                                     v
Public works programs                            al
Training programs                                N                                                          N
Risk of Becoming Poor
Cash transfers                                   N
Conditional cash tranisfers '
Education reform                                                                                            v
Health insturance                                N                                                          N'
Financial sector reform                                                        V
a. Policies that augment seJf-protection for individuals may be setf-insurance or market insurance ar the cosotry level. For example, fiscal stabilization funds ace self-insuransce
(because they transfer resources from good states tO bad} for countries, though :hey qualify as self-protection augmentation here (because they reduce aggregate risk for individuals).
Access to loteroamional Monetary Fund credit during bad times is market insurance for countries (international risk-pooling), bur is again self-protection augmentation at the indi-
ciduat level.
b. Although in theory training programs for the unemploved involve an element of self-protection, this elerment appears modest according to the available evidence, so that these
programs operate mainly as insurance mechanisms.
c. Examples include Boasa Earsa in Brazil sad Progpesa in Mexico.
comprehensive (and more realistic) framework where indi-                          2. See Hlolzmann and Jorgensen (1999) for an excellent effort to
viduals self-insure and self-protect.                                         reduce this confusion.
Second, ideally social policy should aim  to facilitate all                   3. The framework also lends itself to analysis of risk reduction
three types of actions that individuals take when confronted                  policies at the multilateral level, and the possible role of international
agencies such as the World Bank and International Monetary Fund.
with risk. This finding should help reassess the pros and cons                    4. The presence of moral hazard can prevent private insurance
of policies such as income support programs for the unem-                     markets from  emerging for some risks, such as business failures or
ployed  (and  among  them, unemployment insurance)  in                        loss of employment. Ehrlich and Becker (1972) reason that moral
developing countries, focusing the debate on their likely effi-               hazard is not inevitable, because in one aspect market insurance and
ciency cost and the capacity of governments to contain it.                    self-protection are complements-increased self-protection increases
Third, the role of policies in facilitating precautionary                  the marginal product of market insurance. That is, if self-protection
saving   the financiale asses (uch as fianciatl    nrectrustrengthy       or a lowered probability of the bad state is rewarded by market insur-
saving in financial assets (such as financial sector strength-                ance (in the form  of lower premiums), market insurance and self-
ening) has been underemphasized as a social policy instru-                    protection can indeed become complements, and moral hazard could
ment. This finding  is a natural outcome of an approach                       be eliminated.
that begins with the individual and derives the problem  of                       5. It also follows that illiquidity of savers' assets hampers the real-
government as a residual, but can  easily  be missed  by                      location of financial resources toward sound firms in distress in times
analyses where this order is reversed,                                        of crisis, which augments the disruptive effects of shocks.
6. The combination of weak interlinkages wirh international cap-
ital markets and lack of depth in Latin America's domestic capital
Notes                                                                         markets represent a source of adverse shocks to the region (in our
1. This chapter is based on Gill and Ilahi (2000), a background           framework, a higher probability of the bad state, p), and an amplifi-
paper commissioned for this report.                                           cation mechanism  for other shocks.
44



CHAPTER 4
Macroeconomic Volatility in
Latin America and the Caribbean:
Causes and Remedies
Sources of Aggregate Volatility in LAC
A        GGREGATE VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN REFLECTS TWO MAIN FORCES:
real and financial external shocks and macroeconomic policy instability.'
External Shocks
LAC is subject to large external disturbances from world goods and financial markets. These can
be broadly classified as volatility in the terms of trade and in international capital flows. Figure 4.1 graphs the
standard deviation of the rate of growth of the terms of trade across world regions over the last four decades.
The figure shows that over the last two decades, LAC suffered terms of trade disturbances that were much
greater than those affecting industrial economies and the East Asian miracle countries, and on par with those
experienced by South Asia and the Middle East and North Africa.
A key factor behind the large terms of trade variability is the high share of a few primary commodities-
such as oil (Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela) and metals (Bolivia and Chile)-
in the total exports of many of the region's economies. World commodity prices are highly volatile, and this
volatility translates into large terms of trade fluctuations for commodity-exporting countries. Figure 4.2 shows
the share of the four most important commodities2 in the total exports of selected LAC countries in 1995 and
1999 (or the latest available year). Export concentration  This factor can be taken into consideration by looking at
remains high in a number of countries, although a few-    the volatility of terms of trade shocks, a concept that reflects
notably Mexico-have succeeded in reducing it over the   both the changes in the terms of trade and the degree of open-
last decade.                                           ness of the economy.3 Figure 4.3 offers a comparative per-
Terms of trade volatility was particularly high during the   spective across regions and decades on the volatility of terms
1970s (largely reflecting the first oil crisis), and declined    of trade shocks. The pattern that emerges is similar to that in
somewhat in the 1980s and more so in the 1990s, both in   Figure 4.1, although Latin America now ranks higher than
the LAC region and other world regions. The economic   South Asia due to greater openness to trade.
impact of terms of trade fluctuations, however, is determined  Table 4.1 shows the standard deviation of terms of trade
not only by their magnitude, but also by the degree of open-   shocks for the major LAC economies over the last four
ness to international trade of the economies. Like other parts   decades.4 The table shows that this magnitude is generally
of the world, LAC has considerably increased its openness to   higher in smaller commodity-exporting economies (for
global trade over time, and this trend-unless matched by a   example, the Dominican Republic, Jamaica, Nicaragua, and
parallel increase in diversification of trade-could have   Trinidad and Tobago). By this measure, volatility declined
raised the exposure of the region's economies to external   since the 1970s in a majority of economies, although for
trade disturbances.                                    some, such as the Dominican Republic, Jarnaica, Paraguay,
45



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 4.1
Volatility in Terms of Trade Growth
(Regional Medians)
20
I8_ -          1960s         1980s                       0                     
18 
16_   g   1970s   * 1990s.                                                                             i
14 -
1 2
u 10
8 
6-
4
2
0 
Industrial Economies   East Asia and    Latin America and   Middle East and     South Asia      Sub-Saharan Africa   Other East Asia
Pacific 7       the Caribbean       North Africa                                             and Pacific
FIGURE 4.2
Share in Total Exports of Four Most Important Commodities
(Selected LAC Countries)
Venezuela
Uruguay
Trinidad and Tobago
Peru   a          E         E          E               l0E1t9
Paraguay                                                                                                         199S
Panama
Nicaragua
Mexico
Jamaica
Honduras
Haiti                                                       
Guyana
Guatemala
El Salvador
Ecuador 
Dominican Republic
Costa Rica
Colombia
Chile
Brazil                   _
Bolivia
Belize        urB                                           
Argentina
0           10           20           30           40           50           60           70          80           90
Percent
46



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
FIGURE 4.3
Vojatility in Tenrs of Trade Shocks by Decade
(Regional Medians)
5.00-
4.50-     _      960s         1980s
40oo -           1970s        1990s
3.50-
3.00-
2.50-
2,00-
1.50-
1.00 
0.50-
0.00 i
Industrial Economies   East Asia and    Latin America and   Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa  Other East Asia
Pacific 7      the Caribbean     North Africa                                          and Pacific
and Trinidad and Tobago, volatility was actually higher in    is also subject to external financial shocks, reflected in wide
the 1990s than in the 1980s.                                         swings in the volume and cost of foreign capital inflows. Fig-
In addition to the real external shocks represented by            ure 4.4 shows the annual pattern of private capital inflows to
terms of trade changes, LAC, like other developing regions,    Latin America as a percent of GDP. Capital inflows rose
steadily in the late 1970s to peak at over 5 percent of GDP
TABLE 4.1                                                            in the early 1980s, declining sharply to 2 percent in the late
Volatility in Terns of Trade Shocks for Selected Latin Amenican       1980s, followed by a strong recovery in the 1990s that was
Countries                                                            interrupted only by the Tequila Crisis in 1995 and the East
Asian Crisis in 1998.
1960s     1970s      1980s     1990s
(%)       (%)        (%)       (             These large fluctuations in capital flow  volumes are
Argentina                  1.8        0.7        1.0      0.4        accompanied by similarly large fluctuations in their prices.
Belize                     -          -         11.5      2.3        Figure 4.5 shows the spreads on external public borrowing
Bolivia                    3.0        5.6        3                       fou  mao                                                 df
Brazil                     0.5        1.4        1.0      0.7        by four major Latin American economies, defined as the dif-
Chile                      1.9        5.4        2.4      2.5        ferential over world interest rates.5 The spreads display
Colombia                   0.8        2.1        1.7      0.7        huge fluctuations, with strong surges at times of external
Costa Rica                 0.9        4.4       4.1       1.8
Dominican Republic         1.8        2.8        3.7      6.5        crises  (for example, Mexico's Tequila  Crisis  during
Ecuador                    0.4        7.2        3.3      3.7        1994-95), which  signaled  a generalized withdrawal of
El Salvador                1.7        9.5        3.2      1.5
Guatemala                  0.7        2.7        1.5       11        financing for LAC economies.
Guyana                     6.4        9.5       6.2       7.9           The swings in the volume and cost of external financing to
Haiti                      3.3        2.5        1.1      5.8        LAC reflect a combination of external and domestic factors,6
Honduras                   1.3        4.4       2.5       3.1
Jamaica                    2.6        3.0        4.8      9.0        which affect both the decisions of nonresidents to supply
Mexico                     0.3        0.9        2.0      0.9        financing to the domestic economy, and the decisions of resi-
Nicaragua                  1.5        5.1       18.1      6.2
Panama                     -          -         0.9       0.9        dents (including the public sector) regarding whether to bor-
Paraguay                   0.8        4.9        2.6      7.1        row  or lend abroad. The two critical ingredients are the
Peru                       1.5        4.1        1.5      1.1        expected return from holding assets domestically, relative to
Trinidad and Tobago        3.2       12.0        4.0      7.3
Uruguay                    2.5        3.0        2.0      1.2        holding them  abroad, and the perceived riskiness of that
Venezuela                  -          3.6        6.8      3.7        return.
LAC Medians                1.6        4.1       2.6       2.3           For given risk perceptions, private capital inflows tend to
LAC Averages               1.8        4.5       3.9       3.4        move in a direction opposite to OECD interest rates, declin-
47



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 4.4
Median Private Gross Capital Flows in Latin America
(Percent of GDP)
7 -
6-
5-
4.54
2-
6-                                                            .                                                               .. ......  ..:.  
1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
FIGURE 4.5
Spread of Foreign-Currency-Denominated Sovereign Debt Instruments (bps)
(Selected Major Latin American Countries)
3,500 -
Argenrina
3,000 -
Brazil
2,000 -
Venezuela
m1,0(0   L,,                                            4J,S
1,000 
50 0_  - --r^ -*""''".... b' <'
0 -
O    N,    0                                 11                    u      ' .'                  ~      C      >      C
C   >      >  C^.    >         m~ 0<    C>           >      C>     C>     C  C >        >      t       C>    A>      C
ing at times of high rates (as in the early 1980s), and rising           Importantly, however, the flows also reflect developments
when interest rates decline (as in the early 1990s). Inflows         in the destination economies, because botb risk and return are
also  react strongly to payments crises in specific countries,    affected by domestic economic policies. The variability of
such as Mexico, which cause investors to reassess risk  and          capital flows does not reflect just external shocks, blt is in
often leads to a generalized drop in inflows across emerging         part governed  by  forces endogenous  to  the  receiving
markets, in what has been judged as evidence of "financial    economies.8 With this important caveat in mind, Figure 4.6
contagion.' 7                                                        shows the variability of gross private capital flows, as mea-
48



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN  C*AUSES AND REMEDIES
sured by their coefficient of variation,9 across world regions    observed in industrial economies (7 percent) and the East
and time periods. By this measure, volatility of capital flows    Asian miracle countries (10 percent), and was surpassed only
has risen relative to the 1970s in all world regions, although    by Sub-Saharan Africa. It should be noted, however, that in
in most of them it peaked in the 1980s and declined in the    the second half of the 1990s monetary volatility has contin-
1990s. In all three decades, LAC ranks above the industrial    ued on a declining trend in Latin America.
countries and the East Asian miracle countries in terms of        Fiscal policy is also volatile in LAC. Figure 4.8 shows the
capital flow volatility, although the difference between LAC   volatility of real public consumption growth (as measured by
and these regions has narrowed in the 1990s.                   its standard deviation) across decades and world regions.11 As
in previous cases, LAC displays higher volatility than indus-
Macroeconomic Policy Volatility                                trial countries and the East Asian miracle countries-but less
External factors are not the only cause of volatility in Latin    than most other developing regions.
America. Macroeconomic policies must share some of the            Fiscal volatility is also related to monetary instability,
blame. Policy volatility partly reflects mistakes by policy-    because inflationary responses to unsustainable fiscal imbal-
makers, but to a greater extent it is the result of large exter-    ances has traditionally been one of the primary causes of
nal shocks in the presence of weak insurance and financial    volatile monetary aggregates in the developing world-
markets and policy institutions, which constrain room  to    including Latin America until the early 1990s. Figure 4.9
maneuver in macroeconomic management."�                        plots the volatility of money against that of public consump-
Monetary policy volatility has been consistently high in    tion-both policy variables-for a large sample of countries. 12
LAC. Over the last two decades, the region has stood out for    A clear positive association between both variables emerges.
the recurrence of extreme inflation episodes driven by mone-      As noted earlier, however, macroeconomic policy volatility
tary financing of unsustainable fiscal imbalances. Since the    also reflects the effect of external shocks hitting domestic
1970s, as Figure 4.7 shows, the standard deviation of base    economies. This is especially so in developing countries
money growth has been higher in LAC than in most other    where public scctors are heavily depcndent on commodity
world regions. It peaked in the 1980s at over 20 percent    revenues, as in many LAC economies. Terms of trade distur-
annually, and declined in the 1990s to just under 16 percent.    bances have an immediate impact on public revenues and are
The latter figure, which  reflects the extreme inflation    clearly reflected in fiscal aggregates. This can be seen in Fig-
episodes of the early part of the decade in a few countries-    ure 4.10, which plots fiscal volatility against terms of trade
notably Argentina, Brazil, and Peru-is far above the levels    volatility for over 100 countries." Terms of trade fluctuations
FIGURE 4.6
Coefficient of Variation of Gross Private Capital Flows
(Percent of GDP, Regional Medians)
0.70- --
0.60 -    F-I 197 Os
060_ 
*   1980s
0.50 -        1990S
0.40-
0.30-
O 20-
0.10 
0.00  _                                                                                   
Industrial Economies  East Asia and   Latin Amcrica and  Middle East and  SoLoth Asia   Sub-Saharan Africa  Other East Asia
Pacific 7    the Caribbean    North Africa                                    and Pacific
49



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 4.7
Volatility of Reserve Money Growth
(Regional Medians)
25 -
1960s       1980s
20-           1970s        1990s
15-
10 
5
0
Industrial Economies   East Asia and    Latin America and   Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa   Other East Asia
Pacific 7      the Caribbean     North Africa                                         and Pacific
FIGURE 4.8
Volatility of Public Consumption Growth
(Regional Medians)
0.14 -
0.12 -          1960s        1980s
1970s         1990s*
0.1                           i
0.08 
..0.06-
0.04-
0.02-
0
Industrial Economies  East Asia and    Latin America and   Middle East and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa   Other East Asia
Pacific 7      the Caribbean     North Africa                                         and Pacific
appear to be a major force behind fiscal volatility, accounting     and policies that play an instrumental role in absorbing or
for a full one-third of the cross-country variation.                amplifying shocks. Among these shock absorbers and ampli-
fiers, the domestic and world financial markers are perhaps
Absorption and Amplification of Shocks: The                         the most important.
Importance of Financial Markets                                        International financial markets allow domestic agents to
The magnitude of the impact of major economic shocks dis-    sell risky income-generating instruments such as stocks and
cussed above on aggregate income and employment in LAC              bonds of domestic firms. In this manner, domestic agents can
is determined by the functioning of markets, institutions,    reduce their exposure to risks associated with income volatil-
50



Fiscal Volatility                                                          Log of Standard Deviation of Reserve Money Growth         K   C
o  o               o       .�      o               o �                                                                                                q 
0 -
a                                                                                                                                                  c     N io+_
_~ ~~~  -*                                                                                                                               ,   *K
CL~~~~~~~ 
3~~~~~~~~~~~~~~- --                                                                                                                   p    =   + 
0                \                                                                                *0
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
*~~~~~~~
o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
_~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
ava  *l
C~~~~
~~~ ~~~~~a  ~~~~~~*~



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
ity, diminishing the latter and thereby reducing aggregate    Thus, well-functioning domestic financial markets provide
volatility. Further, world financial markets also play an impor-   the efficient means for economywide self-insurance against
tant role by supplying financing to ease adjustment to shocks    aggregate risk-efficiency in the sense that it can achieve rel-
after they have occurred so that, for example, a temporary    atively quick reallocation of financing and avoid unduly long
worsening of the terms of trade, such as a fall in the price of   or widespread disruptions in production and consumption.
oil or copper, does not force the economy into a sharp reces-  In most LAC economies, however, weak links with world
sion. Instead, such financing allows the shock to be weathered    financial markets and poorly functioning or shallow domestic
through a temporary increase in the current account deficit.    financial markets greatly contribute to amplifying shocks
Domestic financial markets also play a key role in the    rather than helping absorb them. This dual financial weak-
adjustment to shocks, fulfilling the dual purpose of facilitat-   ness is at the core of LAC's macroeconomic volatility."5
ing both ex ante risk diversification among domestic agents
in the capital market-hence the diversification is limited to    Weak Links with World Financial Markets
individual, not aggregate, risks"4-and ex post channeling    That links to international financial markets are weak follows
of resources toward sound firms and sectors hurt by shocks.   from LAC's modest volume and large swings in private capi-
BOX4,1
Excess Sensiti to Disturbances The Case of Chile
The weakness of the financial links of LAG economies to    With unhampred access to external financing, Chile
world markets makes them  overly sensitive to distur-   would be able to smooth out tenporary copper price fluc-
bances. Here we document the case of Chile, the economic   tuations, and the swings in growh rates would be more
fbrtunes of wbhich fluctuate widely with world cpper    muted than those of copper prices. However, panel (b)
prices.                                                 shows that ihe opposite happens. The panel compares the
Panel (a) in Figure 4.11 plots the spot prie of copper   fluctuations il GDP actually observed with those that
fiom the London Metal Exchange and Cies quarterly    would be dicated fom perfct smoothing (specifically, the
GMP growth. The tesemblance between the two is stril-   an       value of the present value impact of the change in
ig, with the only important exception beig the 1990    copper prices, as a share of GDP)."8 It is apparent from the
growth slowdown and subsequent recover, which had a    fure (from the different scales in the axes, in particular)
purely domestic origin.                                 that fluauations in GDP are an order of magnitude larger
FiGMRE 4A I
ChiWs Excess Senesiivt to Scks
(a) Growth and copper price                        (b) Present value effct of terms of trade shocks
-4000       15% 
3500                                                       1.0%
3000
+~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~5 -S% /                                                         -0.5%�
2500 
0            3                              (::opper Price  1a00
2 -5% _ ~~Groth                     ..                        5      0-10%  t   = fiii i                  -1.0%
Growth (dev from mean)
(-N 9N  N  N      NN 
Saalm Orowth ftom 15F; opper pices (London Metal Ethange) fiom Datstre
52



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
tal flows, and the volatile interest rate spreads on sovereign    tioning of domestic financial markets in most LAC countries
debt discussed earlier. Even more striking is the fact that    makes them part of the economic instability problem rather
LAC borrowers tend to face much higher premiums, and              than a solution to it. This is true both of banks and other
higher return volatility, than private U.S. borrowers of simi-    financial institutions.
lar rating.'6 All these facts suggest that LAC's integration in     Figure 4.13 shows that LAC still lags behind most world
world financial markets is still limited, which hampers the    regions in terms of banking system development, as measured
ability of the region's economies-even the economically    by the ratio of credit to the private sector to GDP.'9 While
well-integrated ones such as Chile-to smooth the effects of    there is a great deal of variation across countries in the region,20
temporary disturbances (see Box 4.1).                            on the whole the ability of LAC's banking systems to efficiently
intermediate financial resources remains rather limited.21
Shallow Domestic Financial Markets                                  Capital markets, in turn, have experienced a rapid expan-
Despite the considerable progress made since the 1980s, LAC      sion in Latin America over the last decade, but they remain
financial markets remain shallow, and financial systems are    small and illiquid relative to those in other regions. Figure
still weak in many countries in the region."7 The poor func-    4.14 provides a comparative perspective on the size and
than would be observed if Chile were able to resort to inter-    crisis and experience fast domestic growth despite the large
national financial markets to navigate the disturbances.       international  credit  crunch  suffered  by  emerging
Figure 4.12 reinforces the conclusion that the fuinda-    economnies. This is confirmed in panel (b), which demon-
mental problem  is one of restricted access to international    strates that Chile used a large fraction of the "liquidity"
i financial markets. Panel (a) shows that the price of copper    given by the high price of copper to offset the decline in
and Chile's current account deficit are positively associ-    capital inflows, as the current account deficit at "normal"
i ated-exactly the reverse of what would be observed under    copper prices reached its highest level during that year.
smoothing of disturbances.                                     Most important, exactly the opposite occurred during the
The 1995 Tequila Crisis appears to be the exception          1998-99 episode, as the price of copper plummeted (eras-
that proves the rule because high copper prices gave the    ing Chile's liquidity) at the precise time that international
i Chilean economy enough 'liquidity" to ride through the    financial markets tightened.
.FIGURE 4,12
Copper Prices and Chil  Cun'ent Account
(a) Balance of Payments and Cooper Price                              (b) Current Account Deficit
15S                      *                       140           8_I
lID                                                                _ __ _ __ _ _ _   _ __-130 __ __7
110
0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 
.90n
680
-15~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~7
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-6o                              -2 
-15  19 87    189 1O 9t g19 199 149 1S9 g96 999 9899S  50    1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 199S 1996 1997 1998 199
86 87? 8, 81 9 909,  92 '91  '94   9 6 9? 98 ;99                          0- Actual CA. b,IfkkiuNnoCADli
aCuamA,coaDelidt - ca ft9pi lqflo,    Ca  Fie|
Soa,Isrs Iritituto National de Elcadfgtica and Banco Centra dt Chile.
53



SECURING (ITR FiTUJRF iN A GLOBAL FCONOMY
FIGURE 41 1
Average Private Domestic Credit
(Percent of GDP, Regional Medians)
120 -
.6o-                                                                                                    19705         1996,,
80 
C~~
-60
40-
20 -
0                                        611li
Industrial Economies   East Asia and    Latin America and   Middle Easr and  South Asia    Sub-Saharan Africa   Other East Asia
Pacific 7      the Caribbean     North Africa                                           and Pac fic
FIGURE 4 14
Stock Market Capitalization and Turnover Ratios
(Regional Medians in Percent, 1990-98))
s0 -                                                                                           Market Capitalization
70 -Turnover Ratios
60 -
,   50   .
40-
30-
20
10 
0 '
Industrial Economies    East Asia and Pacific 7   Latin America and            South Asia        Other Easc Asia andi Pacific
the Caribbean
turnover (measured respectively by market capitalization as    end, Brazil possesses a fairly liquid market, but its overall size
percent of GDP, and the ratio of value traded to market capi-    is modest by international standards.
talization) of equity markets across world regions.22 The clear
message is that LAC is lagging behind the rest of the world in       The Combination Increases the Likelihood of Economic
both dimensions. Figure 4.15 shows that there is considerable        Crises
diversity among the major economies in the region. At one            The imperfections of LAC's financial markets severely limit
extreme, Chile's market size is at or above industrial-country       their ability to diversify risk and reallocate financial resources
levels, but its market liquidity is extremely low. At the other    at times of distress. This tends to amplify and propagate
54



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
FIGURE 4.15
Stock Market Capitalization and Turnover Ratios for Seected LAC Countiles, 199-98, Averages
120 -
Market Capitalization
100 
*Turnover Ratio
80 
C~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
8   60  -
40-
20
0
Argentina      Brazil        Chile        Colombia       Ecuador       Mexico         Peru        Venezuela
adverse disturbances by creating wasteful contractions in sec-    ables are measured by their averages over the last three
tors most affected by shocks or relatively poorly connected to    decades. A negative association between both variables is
domestic and international financial pipelines. This propaga-    obvious from the figure.25 The relationship, however, appears
tion effect is particularly evident in the case of the banking    nonlinear, as indicated by the solid line-of-best-fit.26 Thus,
system. As adverse shocks put domestic firms in distress, lead-    increased size of financial systems is associated with reduced
ing some of them to bankruptcy, the credit portfolio of the    economic volatility, but the association becomes less strong as
banking system deteriorates, lowering the ability and willing-    the financial system becomes very large.27
ness of banks to bear risk and channel financial resources effi-  This implies a qualification regarding the stability-
ciently. Some borrowers may be completely excluded from the    enhancing role of financial markets-the danger posed by
credit market, exacerbating the magnitude of the downturn.    excessive indebtedness. As financial systems expand, so does
When the banking system's balance sheet is already weak, this   leverage, and with it the vulnerability of the financial system
sequence of events can bring banks to the verge of financial   to shocks also increases. Rapid expansion of financial systems,
collapse, and take sound borrowers along with them.            particularly if inadequately regulated and supervised, can also
Weak capital markets also amplify the effects of shocks. In    contribute to economic volatility, a factor that played a cru-
a manner similar to the credit rationing effect of weak bank-
ing systems just described, they result in what may be termed  Stock Market Illiquidity
"1equity rationing"; that iS, the inability of firms to raise funds
"ntheequity ro  "arket wis,the inabit   pofifirtoise higd     (Regression Coefficient of Absolute Price Changes on Trade
in the equity market without incurring prohibitively high      Volume)
costs. Moreover, thin markets also result in large fluctuations
in equity prices, as shown by Figure 4.16, which compares       1.0
the sensitivity of equity prices to trading volume in Chile23-  0.9 _
0.8 
the LAC economy with the largest stock market-and three         0.7 -
industrial economies. The result is that firms are unable to    0.6 -
diversify their risks well through equity markets.24            0.5 -
The association between underdeveloped financial mar-        0.4-
kets and economic instability is clearly brought out by inter-  0.3 -
national evidence. As an illustration, Figure 4.17 plots the    0.2 -
stock of private sector credit as a ratio to GDP against GDP    0.1 -
growth volatility for a large number of countries. The vari-             Chile       Australia    Norway    United States
55



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 4.17
GOP Volatiliy and Credit Depth
180 -
160 -
140 -
U     \~~~~
P, 120-
o  100-    
80                    U
�  80-                  
;  60-
WA W~~~~U 
20        ,   .ji  I         _                               __
0                      U~~~~ea   
WCfo                5%                  10%                 15%                  20%                 25%
GDP Growth Volatility
cial role in the East Asian crisis of 1997-98. It is ironic that   enced a severe credit crunch following the 1995 Tequila Cri-
several LAC economies have suffered at both ends of the spec-   sis. Loans-especially new loans-collapsed early in the cri-
trum of financial development: chronic financial repression    sis, especially as the peso went into free fall, dragging down
and underdevelopment first, followed by accelerated expan-   the already weak balance sheets of Mexican banks. Thie severe
sion and collapse of the banking system later. Deficient bank    credit crunch amplified the magnitude of the crisis, and the
monitoring and supervision played a major role in these    collapse of the banking system imposed massive costs on the
boom-bust episodes.                                       economy and the public sector accounts.
A second important qualification is that the causation may  In Argentina, in contrast, the amplification developed from
run the other way too: high economic volatility itself tends to   the other side of banks' balance sheets. Figure 4. 18 shows that
hamper financial market development. In a highly volatile   in Argentina the major force behind the credit crunch was the
environment, firms may not be willing to undertake the risks    run on bank deposits, driven by depositors' fears that tight
associated with extensive borrowing, nor may households    external conditions would eventually result in the collapse of
wish to save in financial assets (at least those available domes-   the system of convertibility between Argentina's peso and the
tically). Without appropriate policy action, the economy may    U.S. dollar. The figures also illustrate how the financial tur-
get stuck in a self-perpetuating vicious circle characterized by    moil in world markets during 1998-99 resulted in new credit
weak financial markets that amplify volatility, which in turn    slowdowns in Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico.
prevents further financial market development.               Beyond their shock magnification effect, however,
In the LAC context, the interplay between weak links    domestic and external financial weaknesses are also sources
with international financial markets and underdeveloped    of instability themselves, because they raise the likelihood
domestic financial systems may be key to the region's aggre-   that as-yet unrealized disturbances will have a major dis-
gate volatility (see Box 4.2). A closer look at recent crises in   ruptive effect on the economy, triggering precautionary
the region may help illustrate this. Figures 4.18, 4.19, and    responses by the government or the private sector that
4.20 show credit crunches in three major countries in the    anticipate the crisis. An example of this is the case in which
region that have followed episodes of external distress. Most   policymakers foresee a tightening of external financing,
striking is the case of Mexico (Figure 4.20), which experi-    which leads them to contract monetary and/or fiscal policy,
56



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
FIGURE 4.18
Credit Crunches in Argentina
80 -
70      _      |    Credit to the Private Sector
60-|   Deposits                                                                              - - - - - - - - -
60 -
C
50
c30 - 
20-
10 
0 
_           l              l      ~      ~ I      I              I              I              I
Janl994        Oct1994       July1995       ApriL1996       Janl997        Oct1997       July1998       April1999
FIGURE 4.19
Credit Crunches in Brazil
250 -
200 -
IJ                    __~~------------------------__
C
150 -
-5
0
100 
50 -                                                                             - | _   Credit to the Private Sector
-Deposits
O -     I   I    I    I    I    I    I    I   I    I    l    I    I    I    I    I    I   I    I    I    I    I
~O  \7~  ON ON ~N   '~   N ~N   '0   N \0    '.0 N       cNo   00  00 0 0 ON N ON N
O   ON  f'  g          <     -$    t g                                   wR        U $      D g $ t
driving the economy into recession ahead of the feared    system considerably raises the likelihood of success of such
external tightening. Likewise, the private sector often    speculative attacks and their economic cost.
reacts to an anticipated tightening of the external financial
bottleneck by running against domestic assets, thus dri-    Other Amplification Mechanisms
ving down asset prices and forcing a tightening of macro-    Beyond the financial system, other policy and institutional
economic policies-a scenario similar to the Argentine    factors also play an important role in magnifying or con-
episode of 1995. Needless to say, a weak domestic financial    taining the economic impact of shocks.
57



SECURING OLR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 4.20
Credit Cnunches in Mexico
700
_                                                      ____ G~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Cedit to the Private Setor
c "' ^vs s s s s s s _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Deposits
500
0
o 400
o 300 -
7: 200-
100 
O- ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~      ~~~~~~    - I. I. I  I           III 
.S  g    k        R        t        @        @         @        S' N    'O       'O
Fiscal policy has traditionally been assigned an "auto-    ible rates allow monetary independence and are best
matic stabilizer" function, which consists of offset-     for protecting the economy from real disturbances.30
ting shocks by expanding aggregate demand in the          In recent years, LAC has witnessed a shift toward
face of contractionary disturbances and, conversely,      both ends of the exchange regime spectrum: rigid
in the case of expansionary disturbances. In LAC (and     pegs (for example, currency boards as in Argentina,
in much of the developing world), however, fiscal         and proposals for outright dollarization in Argentina
policy is often procyclical, adding to the expansion      and Ecuador), and freely floating arrangements
during booms and to the contraction during reces-         (Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru). The
sions.8 Thus, a policy risk is inadvertently added to     experience of developing countries, notably in LAC
economic risk, amplifying the effects of economic         and East Asia, over the last decade or so has added
shocks rather than offsetting them. To some extent        some important qualifications to this conventional
this again reflects the operation of financing con-       wisdom. First, the degree of monetary independence
straints, since at times of adverse shocks govern-        allowed by flexible exchange rates may be limited in
ments face sharp reductions in their access to exter-     practice if firms and banks hold large unhedged lia-
nal financing  or large increases in its cost.29          bilities in foreign currency, because under such con-
Procyclicality also reflects the failure of governments   ditions exchange rate fluctuations can have large
to provide for bad times by increasing their saving       effects on firms and banks' net worth, as in the East
during good times, when revenues are high. A stark        Asia crisis.31 Second, the ability of flexible rates to
example of this failure has been the frequent mis-        ease the adjustment to real disturbances depends on
management of resource booms in countries whose           the credibility attached by the private sector to mon-
pLublic sector is heavily dependent on natural             etary policy and on the extent of inflationary inertia
resource revenues.                                        due, for example, to formal or informal indexation.
* Exchange rate and monetary policy also shape the econ-     Lack of credibility and widespread indexation may
omy's ability to weather shocks. The conventional         erode much of the real effect of nominal devaluation
prescription is that pegged exclhange rates provide       through additional inflation.32 Third, hard pegs may
the best insulation against financial shocks, and flex-    enhance financial stability and policy credibility.
58



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
BOX 4.2
IWak Funancial Markets and VolatiOly: A Framework
The interplay between weak international financial links    financing (flat at the discount factor 1 until the maxi-
and underdeveloped domestic financial systems may be at   mum  amount AtAt is reached, at which point supply
the root of much of LAC's aggregate volatility. Here we    becomes vertical), is enough to meet the needs of dis-
present a stylized framework outlining the key mecha-   tressed firms (the solid line that becomes vertical at the
nism, drawing from  work by Caballero and Krishna-    economy's total number of projects, set at unity). Thus,
murty (1999).                                            equilibrium is reached at L = 1, so that the domestic cost
T- e Basic Setup                                         of funds equals the world interest rate, and distressed
The  Xasic Setup                                         firms pledge only a fraction of their assets to the "inter-
i Consider a schematic timeline such that at date 0, which    d        h       t  i             a
corresponds to "normal" times, investment decisions are
made and agents plan toward the "bright future" of date   eral In panel (b), however, international collateral falls
2. Much of this planning has to do with anticipating and    short of the needs of distressed firms. The result is a fre
sale of domestic assets, with the cost of domestic funds
preventing a crisis that can happen in the near future at
period 1. Weak international links imply that the coun-   jumping to L > 1, and only a fraction AtAt of all projects
try may have a hard time persuading foreign financiers    getting financed.
that they will share the gains in a relatively bright future
(period 2) if they help to avert the period 1 crisis.    Weak International Link* Shallow Domestic
In this context, a crisis is a situation in which the    Markets, and Excess Vulnerability
economy needs substantial external funds (to repay debt   If, unlike in Figure 4.21, domestic financial markets are
or undertake new investments) but does not have suffi-   also imperfect-in the sense that distressed firms can-
cient international collateral to obtain them. To make    not fully pledge their assets to the domestic intermedi-
this insufficiency of collateral clear, assume that nontrad-    aries holding the internationally-acceptable collat-
able date 2 assets (for example, buildings that would be    eral-the latter's incentive to hoard and  supply
completed at date 2), denoted An, are of no interest to   international liquidity is lessened. In the model, the
foreigners-they cannot be used as collateral abroad.   domestic price of this liquidity L falls. This situation is I
However, they can be used as collateral to borrow domes-   shown in Figure 4.22 by assuming that only a fraction
tically, at a discount factor L, a maximum of APL- This    An < 1 of domestic collateral can be pledged. This shifts
collateral is held by the "distressed>' firms.. 
collateral is held by the "distressed" firms.            down the effective demand schedule (solid line) in panel
In turn, other domestic firms or individuals hold
(a), leading to a decline in L relative to Figure 4.21.
internationally acceptable collateral, denoted At, which
Frictions ins dornestic financial markets now distort the
includes items like the output of firms in the tradable
return to holding international collateral, and as a result
goods sector at date 2, plus foreign currency assets, plus
less will be held by the intermediaries supplying inter-
perhaps some domestic assets attractive to foreigners,
such as telecom firms. Assuming that the international   national liquidity
discount factor equals 1-or the interest rate equals 0-     This is shown in panel (b) of Figure 4.22 as an inward
the most the country can borrow abroad at date 1. is AtAt,  shift in the supply of international liquidity. The reduced
where At < 1, because of imperfect access to the world   supply means that the economy will experience more fre-
capital market.                                          quent fire sales and more severe distress in the face of
international disturbances. The economy becomes too
Weak International Links and Fire Sales                  vulnerable to external shocks due to the undervaluation
Figure 4.21 shows the equilibrium  in the economy's   of international liquidity created by domestic financial
financial market. In panel (a), the supply of international   market imperfections.
59



SECURING OtUR FUTUJRE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
:m~~~~~~~~~~ HdM! N1
iVMW2200-e        SOR16..l 1......
; Ads  i0ski   i  g  t                                          a 33 gi   gS0f  3fX W 
.M9Ig.8llt.gitsilg}( l}s gWe 0 sg } Wg Ws gS atx W W 10 X 0 W 0 tW~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~i
r   -    U   0-f jl,3s,�Se' :t.   n -r  X .n..  . u. -  * '  .Hi ~W
*  c>5ylsae�x     ..        -3     }:: -    I3i  NM1  
;'''';'W'W; W;W  WW  ; }W  I;WWWWWWW4W   W;  SsSO(RW   EMPg
< ' ^;4--0,U'-<-<d'- 0'lk'0,0  9- - 'lE '  ' 0x.}u  -" ". 0Ag0',''iH
. . .X. W   D  O si D 1e D cas ax  W   WW W WW WW WW W WW    ww~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ .. ... ..
60



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILfTY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIFS
However, when combined with nominal rigidities    regions. It uses industrial countries and the East Asia mir-
(in wages or other prices) they can make adjustment   acle economies as a benchmark for the comparison. As has
to real disturbances slow and costly, as shown by    been shown, LAC's GDP volatility exceeds that in each of
Argentina's experience.                              these regions by a considerable margin.34
Labor market rigidities tend to magnify the cost of real  The results show that LAC's higher growth volatility
disturbances, by forcing the labor market to adjust   relative to industrial and East Asian miracle countries
through unemployment rather than real wages and    arises from three main sources: the region's higher terms-
sectoral redeployment of the labor force. The notable    of-trade volatility, the higher volatility of its macroeco-
example is again Argentina, where lack of adjust-   nomic policy, and its weaker financial links with domestic
ment of real wages has in effect created another    and foreign markets. Of all these factors, terms of trade
source of pressure on firms in addition to the credit   shocks account for one-fourth of the difference in GDP
squeeze that they suffered from financial markets.   growth volatility between LAC and the other regions. In
turn, monetary and fiscal policy volatility combined
Summary                                                   account for over one-third of the cross-regional difference
The preceding discussion has identified a number of key    in volatility. Latin America's lower degree of external finan-
factors behind aggregate volatility in LAC. How impor-   cial integration than the other regions' (measured by the
tant is the contribution of each to the region's overall eco-   volume of capital inflows plus outflows relative to GDP)
nomic instability? To answer this question, we combine    accounts for another 20 percent. Volatility of capital flows
those factors into an empirical quantitative model aimed    also contributes to LAC's higher GDP growth volatility
at explaining long-term volatility. The results are briefly   than in the other regions, but only a small amount. Finally,
discussed here; the model is described in more detail in   the smaller size of LAC's domestic financial markets (as
Annex L.3" The empirical model characterizes the rela-    measured by the ratio of private credit to GDP) accounts
tionships between external volatility, policy volatility, and    for another substantial portion of the difference in volatil-
financial depth. In spite of its simplicity, the model does a    ity. Combined, all these factors account for roughly 95 per-
good job of explaining observed growth volatility, and    cent of the difference in income growth volatility between
accounts for close to 60 percent of the variation in the lat-    LAC and the other regions, leaving only a small portion to
ter across countries.                                     be explained by the relatively higher presence of oil-
The role of the various sources of volatility is described    exporting economies in LAC (which appear to display an
in Figure 4.23, which identifies the factors that make the    extra degree of volatility not captured well by other eco-
average LAC  country more volatile than other world    nomic variables) and a tiny unexplained residual. Thus,
external factors, domestic policies, and financial market
FIGURE 4.23                                               underdevelopment all contribute to LAC's economic
Why is Latin America more Volatile than Industrial and East  volatility.35
Asian Countries?                                             These results, while illustrative, also bring out the
forces behind the observed improvement in LAC's growth
Residudl
Oil (1)                                volatility in the 1990s relative to the 1980s. Improving
(617 )                                 external conditions-less volatile terms of trade and capi-
iscal voa                             trade shocks     tal flows-expanding  financial markets at home and
15   SM           _                           abroad, and more stable domestic policies, have all been
contributing factors to the reduced instability of the 1990s
Financial depth                       Capital flow volatility   relative to the 1980s.
(12 o)                                  (4%)
Policies to Deal with Aggregate Volatility in LAC
Money growth volatility  What should be done to deal with LAC's aggregate volatil-
Capital flow volum                   9              ity? Aggregate risk is not diversifiable within the domestic
(19 '/)                                        economy-since it affects all domestic economic actors-
61



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
but it can be shared internationally if not all countries suf-   domestic economies. It is enough that they not be affected
fer the same shocks at the same time. International diver-   identically by the same disturbances. In this manner, cop-
sification would allow countries to eliminate their country-    per exporters could share in the incomes of copper
specific  risk, so  that they  would  face  only  the    importers, countries specialized in agricultural products
undiversifiable global risk of worldwide income fluctua-    would trade part of their future incomes for those of coun-
tions. This issue has received much attention in recent   tries specialized in manufactures, and so on. By pursuing
years, because if nations diversified optimally their con-   this strategy, countries could entirely diversify away their
sumption risk they would all end up with very similar   idiosyncratic risks, and remain exposed only to global risks.
(strictly speaking, perfectly correlated) consumption pro-    In the case of LAC, international risk-sharing along
files, a theoretical implication which is clearly contradicted    these lines would allow a considerable reduction in the
by the facts.                                              volatility of consumption, resulting in a potentially very
In essence, to achieve international diversification,   large welfare gain. Box 4.3 computes the gain that would
domestic economic actors would purchase claims on the    have accrued to LAC countries had they been able to com-
risky future incomes of foreign workers and firms, and sell   pletely diversity their idiosyncratic aggregate risks in the
claims on their own risky incomes. It is important to note    1990s. The calculations suggest the region's median wel-
that, for this to be a risk-reducing strategy, the incomes of   fare gain would have been equivalent to a permanent
foreign economies need not be less risky than those of   increase in the level of consumption around 7 percent per
t._, ~~~~-   ,-  __- .- ---.-. ------  - - -      --- ._- _- .U-- -.   ----- -l --_- - -.-- - ..-- - _-.- -  - -.E   _- -_. - -  .---   -     -_.-.__- - _  _-.-_
'he WeHare Cost of Volatility and the Gains fom Intemationai Risk4Shaftng
iany countries experience a high degree of volatility in   rik and the amount of risk that could be eliminated by I
theit consumption path. To the extent that their citizens    diversificationhe ltter factor plays the key role in deter-
care about risk, their welfare would improve by reducing    mning the size of potential welre gains. In adon,
consumption voatity  This can be achievd through    ths also depend on the imlicit risk-free interest rate andd
international risk-sharing, which would allow counries    the riskajusted growth rate for the domestic economny.
to shelter their standard of living fiom shocks by-intr-    Finally, the time horizon also maatte: the longer the time
nationa diversification of their portfolios              Whrizon, the gteater the benefits of hedging.
If countries were optimally divered;, they woud           The caLculationm  presented here follow an approach
fully eliminate the idiosyta  (or cuntry-specific) risk    recently proposed by Arhanas s and Van Wincoop
they face, so that they wouWl remain subject only to   (2000), from  whkh we take most paameter vaus.
g&b4 or worldwide, risk. As a resut, the csmion    Specifically, the riskfee real interest rate is 0.85 percent,
paths of all countries woud become closey correlated.   the average growth rate of per capita consumption is 2.35
This is obviously not the case in reality, whic provides    perent, and the coeffient of relative risk-aversion is 3.
proof of inufficient intetnational diversifition. Of   Undiversiiabe or global risk is taken from  the same
course, one reason fbr this could be that the welfare   source and is set at 0.00000225. For each countqry the
gains from better diversification are simply too small to    countr ecific, diversifiable risk is then the difference
imake this worthwhile. This possibilit  is explod    between the variance of its respective growth rate of con-
below                                                     sumption and this undiversifiable ris. For illustrative
purposes, we use the vadance of cotlsuption growth of
Q  antfig Wlfare Gais                                     each comutry during the 1990s. Firnally, the welfare gain
The magnitude of the welfire gain from  internaton        is computed f4r a horizon of 55 years and, m  e
jivrsification depeds primarily on the dgree of risk    with tradition, Is express  as the permanenat percentage 
aversion (that is, how much vale is attributedt to reducing    iease in exeted consumption.
62



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
Table 4.2 assesses the welfare gains that would have           It is important to insist that this type of calculation
been accrued to each country had it been able to diversify    only highlights direct welfare gains. Large as they may
its idiosyncratic aggregate volatility in the 1990s. The    seem for LAC, for several reasons these figures still under-
table shows that the potential welfare gains would have    state the true benefits of international risk-sharing. First,
been quite substantial for most LAC  countries. The    investment in risky assets with  high returns would
regional median exceeds 7 percent-a figure similar to    increase once risk is diversified away, which should raise
those implied by van Wincoop (1999) for non-OECD              growth and contribute to secondary-level gains (Obstfeld
economies, but about 6 times as high as the average for    1994). Second, portfolio diversification would reduce the  j
OECD countries.                                               incentives to  use second-best distortionary  measures
(such as trade barriers) as risk-protection devices. Finally,
TAE8LE 4.2                                                    risk diversification would allow financial markets to bet-
Esfimated Welfare Gains from DivfsIfcatoan
ter fulfill their related functions of consumptiorf-smooth- ~i
(Latin America and the Caribbean, Percent of Private Annual
Consumption)                                                  ing and optimal resource allocation.
cCOUNTY                                                       Operationalizing Risk-Sharting
Argentina                                        9.55         How would international risk-sharing be implemented?
Bolivia                                         0.06         One conceptually simple way would be for residents in
Brazil                                           6.99
!CGbile                                          3.71         the different countries to trade claims on their respective
| Colombia                                       1.01         risky national incomes. For example, residents of devel-
Costa Rica                                       2.95
Dominican Republic                              22.39         oping countries would sell claims on their GDP and buy
Ecuador                                          0.02         claims on the GDP of industrial countries or other devel-
El Salvador                                     13.65
oping economies. Since not all economies suffer the same
iGuatermala                                       0.27
Honduras                                         1.09         shocks at the same time, the result of this portfolio diver-
t Jamaica                                       79.05          sification would be a reduction in the risk faced by eco-
Mexico                                           8.49
Nicarggua                                       63.35         nomic actors in each country. This is far from  reality, I
Panama                                          30.28         however. At present, existing markets only allow trade in
Paraguay                                        45.97
Pemaguay                                        4649          claims on firm  dividends, which are a minor share of
Trinidad and Tobago                             97.01         income in most countries, and ideally it would be neces-
Veneuegay                                        8.58         sary to develop  'macro markets" to trade such national
il Venezuiela                                      6.48,,|
Mean                                            20.37         income claims.
Median                                           7.74            If the potential welfare gains that such markets would
Indatriaze Ero7omis Mean1.7
1.17        allow are so large, why are they not already in operation?
Smnaler CoantriM.                                             Their establishment involves a "public good" aspect that
Baelzas                                          _            would prevent private firms and individuals from captur-
Belize                                           7.54
I Barbados                                         6.80          ing the benefits of market introduction, even though
Guyana                                          27.58         they would have to bear the costs. Problems of measure-
Mean                                            13.03
Medan                                           13.03         ment of national incomes and enforcement of market
Median                                           7.64
contracts would also be substantial. Finally, benefits of
Ovsrall Mean                                    19.13         risk-sharing  are far greater for the  more volatile
Ovcrall Median                                   7.02g
economies, and these economies are not necessarily the
Mmte: Variances are over sample period 1990-99. For Argentina and Barbados, total    ones best positioned to lead in the creation of new mar-
consumption has been used. Tine horizon is 35 yeaes.
Saanre World Bank staff calculations based on Arhanasoulis and van Wincoop (2000).    kets that would be trusted by investors.
63



SECUIRING OTIR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
year-well above the corresponding figure for the average           total wealth, of a large group of industrial and developing
industrial economy. The more volatile economies in LAC             countries.36 Even for industrial economies, claims on cap-
would of course have benefited more from  risk diversifica-    ital held abroad are only about 5 percent of total wealth
tion, because they would have been able to more greatly    in the 1990s; domestic capital held by foreigners is of a
reduce the variability of their consumption path, so their    similar magnitude. For developing economies, the figures
estimated gains would have been much bigger.                       are even smaller-less than 0.5 percent and about 3 per-
If the gains from  international diversification are so         cent, respectively.
large, why is it not already taking place? The answer is              In addition, other existing  market-based insurance
that the necessary financial instruments and the markets           mechanisms for aggregate risks are limited in scope.`
to trade them  simply do not exist. At present, organized          Even with better-developed markets, however, the insur-
markets around the world only allow trade in the equity            ance decisions of private individuals would likely lead to
of a handful of firms accounting for a small fraction of    underinsuring anyway, because they do not take into
world output. In other words, asset trading is limited to          account the fact that their individual actions may collec-
the sale and purchase of legal claims on the future profits    tively add to economywide risk.38 These facts call for
of these firms, which represent a minuscule fraction of    policy action to deal with aggregate risks.
world incomes. And the available evidence shows that the              At the level of the national economy, what policies
degree of diversification generated by such trading  is    and institutions can help reduce aggregate volatility?
small. Table 4.3 presents the portfolio shares, relative to        Three broad  types of measures can be distinguished,
TABLE 4,3
International Portfolio Diversification
(Ratios to Total Wealth)
1966-73            1974-81            1982-89            1990-97            1966-97
Weighted Average
Industrial Countries
Foreign assets                           0.013              0.007              0.000              -0.006              0.004
Capital owned by foreigners              0.025              0.024               0.029              0.042              0.033
Capital held abroad                      0.028               0.029              0.032              0.053              0.039
Grosslending                             0.041              0.061               0.124              0.158              0.112
Gross borrowing                          0.031              0.059              0.127               0.175              0.114
Developing countries
Foreign assets                          -0.099              -0.037             -0.081             -0.065             -0.068
Capital owned by foreigners              0.039              0.022               0.023              0.029              0.028
Capital held abroad                      0.004              0.002               0.002              0.005              0.003
Gross lending                            0.024              0.060               0.048              0.041              0.045
Gross borrowing                          0.088               0.077              0.108              0.082              0.088
Median
Industrial Countries
Foreign assets                           -0.011            -0.028              -0.025             -0.037             -0.016
Capital owned by foreigners              0.021              0.021               0.030              0.061              0.035
Capital held abroad                       0.007              0.007              0.023              0.053              0.028
Gross lending                            o.046              0.050               0.119              0.140              0.105
Gross borrowing                          0.044               0.083              0.161              0.199              0. 145
Developing countries
Foreign assets                           -0.120             -0.116             -0.167             -0.139             -0.137
Capital owned by foreigners              0.039              0.027               0.031              0.033              0.035
Capital held abroad                      0.000              0.000               0.000              0.001              0.0(1
Gross lending                            0.028              0.043               0.045              0.056              0.051
Gross borrowing                          0.105              0.128               0.174              0.155              0.160
Note. Weighted averages are computed over an unbalanced panel of eight-year averages for 68 countries. As a result, to a small extent changes across periods reflect changes irn the
composition of the sarnple. Results using a smaller balanced panel are similar.
64



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
respectively aimed at increasing (market) insurance, self-    Terms of Trade Risk
insurance, and self-protection against aggregate distur-    As with other aggregate disturbances, risk diversification
bances. Dealing effectively with macroeconomic risks    provides the best response to terms of trade volatility.
requires a comprehensive strategy combining all three    Diversification could be achieved by selling to foreigners
types of measures.                                               the rights to a part of the country's income from the future
An overview of policies in each of these areas to deal    sale of commodities. Then domestic agents will not have to
with specific sources of aggregate volatility is outlined in     bear the full brunt of its volatility and can hold other assets
Table 4.4. Rather than being comprehensive, the table's   instead. In this regard, the boom of foreign investment in
purpose is to illustrate the various alternatives available    LAC in recent years plays, in part, a risk-reducing role or
to governments to tackle the sources and amplification           self-protection-augmenting role.39
mechanisms of macroeconomic volatility. Because labor               Hedging in international futures markets-for exam-
markets are examined again later in this report, we defer    ple, by selling tomorrow's copper or oil output at prices
until then discussion of measures targeted at them. It is    known today-is another way to diversify terms of trade
important to keep in mind that some policies serve more    risk. In spite of their expansion over recent years, however,
than one purpose-they  may address more than one    futures markets remain limited in size, futures prices often
source of instability, or combine two or more of the    fluctuate widely, and trading concentrates on short-term
insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection aspects.          instruments. Currently, they offer limited scope for diver-
Finally, the risk management policies reviewed below          sification over longer horizons.
entail implicit and explicit economic costs. This does not          Given the limitations of insurance markets, several LAC
mean they should not be undertaken, but rather that it    countries (for example, Chile and Colombia) have resorted to
is important to take such costs into consideration when          self-insurance, in the form of commodity stabilization funds,
assessing policy options. The cost and effectiveness of the    to deal with terms of trade risk. Such funds are designed to
various options depend on the economy's overall struc-    accumulate resources at times of high commodity prices and
ture and institutional framework, so the optimal policy          run them down when prices fall below a predetermined "ref-
mix will differ across countries. The discussion below is    erence" level. Unlike insurance mechanisms, stabilization
meant to provide a guide or starting point for assessing         funds do not involve any diversification of risk, only a pre-
the different alternatives.                                      cautionary transfer of resources from  good to bad states.
TABLE 4.4
An Overview of Policies to Deal with Aggregate Volatility
pOLICY
SOURCE/AMPLIFIER
OF VOLATILITY                            INSURANCE                      SELF-INSURANCE                 SELF-PROTECTION
Terms of trade                 * International portfolio         * Stabilization funds          * Trade diversification
diversification                                               * Trade taxes/subsidies
* Hedging
International capital flows    * Contingent credit lines        * Liquidity hoarding            * Debt management
* Limits on current account gaps
* Capital controls
Financial system               * Facilitate risk divcrsification  * Enhanced capital and liquidity  * Adequate bank regulation and
through capital market           requirements for banks         supervision
development                    * Deposit insurance            * Avoidance of portfolio
* Internationalization of the                                      mismatches
banking system
Fiscal policy                                                    * Precautionary targets and    * Tax base diversification
contingent rules             * Public debt management
Monetary and exchange rate policy                               * Clear and transparent exchange rate/monetary rules
* Balance flexibility against credibility
65



SECURfNG OLIR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
They entail opportunity costs from the returns foregone by    the action of international investors' portfolio diversifica-
holding those resources in the form of short-term  assets   tion rules that limit the share of financing suppliecl to spe-
rather than longer-term, higher-yield investments.        cific countries or regions.
Reducing the economy's exposure to terms of trade dis-    Countries can also self-insure against capital flow shifts
turbances (that is, self-protection) is another way to limit   by hoarding international liquidity, in the form of' foreign
their potential damage. One way in which this may be    exchange reserves and short-term assets, and reduce expo-
achieved is through export diversification, which reduces    sure (that is, self-protect) to unanticipated capital flow
the impact of commodity price fluctuations by lowering    shifts by managing external borrowing so as to prevent
the degree of concentration of exports in a few primary    accumulation of large short-term  liabilities and 'bunch-
commodities. Diversification is often a natural result of the    ing" of repayments. Importantly, such strategy should
removal of bad policies-trade barriers or overvalued    involve both public and private borrowing, because it is
exchange rates-imposing an anti-export bias in the eco-   the repayment schedule of the country as a whole that mat-
nomic framework.                                          ters-as shown by the East Asian crisis of 1997-and the
A related, but much more wasteful approach entails the    private sector may tend to overborrow at short maturi-
use of trade barriers to isolate the economy from fluctua-   ties.41 Yet this strategy entails high costs, from both hold-
tions in world prices (see Eaton and Grossman 1985). This   ing large stocks of resources in short-term, low-yield
procedure, however, runs counter to diversification-it can    instruments, and borrowing at long maturities, which
impose a strong anti-export bias in the incentive structure   involve an interest premium.43
in addition to the efficiency cost of the distortions it cre-  A more direct form of sheltering the economy from dis-
ates. On the whole, these side effects make trade barriers   ruptions in capital flows is attempting to restrict: them.
counterproductive from the point of view of sheltering the    This can be achieved by limiting the economy's financing
economy from terms of trade risk.                         needs, keeping the current account balance within narrow
limits. While runaway current account deficits are a sure
Capital Flows                                             recipe for macroeconomic disaster, however, inflexible
Sudden reversals of international capital flows often leave    adherence to rigid current account targets tends to make
emerging market economies deprived of external financing    adjustment to adverse disturbances unduly harsh. At the
when they most need it. In the lack of developed market-   same time, it is no guarantee against sudden losses of con-
based mechanisms to insure against such risks, the inter-   fidence by international investors, as shown by the East
national financial institutions have often played a sub-    Asian crisis of 1997.
sidiary role by supplying additional liquidity in emergency  Capital controls-on inflows, outflows, or both-also
situations. But some market mechanisms are beginning to    aim directly at restricting international capital mobility. In
emerge. One example is that of contingent credit lines,   the aftermath of the Asia and Russia crises of recent years,
which are prearranged and can be drawn upon by the bor-   they have received renewed attention, in particular given
rower if needed. Mexico entered such an arrangement with   the Chilean experience with controls designed to have a
a group of private banks in 1997 and drew upon it in 1998    stronger deterrent effect on short-term inflows, which are
following a deterioration in oil prices and external financ-    conventionally deemed the most volatile.44 From the theo-
ing.40 The potential role of international financial institu-    retical perspective, the drawback of capital controls is that
tions in this area is also highlighted by the case of   they distort intertemporal saving and investment: deci-
Argentina, the access of which to financial markets in 1999    sions, and hamper the efficient allocation of capital across
was facilitated by a World Bank policy-based guarantee on    countries.45 From the practical perspective, the effective-
repayments.4'                                             ness of capital controls in deterring flows beyond the
While contingent credit arrangements are a promising    immediate future remains hotly debated-many argue that
phenomenon, their implications remain to be fully estab-    private investors sooner or later find ways to circumvent
lished. Specifically, it is not yet clear whether such arrange-   the controls. There seems to be some agreement, however,
ments represent genuinely additional financing, or just   that controls may succeed in altering the composition of
substitute for more conventional forms of financing, under   flows.46
66



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LAItN AMERICA AND IHE 5AKIBBEAN: CAUSES ANI) REMEI)I ES
The Financial System                                      high priority in the policy agenda. The first step, already
As noted earlier, the domestic financial system plays a dual   achieved in many of the region's economies, is to set pub-
role. It allows risk diversification through capital mar-   lic finances on a sustainable path. To reduce aggregate
kets-mainly for idiosyncratic risks, but also for aggregate   volatility, however, it is also necessary to allow fiscal policy
risks if foreigners participate in the market. It also provides   to carry out a countercyclical role. To a large extent, this
the means to efficient self-protection against risk by indi-    will only be assured with development of stronger external
viduals and firms.                                        financial links and deeper domestic financial markets.
In LAC, enhancing the first of these two functions    However, specific steps can be taken to reduce the impact
requires development of deeper capital markets open to for-   of shocks on the fiscal accounts and the amplifier role
eigners. This in turn raises the need for regulatory reforms    played by fiscal policy.
aimed at improving firms' transparency and accountability    Effective implementation of precautionary targets, and
and enhancing corporate governance. In the banking sys-   contingent fiscal rules that create room for action in bad
tem, in particular, one way to diversify risk internationally   times by accumulating resources during good times should
that has been cmployed by several LAC countries is to allow    be at the top of the policy agenda. Precautionary schemes
entry of foreign banks, the overall portfolios of which are   to accumulate fiscal revenues in good times and run them
less subject to the risks affecting domestic banks. The other   down in bad times-as in the case of Chile's and Colom-
side of the coin is that foreign banks might increase finan-   bia's stabilization funds-are a good example. However,
cial contagion by retrenching in the domestic market when   these rules should ideally be extended to all revenues, not
hit by adverse developments in other markets.             only to those derived from natural resources. In addition,
As argued earlier, weak banks tend to amplify shocks    adoption of contingent rules relating fiscal policy to devel-
rather than help absorb them. They hamper efficient self-   opments in the terms of trade, world capital markets, and
insurance against aggregate shocks by discouraging indi-   so forth would also speed up and facilitate management of
viduals from holding deposits and other banking system    shocks, especially if such rules are preannounced. Adequate
liabilities when the health of banks is perceived as suspect.   fiscal institutions and transparent budgetary procedures are
In such cases, they are also vulnerable to losses of confi-   necessary to ensure that such systems work as intended,
dence. Maintenance of high capital and liquidity ratios can    and their resources are not misused for political objectives.
self-insure against such events. Such ratios should be    In this regard, Brazil's Fiscal Responsibility Law represents
higher the lesser the degree of financial market develop-   an important step in the right direction.
ment, and could be made procyclical-rising in economic       To limit the effects of disturbances on public revenues,
booms and falling in recessions. They are not without eco-   countries need to diversify their sources of fiscal revenues
nomic costs, however, because they will be reflected in    by expanding tax bases. This is particularly important in
higher costs of credit for borrowers. Deposit insurance can    economies whose public sectors are heavily dependent on
also raise savers' confidence in the banking system and thus    commodity revenues (such as Mexico or Venezuela). While
encourage saving, enhancing economywide self-insuirance    any tax system entails deadweight losses, the international
(it may also enhance self-protection by making the system    experience provides valuable hints on ways to limit such
less vulnerable to runs). To limit the impact of distur-   costs. Finally, management of the public sector's external
bances on the banking system, adequate prudential regula-    borrowing program along the lines described earlier could
tion and supervision of banks is also a high priority. In par-   also go a long way toward reducing fiscal vulnerability to
ticular, regulatory norms should aim  at avoidance of   financial shocks and, hence, fiscal and aggregate volatility.
unhedged currency mismatches in bank portfolios-mis-
matches that may arise directly in their balance sheets, or   Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy
indirectly through the balance sheets of their borrowers.  Regarding monetary and exchange policy, the key concern
is to strike a balance between flexibility and credibility.
Fiscal Policy                                             Hard pegs and flexible rates offer different advantages and
Unstable fiscal policies are perhaps at the core of LAC's   disadvantages in terms of self-protection and self-insurance
aggregate volatility. Ensuring fiscal stability is therefore of   against economywide risks. Flexible exchange rates and
67



SFCtiRING OUR Fl. lItRE IN A Gl OBlAL ECONOMY
independent monetary policy may help ease adjustment to   the meantime, the international financial institutions (IFIs)
real shocks, and thus reduce volatility. To deliver these ben-    could play a major role, along two dimnensions: first, by
efits, however, credible monetary policy should follow clear    explicitly deploying rheir lending anticyclically, to coun-
rules, which could be explicitly made contingent on exter-   teract in part the fluctuations in private capital flows; and
nal developments, to facilitate the management of shocks.    second, by helping expand the use of other insurance
Monetary independence may be curtailed by low credi-    mechanisms, such as contingent credit lines. Their provi-
bility, large private sector foreign currency liabilities, or   sion by the IFIs could serve as a catalyst for their further
extensive de facto dollarization, when most real and, espe-    development by the private sector. Enhanced use of these
cially, financial transactions are carried out in foreign cur-   or similar instruments by the IFls-such as the policy-
rency. In such cases, a rigidly pegged exchange rate may be    based guarantee recently obtained by Argentina--would
a preferable alternative to impose financial discipline and    serve to strengthen LAC's links with world financial mar-
establish credibility. Hlowever, it needs to be matched by    kets and address the core of its economic instability
well-managed fiscal policy and flexibility in labor markets,  Of course, important issues would need to be worked
since these become the major adjustment mechanisms to    out. Key among them would be designing these contin-
shocks in the absence of independent monetary tools. In    gent systems so that countries eligible to access them
addition, the absence of a lender of last resort that can help    would nevertheless retain strong incentives for sound eco-
domestic banks in the face of adverse disturbances will   nomic management so as to avoid moral hazard problems
require imposing high liquidity requirements on banks    that could hamper such implicit insurance schemes. Clear
(like in Argentina) to self-insure them against shocks.   definition of such policies, and design of adequate moni-
The upshot, however, is that there is no universally   toring mechanisms and certification procedures that deter-
valid exchange rate and monetary regime for LAC    mine a country's eligibility status, are a prerequisite for
economies. The key recommendation is to adopt simple   implementation of the system. These issues shoulcl be at
and transparent monetary and exchange rate rules, a pre-   the top of the international policy agenda.
condition to establish credibility (see Frankel, Schmukler,
and Serven 2000). Hard pegs-in the extreme, dollariza-    Annex 1
tion-or floating exchange regimes-as in Brazil, Chile,   This annex describes the methodology used in Figure 4.23
and Mexico-provide the best options in this regard.       to identify the contribution of different economic factors to
the "excess" aggregate volatility in Latin America-t-hat is,
Supranational Action                                      the difference between the region's growth volatility and
In a broad sense, international financial integration is too    that observed in industrial countries and the East Asian
limited rather than too broad. So far, it has not led to suf-    miracle economies.
ficient development of markets and instruments capable of    To perform the decompositions, we estimated empirical
providing adequate risk-sharing opportunities for develop-    equations relating GDP growth volatility during 1975-99
ing economies to diversify much of the risk they face.   (the period for which comprehensive data, particularly on
While some progress in this direction has been made in   capital flows, are available) to a number of variables dis-
recent years-with the expansion of world futures markets   cussed in the text, describing external and policy shocks
to trade commodity risks, and the emergence of contingent    and the depth of domestic and foreign financial markets.
credit lines supplied by private investors to countries like    Specifically, the explanatory variables include the standard
Mexico-deep international markets for insuring aggre-    deviations of terms of trade shocks, public consumption
gate risks remain a distant dream.                        growth, and reserve money growth; the coefficient of vari-
In this context of market imperfections, two lines of   ation of gross private capital flows; and, to capture domes-
supranational policy action could speed up the process   tic and foreign financial market depth, the logarithm of the
toward better international risk-sharing. Coordinated gov-    private credit/GDP ratio and the sum of private capital
ernment action could speed up the development of ade-   inflows and outflows relative to GDP. For credit, we use the
quate markets and instruments for international risk diver-   logarithm  to allow for the nonlinear effect on volatility
sification. This, however, is a long-term  undertaking. In    mentioned earlier in the text. In addition to these vari-
68



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN' CAUSES AND REMEDIES
ables, we also include a dummy variable taking the value          ting all financial factors. It can be seen that these "real" fac-
of unity for countries specialized in oil exports. All the        tors all significantly contribute to explaining growth volatil-
variables are constructed over 1975-99  or the longest    ity. Column 2 adds (the log of ) credit depth to the specifi-
period available within this time span.                           cation in column 1; it carries a negative and significant
The empirical sample includes all industrial and devel-    coefficient, suggesting that deeper donmestic financial sys-
oping countries outside of Eastern Europe and Central Asia    tems contribute to reducing volatility. Addition of the credit
with population above 250,000 in 1995 for which the nec-    variable, however, makes fiscal volatility insignificant, as
essary data were available. From  this initial sample, six        both variables display a high correlation (around -.50).
countries (Cameroon, Chad, Gabon, Jordan, Sri Lanka, and             Column 3 replaces domestic financial factors with for-
Syria) were dropped because they presented extreme values    eign ones, as represented by the volatility of gross private
for at least one of the variables of interest, which distorted    capital flows and their average volume (of inflows plus out-
the empirical results. This left a sample of 82 countries.        flows), both relative to GDP. The former carries a positive
Estimation results are presented  in Annex Table 1.    coefficient, as expected, while the latter carries a negative
Before reviewing them, some caveats should be noted.    cocfficient. Thus, given capital flow volatility, deeper finan-
Most important, some of the explanatory variables may be    cial integration  with  foreign  markets tends to reduce
themselves affected by growth volatility, so that the empir-    growth volatility, as argued in the text.
ical association detected here may not reflect exclusively           Column 4 in the table combines the preceding two by
their impact on growth volatility but partly also reverse    adding both domestic and foreign financial variables to the
causality flowing in the opposite direction. The methods    initial specification. This is the column used to construct
employed here (Ordinary Least Squares [OLS}) do not    Figure 4.23. Because of the relatively large cross-correla-
make any attempt to correct this problem. Some of the             tion already mentioned among some of the explanatory
explanatory variables are strongly correlated, making it    variables, two of them  are not individually significant-
difficult to  identify  their individual contributions to    the volatility of capital flows and the (log of) private credit.
explaining growth volatility.                                     However, when considered jointly, they are significant at
The table lists the regrcssion coefficients obtained using     the 10 percent level. This means that these two variables
alternative empirical specifications. Coefficients in italics    jointly make a significant contribution to explaining the
are statistically different from  zero at least at the 10 per-    observed variation in growth volatility across countries,
cent confidence level.                                            even though their individual contributions cannot be accu-
Column 1 starts with a specification including only terms    rately estimated. For this reason, the calculations in Figure
of trade shocks and macroeconomic policy volatility, omit-    4.23 should be viewed as illustrative rather than definitive.
ANNEX TABLE I
Empirical Determinants of GDP Growth Volatility
(Dependent Variable: Standard Deviation of GDP Growth, 1975-99)
VARIABLE                                               (1)              (2)             (3)             (4)              (5)
Constant                                               0.024           0.043           0.02Z           0.030           0.025
Volatility of terms of trade shocks                    0.002           0.002           0.002           0.002           0.002
Volatility of public consumption growth                0.015           0.013           0.013           0.012           0.012
Volatility of reserve money growth                     0.066           0.042           0.050           0.040           0.043
Log average of private credit/GDP ratio                               -0.O05                           -0.003          -0.003
Volatility of capital flows                                                            (.013           0.012           0.013
Average volume of capital inflows+outfilows (xlo00)                                   -0.025          -0.019          -0.020
Average per capita GDP                                                                                                 0.001
Log population 1995                                                                                                    0.000
Oil-exporters dummy                                    0.011           0.011           O.(Jl           0.011           0.()10
R-squared                                              0.51            0.54            0.57            0.58            0.58
Number of observations                                  82              82              82              82              82
Note: Coefficients shown in italics are stacistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. Significance tests use heteroskedasticiry-consistent standard errors.
69



SECtJRING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Finally, the last column adds to column 4 per capita real    tion, itself dependent on the level of economic activity, sod with
income and country size (as measured by population), the               interest rates, which determine the burden of domestic debt service
two variables found in Chapter 2 to be significantly associ-    and are themselves affected by inflation. Variation in inflar ion rates
ated.withgrothvolatilit. They are notsignifiacross countries and periods then hampers comparability of public
separately or jointly  and  their addition changes little the         deficit figores. Srcond, data on puhlic consumption are much more
widely available than data on the public deficit. The ideal measure of
coefficients on the other regressors, which appears to con-            fiscal stance would be the cyclically adjusted primary deficit (that is,
firm the ability of the preferred specification to identify the       the deficit exclusive of interest payments and adjusted for endoge-
economic roots of volatility.                                          nous changes in tax collection). Such information, however is avail-
able only for a small number of countries and years. In any case, the
picture that results from using the standard deviation of public con-
Notes                                                                 sumption growth (as in the text) as the measure of fiscal voilatility is
1. Aggregate volatility also reflects other noneconomic factors,    very similar to thar obtained using instead the coefficient of variation
such as climatic changes, natural disasters, and political develop-    of public consumption relative to GDP. By this latter measuire, Latin
ments. While these are important for some countries-for example,    America would also display higher volatility in the 1 990s thain in the
climatic factors in the Caribbean subregion-they are not covered in    1980s, exceeding in the former decade all other world regions.
this report.                                                              12. Figure 4.9 plots the (log) standard deviation of base money
2. That is, che four commodities with largest export volume for
each country. They are nor necessarily the same for all countries.     growth. The sample includes all countries, except those in Eastern
3. It is importanc to note that the data required to compute terms  Europe  and Central Asia, with populations of more than 250,.000.
of trade shocks are not available after 1998. In  1999, several           13. Figure 4.10 plots the standard deviation of terms of trade
economies in the region (such as Argentina and Chile) experienced         a intha of   plonsump             tion   or  tesms    of
termsof trde diturbaces o signfican  magntude.against that of public consumption growth, for the same saLmple of
terms of trade disturbances of significant magnitude.                  cutisa  ntepeiu  iue
4. Terms of trade shocks are defined as the change in export prices    14. altho    prtiion fi forei
times the share of exports in GDP, minus the change in import prices      14. Although participation of foreigners in the domestic capital
times the share of imports in GDPR                                    market also allows international sharing of aggregate risks.
5. This information is available on a comprehensive basis only for     15. The following discussion draws extensively from  Caballero
the 1990s.                                                            (2000).
6. See Gavin, Hausmann, and Leiderman (1997) for a compre-             16. This is documented by Caballero (1999a, b, c) for several
hensive analysis of the evolution of capital flows to Latin America.  major Latin American economies.
7. The operation of margin calls in financial markets has also been    17. The progress of financial development in Latin America was
singled out as a source of contagion, as investors incurring losses in    reviewed in World Bank (1997).
one market are forced to sell in other markets to meet cheir liquidity    18. The present value effect is computed assuming an AR(4)
requirements.                                                         process for the spot price of copper, a constant growth rate for cop-
8. Terms of trade are also determined in part by domestic factors    per production (7 percent), and a fixed discount rate (7.5 percent).
in the case of countries which possess a major share of the world mar-    19. A similar picture emerges if we use instead another standard
ket for their imports and exports.                                    measure of banking system size, namely the ratio of banks' liquid lia-
9. The coefficient of variation of gross capital flows relative to  bilities to GDP.
GDP is a more appropriate measure than the standard deviation             20. Banking systems are highly developed in a few  smaller
because the average level of this ratio is of a relatively large magni-    economies that are international financial centers, notably the
tude that varies considerably across world regions and over time.    Bahamas, Barbados, and Panama.
This is in contrast to most of che other macroecon1omic variables         21. This does not mean that LAC countries should embark on a
examined so far, which are typically small in magnitude. To perform   runaway expansion of the banking system. As experience has
cross-country comparisons of the variability of capital flows, st is
thereore  onvenent o adjst fr ther avrage ize,shown, the speed at which the banking system can safely expand is
therefre coveniet to djustfor teir aeragesize.closely dependent on the strength of the regulatory and supcrvisory
10. In fairness, policy volatility could also result from policy-  closto
makers' attempts to stabilize a highly volatile economy through       framework.
swings in fiscal and monetary policies. In practice, however, this
"good" volatility is unlikely to account for much of Latin America's  North Africa due to the small number of countries from  those
observed policy instability, with the possible exception of a few      regions for which information is available.
economies such as Chile.                                                  23. Setsitiviry  is measured by the regression coefficient of
11. We use public consumption rather than the overall public       absolute equity price changes on trade volume.
deficit for two reasons. First, the former is under the direct control of  24. The importance of these financial issues for macroeconomic
the authorities, while the latter varies endogenously with tax collec-  management is discussed in Easterly, Islam, and Stiglitz (2000).
70



MACROECONOMIC VOLATILITY IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: CAUSES AND REMEDIES
25. A similarly negative association emerges if we use instead     34. The figures in Chapter 2 presented regional medians, while
the ratio of banks' liquid liabilities to GDP as our measure of finan-    the empirical methods used here employ unweighted regional aver-
cial depth. Furthermore, the results are robust to also controlling for    ages. They also exclude economies with populations under 250,000
the level of per capita income. This is necessary because financial    in 1995, and economies for which data on any of the relevant vari-
depth indicators are strongly associated with per capita income    ables was missing.
across countries.                                                     35. In several respects, these results are in fact rather similar to
26. This resulted from a regression of GDP growth volatility on    those reported by the Inter-American Development Bank (1995) and
the logarithm of the credit/GDP ratio.                             Easterly, Islam, and Stiglitr (2000). Tte former also finds a large
27. Easterly, Islam, and Stiglitz (2000) obtain the same empirical    effect of monetary instability and financial depth on Latin America's
result.                                                            volatility, and both studies fail to find large effects of capital flow
28. This procyclical behavior of fiscal policy is documented in    volatility.
Inter-American Development Bank (1995) and World Bank                  36. The table is taken from Kraay, Loayza, Serven, and Ventura
(1997).                                                            (2000).
29. However, procyclical fiscal deficits might also be viewed as a  37. This situation parallels the lack of development of market
second-best response to financial constraints, since at times of finan-    insurance for catastrophic risks in industrial countries.
cial distress the government may not necessarily be the actor that can  38. This is analyzed by Caballero and Krishnamurty (2000).
make the best use of scarce funds from the social point of view.      39. With foreign resource ownership, however, an adequate taxa-
30. See Ghosh and others (1998) for a comprehensive empirical    tion system is necessary to capture natural resource rents.
assessment of the macroeconomic effects of alternative exchange rate   40. The line of credit was refinanced in 1999.
regimes. They find that pegged exchange rates are associated with     41. The guarantee was based ona number of specific policy reforms.
lower inflation and higher variability of real income growth than     42. Long-term debt can be viewed as short-term  debt plus an
flexible rates. However, the robustness of these results is questioned    implicit rollover insurance. By neglecting their contribution to the
by Edwards and Savastano (1999).                                   overall repayment schedule, individual borrowers may undervalue
31. This "devaluation refrainment" is examined by Calvo and    the implicit insurance and tend to overborrow at short maturities.
Reinhart (1999) and Hausmann and others (1999).                       43. Ironically, borrowing only long term and holding large short-
32. See Perry and Lederman (1999) for a discussion of the real    term reserves would be considered poor financial management in
effects of nominal devaluations in Latin American and East Asian    most corporations of industrial countries. Several major economies in
economies following the 1997 crisis.                               Latin America (especially Chile) already hold very large precaution-
33. Some caveats are in order, however. First, some of the poten-    ary balances; see Caballero (2000) for details.
tial explanatory factors are themselves affected by volatility (for   44. A similar scheme has been used by Colombia.
example, capital flows, as noted above), and hence their causal effect  45. Capital controls may also hamper another function of capital
on volatility may be blurred in the observed empirical association    flows, namely the contribution of equity inflows to improving cor-
between both variables. Second, some of the explanatory variables are    porate governance in destination countries. Moreover, an unintended
strongly associated among themselves, so it is difficult to disentan-    side effect of controls is that they may create opportunities for rent-
gle from the data which one is responsible for what effect. This is    seeking and corruption.
particularly the case as our measures of fiscal volatility move closely  46. On the effectiveness of capital controls see, for example,
with terms of trade shocks and monetary factors (positively with   Edwards (1999), Montiel and Reinhart (1999), and Kaminsky and
monetary volatility and negatively with credit depth).             Schmukler (2000).
71






CHAPTER 5
The Response of LAC Households
to Economic Shocks
L A      ATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN IS CHARACTERIZED BY HIGH LEVELS OF VOLATILITY OF
household per capita income. Although this volatility declined in the 1990s as compared to the 1980s,
it has remained high in international terms. These aggregate fluctuations have various sources: climatic
shocks, such as those imposed by Hurricane Mitch on Honduras and Nicaragua in 1999; terms of trade
shocks, such as the oil price shocks of 1973 and 1979; and external financial shocks, such as the higher
real interest rates and quantity loan rationing of the Debt Crisis in the 1980s, and the more recent capital outflows
associated with the Asian and Russian contagion episodes in 1997 and 1998-99. Transmission mechanisms and
the macroeconomic policy implications of these various shocks are different for each shock and each country.'
Because aggregate volatility as examined in Chapter 4 measures the variance of means, it stands to rea-
son that the mean volatility in individual or household income must have been even higher. After the debt
crisis of the 1980s, economists started to quantify the effects of aggregate fluctuations on household wel-
fare.2 However, the absence of disaggregated, household-level panel data had, until recently, prevented seri-
ous empirical analysis of the impact of aggregate economic volatility on households and individuals in
LAC.3 The goal of this chapter is to contribute toward understanding the impact of shocks on LAC work-
ers and households, and of their strategies-both ex ante and ex post-of dealing with these high levels of
risk.
The Risk of Unemployment: Who is Most                 However, a temporary fall in reported income due to
Affected?                                          job loss may lead to incorrectly classifying generally well-
Though real wages often drop dramatically during crises,   off unemployed individuals as poor. Reranking households
in normal times shocks to individual households (idiosyn-   by a measure of consumption-which is less likely to drop
cratic risk) may be more likely to occur when the main   as sharply as income if the job loss is considered tempo-
earner or household head loses his or her job.      rary, as in most cases it turns out to be-leads zo a sub-
stantially different picture. In Mexico and Uruguay,
Are the Poor Most Likely to Become Unemployed?      unemployment is far more evenly distributed across
Though differences in definition, measurement, and even   income classes; in Peru and Brazil, the poor show dispro-
cultural conceptions make comparing unemployment rates   portionately less unemployment.
across countries difficult, this does not prevent us from
studying how unemployment may vary across income   Are Older, Less-Educated Men More Likely to Become
quintiles within each country (see Table 5. 1). The common   Unemployed?
conception that the poor bear a disproportionate share of   Table 5.2 reveals another important fact: the highest rates of
the brunt of unemployment seems supported by the rank-   unemployment are found among those under 19 years of age
ings by per capira reported income.                 who probably are not heads of households. This suggests
73



SECURING OUR FLTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 5.1
Unemployment Rates by Household Income and Consumption Quintile
POOREST                   2                      3                      4                   RICHEST
Income
Argentina                     28.5                   16.1                   13.2                    7.5                    4.1
Brazil                        10.8                    7.1                   6.0                    4.6                     2.9
Chile                         27.7                   11.2                   7.6                    5.1                     2.8
Colombia                      31.2                   20.3                  13.8                    10.6                    5.0
El Salvador*                                         26.8                  15.3                    2.9                     0.6
Mexico                         5.0                    4.8                   4.6                     3.9                    3.2
Uruguay                       35.7                   26.4                  19.5                    11.9                    6.7
Consumption
Brazil                         5.8                    8.8                    6.8                   6.2                     4.7
Mexico                         4.8                    4.4                   4.5                     3.9                    3.8
Peru                           5.2                    6.3                   8.1                    9.1                     7.4
Uruguary                      25.1                   20.3                  21.1                   19.7                    13.6
*For El Salvador, the first and second quntiles are combined.
Source: Household Surveys (various); Argentina 1994, Pem 1996, all other countries 1998.
that facilitating the entry of the young into the workplace          Is There No Unemployment in the Informal Sector?
may be as important an item  on LAC government agendas               For Mexico and Argentina, Arango and Maloney (2000)
as mitigating unemployment risk among household heads,    have used panel household data to more carefully study the
generally assumed to be older males. Another notable find-    dynamics of unemployment, especially the incidence and
ing is that women experience higher unemployment rates               duration of unemployment spells.4 Table 5.3 presents esti-
across the sample. It is not clear whether this is due to recent    mates of transition probabilities among four types of work-
surges in female participation in the work force, or the             ers: formal salaried workers; informal workers both salaried
imperative of predominantly male household heads to take a           and self-employed, unemployed people, and people outside
job and hence shorten job search times, or other factors.    the labor force. The term  "informal" refers here to owners
Finally, the highly educated do experience less unemploy-            of and workers in firms with fewer than 16 employees who
ment; but among primary- and secondary-level educated                do not have social security or medical benefits and are
workers there is no consistent pattern across countries.             therefore not protected.
TABLE 5.2
Unemployment Rates by Age, Education, and Gender
ARGENTINA         BRAZIL            CHILE          COLOMBIA        EL SALVADOR        MEXICO          URUGUAY
Age
12-19                 36.8            13.9                               36.7             11.6             13.3             20.2
20-29                 16.5             8.6              16.5             20.7             10.2              4.6             12.7
30-49                 10.2             4.2               7.6              9.8              4.9              1.8              A.4
50-65                 12.9             2.5               6.1              8.5             4.7               2.0              4.3
65+                   11.0              1.1              5.6              8.7              3.1              6.8              1.3
Education
Primary               16.6             10.2             NIA              13.7              8.5              4.7              9.4
Secondary             13.8              6.8             N/A              17.3              8.9              3.7             10.0
University             6.0              2.4             N/A               5.9              4.9              2.9              5.1
Gender
Men                   12.5              5.6              9.1             12.1              8.1              3.4              8.1
Women                 17.4              8.0             11.7             18.1              6.0              5.5             12.8
Source; Household Surveys (various); Argentina 1997, Peru 1996, all other countries 1998.
74



THE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCHOCKS
TABLE 5.3
Annual Probability of Becoming Unemployed from Formal and Informal Work (Percent)
ORIGIN:                        FORMAL SALARIED                                         INFORMAL
MEXICO                  ARGENTINA                   MEXICO                   ARGENTINA
AGE         HIGH SCHOOL  LOW SCHOOL  HIGH SCHOOL  LOW SCHOOL  HIGH SCHOOL  LOW SCHOOL  HIGH SCHOOL  LOW SCHOOL
<22             NA            1.7          15.4        25.0          NA            1.7         18.0          31.6
22-35           0.8           1.1          4.1          10.0          1.0          1.2          0.2          11.0
36-55           1.3           1.5           2.09        7.3           1.3          1.9          4.3          13.6
>55             2.3           2.7          0.6          8.0          2.7           2.7          2.3          11.3
Total            1.1          1.5           2.8         6.5           0.9          1.4           3.0         13.0
NA= Insufficient data.
Source: Arango and Maloney (2000). Maximum Likeihood Estimations following Kalbfieisch and Lawless (1985).
Consistent with more traditional views of the informal   that one commonly cited "safety net," the informal sector
sector, the likelihood of becoming an informal sector   itself, is less comprehensive than often thought.
worker is found to be two to three times as high as the like-  But without evidence that the differences in Table 5.4
lihood of entering formal employment after being unem-    are indicative of a higher income variance of any particular
ployed. However, what is striking is that there are also
large flows from informality into unemployment. In par-       BOX 51
,    .       I~~~nfofmal Self-Employmerk: Precarious VVokers or Voluntary
ticular, in Argentina, it is twice as likely for primary-
school-educated informal sector workers to become unem-       Enrepreneurs?
ployed as their formal sector counterparts. Only some of     Do the findings that the informal often find themselves
this effect disappears when we compensate for the fact that   unemployed provide additional evidence that informal
fewer people leave formal employment relative to informal     work is especially precarious? Perhaps not. As Chapter
sector jobs. This suggests that what is traditionally consid-  2 suggested, there is evidence that up to 70 percent of
ered the reserve sector for the formal sector unemployed     the people working in'the informal sector may be
itself generates many unemployed. In fact, tabulations of    doing so voluntarily. Informal self-employment has
the sector of origin of the unemployed sector in Argentina    behaved procyclically for long periods in Argentina,
and Mexico suggest that only 36 percent and 25 percent,      Chile, and Mexico, and enterprise surveys suggest that
respectively, of those currently unemployed (who previ-      less than one-third of business owners in Argentina and
ously held jobs) were in the formal sector. The remainder    Mexico entered the sector involuntarily.
were from  either informal self-employment or informal          Levenson and Maloney (1998) argue further that
salaried employment.                                         small firms everywhere show high rates of mortality
In addition, the informal salaried sector is often thought  and higher income variance. The fact that they may
to be a "supercompetitive" sector where a laid-off worker     either be able to avoid taxation and regulation (Loayza
can instantaneously find another job. And in fact, in Mex-    1998), or that they generally do not benefit from for-
ico and Argentina, those entering unemployment from the       mal contracting, risk-pooling, and other institutions
informal sector do spend between 22 and 35 percent less      that larger formal sector firms can avail of, means that
time, respectively, in unemployment than formal sector        small firms will tend to be disproportionately informal.
workers (see Box 5.1). But it is also true that the income   Combining these two elements leads to a finding that
variance among self-employed workers is significantly        is common in the literature: informal firms show very
greater than in the formal sector (see Table 5.4). However,   high rates of failure and income volatility, and informal
given the substantially higher incidence of unemployment,     workers show high rates of turnover. But under this
the difference in durations does not seem so large that we    interpretation, this is voluntarily accepted risk and
can conclude that informal workers are somehow of less        does not reflect a "precarious" business environment in
concern than formal workers from  the point of view of        the sense the term is frequently-used.
designing an income security program. It also suggests
75



SECURING OUR S'UL1TURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 5.4
Income Variance of Formal Salaried vs. Self-Employed Workers
(Theil Index)
ARGENTINA          BOLIVIA            CHILE          COLOMBIA          URUGUAY          VENE:ZUELA
Formal Salaried       .295              .430              .411             .433              .350              .2 64
Seif-Employment       .484              .819              .867             .972              .499                i70
S,(r,-\Vodon, N Maloney, and Barensrein (2O0U).
individual in one sector versus the other, this cannot be    Salvador (Conning, Olinto, and Trigueros 2000), for the
Llsed as evidence of "precariotLsness"; it could as likely be    1995 Mexican Tequila Crisis (Cunningham  and Maloney
evidence of greater heterogeneity in the informal relative to    2000), and for various boom and bust episodes in B3razil in
the formal sector. This should not imply, therefore, that    the 1980s and 1990s (Neri and Thomas 2000).'
those in informal activities should be the focus of an           In interpreting the results of these three studies, readers
employment security program.                                  are advised to keep in mind an important shortcoming. All
three studies use incomes, not consumption expenditures,
Who Becomes Unemployed andfor How Long?                       to analyze the effects of aggregate shocks. For a study of
Tables 5.3 and 5.5 shed some light on who becomes    household responses to shocks, this is no small shortcom-
unemployed and for how  long. In both Argentina and    ing. (See Box 5.2 for a discussion of methodologies used in
Mexico, people with more schooling tend to become    these studies.) If shocks are not perfectly foreseen, or if cap-
unemployed  less frequently, but remain  unemployed    ital markets are imperfect, a (constrained) consurnption-
longer. This is consistent with more firm specific human    smoothing household will respond by adjusting consump-
capital leading to both lower separation rates and longer    tion levels. But even an unforeseen negative shock ought to
job searches. No clear pattern by age is shared across coun-    lead to a (less than proportional) decline in consumnption,
tries. In Mexico, older workers are more likely to become    and an unexpected positive shock should entail a (less than
unemployed, and for longer periods. In Argentina, the    proportional) increase in consumption.6 Since welfare ulti-
young are far more likely to become unemployed and,    mately derives from consumption, rather than income, this
among the less skilled, for longer periods. In sum, a blan-    implies that income variations overstate welfare variations
ket statement about who especially needs income protec-    in all cases (and in both directions). The magnitude of the
tion cannot be made easily.                                   overstatement will, however, decrease with the degree of
imperfection in capital markets and with how binding any
Household Responses to Income Shocks:                         subsistence constraint is.
Findings of Panel Studies                                        The studies generated a wealth of detailed, country-spe-
This section discusses the main results of the impact of    cific information that should be valuable to those with a
shocks on households and their coping strategies, obtained    special interest in these countries, but there are also results
for the agricultural production crisis of 1997 in rural El    of more general interest. We focus on what we call the four
TABLE 5.5
Unemployment Duration, in Years
MEXICO                                          ARGENTINA
AGE                          HIGH SCHOOL              LOW SCHOOL               HIGH SCHOOL              LOW SCHOOL
<22                              NA.                      0.10                    0.73                     0.58
22-35                            (.19                     0.12                     1.20                    0.49
36-55                            ().17                    0.15                    0.80                     0.51
>55                              0.20                     0.14                    0.64                     0.39
Total                            0.18                     0.14                     0.82                    0.47
NA = Not applicable.
Scarce: Arango and Maloney 120). Maximam Likelihood Estimarions following Kalbtleish a-d Lawless (198S).
76



THE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCHOCKS
BOX 5.2
Dab Sets and Metdolges Used
This box describes the data sets and empirical approaches   interviewed quarterly, and stay in the panel for five con-
used by the case studies commissioned for this report and   secutive quarters.
sumrnarized in this chapter.                            To account for the possibility that "vulnerability"
might depend on the initial rank of the household in the
Rural El Salvador                                    welfare distribution, results are presented for unweighted
Conning, Olinto, and Trigueros (2000) investigate the   and weighted-where different weights are attached to
effects of a downturn in agricultural activity in El Sal-  income levels depending on the place in the distribution.
vador in 1997, using a panel of 489 rural households sur-   Three quantile regressions (for the first quintile, the
veyed in 1995 and 1997 by the Universidad Cen-   median, and the fourth quintile) are estimated, with pro-
troamericana. The authors use these data to quantify the   portional changes in household income as the dependent
incidence of the impact by income groups, to disaggre-   variable. A set of demographic, educational, and occupa-
gate it by occupational category, and to investigate which   tional dummy variables, three of which capture house-
household characteristics were associated with differences   hold behavior in response to the shock (head enters labor
in the mragnitude of the income shock. The existence of   force, spouse enters labor force, and child enters labor 1;
such characteristics would indicate that they play a role   force), are used as independent variables.
in risk management by the household, either ex ante (as
insurance or self-protection), or ex post (as coping).  Metropolitan Brazil
The authors deploy two complementary techniques.   Neri and Thomas (2000) identify the groups most
First, poverty indexes are computed by subgroup, using    affected by aggregate economic fluctuations in Brazil,
one of the seven occupational categories the household   and then investigate the nature of the household
fits into: self-employed only, nonagricultural wage only,   responses. They restrict their inquiry to urban areas, but
agricultural wage only, agricultural wage and nonagri-   span a longer period: from 1982 to 1999. The data set is
cultural wage, nonagricultural wage and self-employ-   drawn from the Monthly Employment Survey (PME),
meat, agricultural wage and self-employment, and all   carried out by the Brazilian Statistical Institute (IBGE)
1 three occupations. Second, a model of income determina-   every month for Brazil's six largest metropolitan areas.
tion, including household-specific and time-variant vari-   The same households are interviewed for four consecutive
i ables, household-specific and time-invariant variables,   months, then excluded from  the sample for eight
household-specific and time-invariant unobserved effects,   months, and then revisited for a further four consecutive
and household-specific and time-variant shocks, was esti-   months. This allows the authors to construct a series of
mated to generate random-effects estimators. A specifica-   panels, using four-month averages of household incomes
tion test suggested that the hypothesis that the estimates   per capita, to investigate the impact on households of
were the same could not be rejected. The authors focus on   seven periods of macroeconomic volatility: three booms
the analysis of the random effects estirnates.       and four recessions. The distribution used is a distribu-
tion of household per capita income, per household head.
Metropolitan Mexico                                     Neri and Thomas also find that using current income
Cunningham and Maloney (2000) identify the groups   to rank the distribution would bias the results by exag-
worst affected by the 1995 Tequila Crisis in Mexico, and    gerating true mobility. They too use a proxy for perma-
i study the results of labor force participation changes   nent income, which is the value of the predicted income
around the shock, as coping strategies. The data set used   for each household head in a Mincerian (earnings) equa-
is a panel of 21,262 households in 16 metropolitan areas   tion with age, experience, gender, marital status, and
in Mexico, from 1994 to 1997, drawn from the National   employment sector. Average proportional income
Urban Employment Survey (ENEU). Households are                                       (continnes on next page)
77



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
BOX 512
|.Continued
changes for each quintile in each episode are calculated,   canges in occupational status Finally, a diffrence-rn-
then disaggregard depending on whether the thuehold    differences approh is used to compare the probabilities
head was a ifomal or informal sector emnployee or was   of four types of household responses to changes in
self employed in the first per,iod. The probability of   empoyment status of the household heads+ spouse enters
entering or exiting poverty in booms  ad recessions is   emnployment, child leaves school, child repeats grade, and
conmputed by edcation of the household head and    child enters enployment.
stylized facts of aggregate income risk and household wel-   ated a greater proportional income loss to the poorest quin-
fare in Latin America:                                   tile than to any other. In all other cases (1990-91, 1996-97,
(1) Aggregate income volatility affects different ranges   and 1998-99), the greatest proportional-and therefore
of income distribution differently, depending on    obviously also absolute-income losses were borne by the
the country and on the episode. There is no dis-   richest quintile. In fact, during the recession that followed
cernible pattern that either the poorest or the rich-   the failed stabilization attempt known as the "Collor Plan,"
est households persistently have a higher income    which was based on a temporary seizure of financial assets,
volatility than others.                            proportional losses declined consistently by income quintile.
(2) The ownership of assets-such as land, education,     Growth episodes also appeared to have been more benev-
and surplus household labor-reduces the risk faced    olent to the poor than is generally acknowledged. In two of
by households.                                    the three boom  episodes considered (1984-85  and
(3) The poor, like everyone else, appear to be reluctant    1986-87) proportional income gains also declined consis-
to make irreversible divestments during bad times,   tently by income quintile. The third episode, which fol-
and this is especially true of decisions concerning    lowed the succesfull stabilization of the Brazilian real dur-
the education of their children. The evidence   ing 1994-95, is best described as broadly neutral. Table 5.6
broadly suggests that school enrollment is reason-   and Figures 5.1 .a and b summarize the results from Brazil.
ably insensitive to aggregate economic fluctuations,  Using a different methodology, similar results emerge
although school perfomance is not. Child labor is   for Mexico in 1995. Households that suffered average or
generally procyclical rather than countercyclical.  median losses were found to be evenly spread across all
(4) From the experience of some countries, relatively    wealth classes. But households in the poorest 40 percent of
large crises (deep or long recessions) appear to have   the population were less likely to suffer large negative
qualitatively different effects on poverty and invest-   losses and were overrepresented among those "suffering"
ments in human capital than smaller shocks; for   small losses (or even gaining) in the aftermath of the 1995
example, the poor are affected more than the rich    crisis. Table 5.7 reports the actual results of those regres-
when the shocks are big, but vice versa when the    sions. In addition, some groups often thought to suffer dis-
shocks are smaller.                                proportionately, such as the elderly and single mothers, do
not appear to be particularly badly affected, echoing earlier
Do Aggregate Shocks Hurt the Poor More than the Rich?    findings from Peru by Hall and Glewwe (1998).
Macroeconomic volatility-in particular, unexpected nega-    But just as they did during 1982-83 in metropolitan
tive aggregate income shocks-do not appear to dispropor-   Brazil, the poorest households do, on some occasions, fare
tionately affect the incomes of any particular range of the    worse than richer households in terms of the relative
income distribution. Specifically, we find no support for the   income losses inflicted by a shock. This was found for the
common claim  that the poorest are always those most   rural Salvadoran sample, where the mean proportional
affected by economic fluctuations. Of the four Brazilian   income loss during the aggregate shock suffered by the
recessions studied, only the most severe (1982-83) gener-   poorest 20 percent of the population was 32 percent; 18
78



THE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCHOCKS
TABLE 5.6
Metropolitan Brazil: Percentage Income Changes by Head's Wage Bracket
WAGE BRACKET                      GROWTH                                                 RECESSION
1984-85         1986-87         1994-95        1982-83         1990-91         1996-97         1998-99
1 (poorest)         8.8             31.0            15.7           -33.3           -11.7            -1.8           -3.9
2                   6.7             19.4            17.1           -30.7           -12.5            -1.9           -5.5
3                   6.6             14.9            16.9           -31.0           -18.9            -1.7           -4.9
4                   4.6             12.6            18.0           -28.6           -26.0            -2.0           -6.3
5 (richest)         3.8              4.9            14.0           -27.1           -28.1            -5.2           -6.5
Source: Neri and Thomas (2000).
percent for the second fifth; 2 percent for the third; 5 per-    although the different settings to which they refer imply
cent for the fourth; and the richest 20 percent actually    that the assets in question differed in importance.
experienced a 9 percent gain in income.7                           Perhaps the starkest evidence refers to the smoothing
Just as the Salvadoran example showed that the results    effect of land ownership on the plight of rural households
may differ among countries-or for the same country,    during the 1997 agricultural downturn in El Salvador.
between rural and urban areas-results also differ if distrib-    Table 5.8 decomposes the total change in the poverty head-
utional weights are attached to losses, for example, with    count ratio9 for the seven occupational categories previ-
higher weights attached to incomes of the poor. This quali-    ously mentioned, into three effects: one due to an increase
fication should be kept in mind when interpreting results    in poverty within the existing subgroup, another due to
such as those for Brazil and Mexico, and in reacting to claims    changes in the population shares of each subgroup, and a
that the "the poor are affected more severely during crises."8    third that accounts for interactions between the previous
two terms. Given the choice of a relatively high poverty
Does Ownership of Assets Reduce Vulnerability to                line, the headcount did not change much overall, rising
Aggregate Shocks?                                               from  0.65 to 0.69.10 However, the poverty profile was
The second stylized fact of covariate income risk and    transformed. The self-employed only group, which gener-
household welfare in LAC is that asset ownership decreases    ally has no access to land, accounted for some 16 percent of
a household's vulnerability to shocks (in the sense of reduc-    the poor in 1995; two years later, the figure was 25 percent.
ing its proportional income variation). The term "asset" is    Interestingly, this did reflect a rise in the intragroup head-
used in a broad sense to include land, education, the bene-    count ratio, but was predominantly due to an increase in
fits associated with formal employment, and underused    the number of people who lost jobs in agriculture. Corre-
family labor. All three studies uncovered evidence of this,    spondingly, the poverty share of agricultural wage workers
FIGURE 5.1
Income Gains and Losses in Seven Episodes of Volatility in Brazil
35  -0 
-   ----------- ~ 6-97
87                                     ;98-99                                                   - 'C
25 --10 
20  -
15       2         3          4        5                          1         2        3         41
r                                                  ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-20 
10                                             ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~-30--
5    -                                                           35-
0                                                               -40 - 
1        2         3          4         5                         1         2        3         4        5
Wage Bracket                                                     Wage Bracket
79



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 5.7
Mexico: Proportional Income Change by Income Quintile, 1995-96
PERCENTAGE CHANGE ACROSS 5 QUARTERS
0.2                0.5                 0.8                0.2                 0.5                 0.8
A                  B                   C                  D                   E                   F
Quintile 1                0.033*            0.007               0.085**             0.091**             0.091**             0.281**
Quintile 2                0.048**           0.016               0.006               0.053**             0.046**             0.112**
Quintile 3                0.018             -0.0068            -0.0291              0.064**             0.034**             0.094**
Quintile4                 0.011             -0.021              0.006               0.027               0.012               0.032
Consumption              -0.562**          -0.260**             0.115**             -0.382**           -0.004               0.508**
Denotes statistical significance at the 1 percent level.
** Denotes staristical significance at the 5 percent level.
Note; The table reports percentage income changes relative to the richest 20 percent of the population. The omitted category is the top quintile, and the proportional change in its
income is given by the constant term; other entries indicate differences with respecr to thar change.
SoAace: Cunningham and Maloney (2000).
TABLE 5 8
Rural El Salvador: A Dynamic Decomposition of Poverty Changes, 1995-1997
CONTRIBUTION TOWARD CHANGE IN POVERTY (SE)
HEADCOUNT RATIO                                          TOTAL              SECTORAL           POPULATION SHIFT       INTERACTION
Self-employed only                                        160                   22                    127                   11
Nonagricultural wage workers only                         -23                   29                   -43                    -8
Nonagricultural wage + self-employed                       21                    -3                   24                    -()
Agricultural wage workers only                            -91                    11                  -98                    -4
Agricultural wage workers + self-employed                  49                    27                   21                      1
Agricultural wage + nonagricultural wage                  -12                    36                   -35                  -13
Agricultural and nonagricultural wage + self               -5                   -22                    20                    -3
Total                                                     100                   100                    16                   -16
fell from  18 percent to 11 percent, despite an increase in its       5.2, which suggests that those with higher earnings did
own headcount ratio.                                                 not suffer income losses even during the agricultural down-
The results for El Salvador indicate that-controlling             turn (and may even have done better during the crisis), this
for income-land ownership makes households more likely               hints at the role of education as an important self-protec-
rn keep children enrolled in school, and helps preserve the          tion instrument.'2
productivity of labor during crises. The importance of land              This possible self-protection role of education was found
is confirmed by statistical analysis to estimate earnings in    to be associated with a smaller probability of transition
both periods. Land ownership appears to have played a                into poverty and a larger transition rate out of poverty,
more important role as a self-insurance strategy than as a           both during recessions and growth spurts in Brazil. Figures
direct determinant of earnings in good times: the effect of    5.3.a through 5.3.d illustrate that those associations were
land ownership was not statistically significant in 1995,    robust for all three growth episodes and all four recessions
and only became important after the crisis. During good              considered.
times, it was access to off-farm  employment, rather than                A partial exception to this role of education is the case
having a plot of land, that had the greatest (and most sig-          of Mexico, where households headed by college-educated
nificant) impact on household income."1 And both original    males suffered  somewhat larger proportional falls  in
access to nonagricultural employment and the ability to    income as a consequence of the 1995 crisis than did those
keep it after the crisis appear, in turn, to have been corre-        with primary or secondary education. However, inclusion
lated with that other asset crucial to the poor: education.          of what the  authors call "coping  variables"-namely
The results for rural El Salvador also indicate a strong          entry into the labor force by the head, the spouse, or a
and statistically significant effect of the years of schooling       child-reduces that advantage of the uneducated, and it
of the household head on income. Combined with Figure                ceases to be significant at the median. It appears that for
80



THE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCHOCKS
FIGURE 5.2                                                  is particularly true of parental decisions about the school-
E1 Salvador. Cumulative Distributions of Real Income Per Capita,   ing of their children.
1995 and 1997                                                  A number of recent studies have emphasized the risk
d                                                     that, in addition to their temporary impacts, temporary
negative income shocks might have permanent effects on
the incomes of poor families. One of the main transmission
.75 -                     >�mechanisms which these studies suggest for such "poverty
hysteresis" is that parents might be forced to take their
o children out of school to deploy them in income-generat-
ing activities (see, for example, Lustig 1999, and IDB
2000). Even though the opportunity cost of schooling is
likely to have declined, as the covariate shock reduces the
.25 -                                          potential earnings in the market for children's labor, the
argument goes, a subsistence constraint may become bind-
ing and necessitate a reallocation of the child's time away
from schooling and toward work. The existence of a sub-
o- l                                                    sistence constraint, and of irreversibilities in the educa-
0                  5,000                 10 000     tional production function, would thus lead to a rational
Income Per Capita, 1997 Colones          decision which might, nevertheless, imply a reduction in
the lifetime earnings of the child.
Mexico any apparent greater ability to weather shocks by       Although the conceptual argument is plausible, empir-
the less educated is due to their greater ability or will-   ical tests have been scant. And they are needed: theoretical
ingness to send household members previously out of the    predictions are ambiguous because of opposing effects of
labor force into it. If one thinks of underemployed family    earning opportunities (which are lower during bad times)
labor as an asset, this finding simply suggests that educa-    and the need for income (which is higher during bad
tion is a subsitute for it, as a self-insurance strategy. And    times). Examining the effect of the four Brazilian reces-
if leisure is a good thing, as Box 5.3 suggests, the conse-    sions and three growth episodes on three child schooling
quences for family welfare, particularly that of women,   variables-dropout rates, grade repetition rates, and child
may be substantial.                                         labor participation rates-helps shed light on the nature of
In fact, recourse to underused family labor is also found    the effects sketched above. As Figures 5.5, 5.6, and 5.7
to be an important coping strategy in rural El Salvador.   suggest, school enrollment is largely acyclical with respect
This may reflect a greater proportion of women in the wage-   to trend, but child labor and grade repetition are mildly
contract labor force-where demand rationing was clearly    procylical.
in effect-and perhaps more important, a complementarity        The economic cycle appears to have no overall effect on
between greater reliance on owned land and unpaid family    dropout rates. It does, however, have some effect on repeti-
female labor. Just as in Mexico's urban setting it appears   tion rates, a serious problem in the Brazilian education sys-
that education and surpLus family labor are substitute assets   tem. Upturns appear to increase repetition rates; this may
in coping with a crisis, in the rural El Salvador setting, sur-    be associated with the procyclical nature of child labor
plus family labor and land are complementary assets, with a    (which can be engaged in without dropping out of school
measurable volatility-reducing effect.                      entirely, but at the cost of diminished performance). The
result for child labor, illustrated in Figure 5.7, suggests
Do the Poor Engage in Self-Destructive or Myopic Coping?    that the effect of a lower opportunity cost of schooling dur-
The third stylized fact of covariate income risk and house-   ing recessions outweighs the other effects.'3
hold welfare in LAC is that the poor, like everyone else,      However, a more detailed investigation revealed that for
appear to be reluctant to jeopardize their (family's) future    children of workers moving from  formal sector jobs to
in an irreversible way during a temporary downturn. This   informal self-employment-which is more frequent dur-
81



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGtlRE 5.3
Brazil: Moves Into and Out of Poverty, by Level of Education
[a] Into Poverty During Growth                                 [b] Into Poverty During Recession
40                                                              40-
30                                                              30
W>> ~ ~ ~~~~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~    90  9-\>                                0      91
C                                                             0
1 0                                                               20   -_ _
10                                              1~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0                          I
none       1-3       4-7      8-11       12+                    none       1-3       4-7       8-11      12+
Years of Schooling                                            Years of Schooling
[c] Out of Poverty During Growth                               [d] Out of Poverty During Recession
70                                                              70
60 - -      .-- -  _  .  ...-.        -_ . -                    60
50  -      -  -   -   -6  -__                                   50 .-.- .        -       -     _____  ___6
_  40                               ~                               40-
2  30                                                               30
a.              84-85                                                    96-97
20                                                              20-
10                                                              I00
none       1-3       4-7      8-11       12-+                   none       1-3       4-7       8-11      12+
Years of Schooling                                              Years of Schooling
Soare: Neri and Thomas (2000).
ing recessions-repetition  rates increased substantially,          The procyclicality of child labor is not a peculiarity of
and there was also an increase in the work participation of    metropolitan Brazil. In Mexico, the proportion of house-
these workers' spouses. It is tempting to hypothesize that    holds sending children to work during the 1995-96 cycle
informality may worsen school performance by drawing on    was consistently low (less than 4 percent) and marginally
"surplus" household labor." Brazilian children-and prob-    higher during the recovery than during the downturn (see
ably those in most LAC countries-age 10 to 15 have been    Box 5.4). The procyclical nature of child labor was more pro-
entering the labor market at decreasing rates over the last    nounced for the poorest quintile, where 3.8 percent of fami-
two decades. This trend is clear, and the effects of aggre-    lies added children to the work force in the recession, but 5.7
gate fluctuations are relatively minor. But they do exist and    percent did during the recovery. In Chile, once again, labor
are procyclical: entrance into the labor force for this age    force participation of youth age 15 to 19 is procyclical,
group has generally been higher in booms than during            falling for both males and females during the 1982-84
recessions.                                                     recession. The same is true for men age 20 to 24.'5 Again, it
82



ITHE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHIOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCHOCKS
BOXD 5       e3                                            during recessions. Hence, the results have important policy
WI3oreDoesNmeGoDurlngaCrisi?                               implications. Caution is necessary, however, until this is
found to be true for other countries or settings (for example,
Using the same Mexican panel data, Cunningham              rural areas), and one must keep in mind that this procycli-
(1999) and Parker and Skoufias (2000) find that wives      cality result relates to child labor, not school enrollment. In
do enter the job market if the husbancd loses his job.     fact, the results for school enrollment are mixed: in Brazil,
But when a woman enters the job market, who does the       enrollment was acyclical while in Chile enrollment declined
work she used to do? Or does she simply lose her           during a severe recession. There is also some evidence that
leisure time and work a "double shift"?                   ingredients for producing well-schooled children decline in
Cunningham (1999) finds that for every additional       quantity or quality during downturns (for example, because
hour worked outside the house, women do one-half           of lower public and private spending or because some
hour less housework, in effect, working a "shift and a     spouses join the labor force and have less time to spend with
half." Other members of the family compensate some-       their children). It is also too early to make strong claims
what, but overall, the household work falls by about       about the nature of the effect of aggregate income shocks on
the same amount, This implies both that women              the education of poor children. Nevertheless, the evidence
become more "time poor" (that is, lose leisure time)       uncovered so far can provide useful guidance to policymak-
and that many necessary household tasks-such as rais-      ers, as we outline in Chapter 7.
irg children, ensuring healthy living conditions, and
isvesting in socially usefil nerworks-may get less        Are All Downturns the Same in Their Effects?
attention:(see Figure 5.4).                                Discussions about policies to protect the vulnerable from
the effects of aggregate volatility generally assume that all
downturns are similar in their effects on poverty and
was only for young adult women (age 20 to 24) that partic-    human capital investments. In fact, the evidence from the
ipation rates were found to be countercyclical. The results   case studies for Brazil, Chile, El Salvador, and Mexico
from  Chile confirm  both the countercyclical pattern for   reveal that this is not true: longer, deeper recessions appear
female labor force participation rates and the procyclical pat-   to have results qualitatively different from shorter down-
tern for child labor found by the other studies.            turns. The poor suffered greater proportional losses in
These results run counter to frequent claims that gov-    income during severe recessions than the wealthy (but this
ernment efforts to combat child labor should be stepped up    was reversed at least for metropolitan Brazil and Mexico),
FIGURE 5.4
Change in Housework rime Due to Labor Force Entry
10
5   -    .   i  g 1R~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~F7    Headl male|
O  _                                                                                   E] wC-':  r   S   S  ; CL  Teen son
*  Teen daughrer
MOther male
-I Other female
-10
Head Female
Wife Enters                  Husband Enters                Enters
-15
83



iFCtJRING OtlR F[tTL RIF IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
FIGURE 5 5
Brazil: Probability of School Dropout
8-
7
5
4
3 _
2   -              downrurn      . .               ..                       . ..                 .     ....                             .
P10 *tptulrn                                                                   
I  _        _  trend
0   -IIIIII
1982           1984            1986            1988           1990             1992           1994            1996            1998
FIGURE 5.6
Brazil: Probability of Repeating a Grade at School
40                                                                                                                                - -
35   -
30   --1
25   -     1
20 -
15 -
10          4&  downturn
n   upturn
-   trend
0         -
1982            1984            1986            1988           1990            1992           1994            1996           1998
FIGURE 5.7
Brazil: Probability of Child Aged 10-15 Starting Work
14 4
12
10
8-
6-
4                 *  downturn
2                 1   uipturn
2   trend
0-
1982           1984            1986            1988            1990            1992           1994            1996            1998
Source Neri and Thomas (2000).
84



THE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCIIOCKS
and children were pulled out of school in Brazil and Chile   changes) was substantial. Recessions like those of
when the recession was deep, but not otherwise. If con-    1982-83 and 1990-91 in Brazil led to proportional
firmed for other countries and settings, this finding has    declines in mean incomes for some quintile groups on the
important policy implications.                           order of 30 percent. In Mexico's 1995 crisis, the median
The Brazilian recession of 1982-83 was more serious    proportional income loss for all households was around 25
than the other three downturns (1990-91, 1996-97, and    percent, and for those suffering "catastrophic losses" (that
1998-99) examined here. But it was also different in that   is, in the first quintile group of the distribution of
while in milder recessions the poorer 40 percent suffered    changes), the figure was over 50 percent. In El Salvador,
proportionally less than the wealthiest 40 percent of the   the agricultural crisis of 1997 led some measures of the
population-declines in income of about 12 percent, 2    severity of poverty to rise by about 37 percent among the
percent, and 5 percent for the poor during 1990-91,   rural self-employed.
1996-97, and 1998-99, respectively, as compared with       If Latin Americans are risk-averse, as we suppose most
27 percent, 4 percent, and 6 percent, respectively-the    people to be, this degree of household income volatility
deeper recession resulted in a loss of 32 percent for the    implies a considerable loss of social welfare. Reducing it
poorest two-fifths as compared with 28 percent for the    would make workers and their families better off, other
richest two-fifths (see Table 5.1 and Figure 5.1). Again,   things remaining the same. This argument and the mag-
the Chilean recession of 1982-84, which was steeper and    nitude of the variations at the household level provide a
longer than other episodes of negative growth, was also    powerful incentive to study the determinants of micro-
different in that it was the only recession during which    economic risk and the strategies adopted by households
child enrollment declined.                               to reduce it and insure against it.
The rationale for these findings may be that the poor    The general conclusion of this chapter is that house-
have smaller asset stocks (both in absolute terms and rel-   holds largely respond rationally and sensibly both from
ative to income flows) as compared with the rich, limit-   the viewpoint of individual households and often even
ing their ability to draw on their assets for prolonged    from that of society: most notably, they attempt to shelter
periods. Thus, while they behave similarly during mod-   their children's schooling and leisure from  economic
erate downturns-drawing down some of their assets and    shocks, both aggregate and idiosyncratic. This does not
working longer hours but maintaining critical long-term  mean that governments cannot do more to help house-
investments such as education of children-longer down-   holds deal better with income risk. Chapter 6 dicusses
turns result in a divergence of behavior between the rich    how countries in the region have sought to deal with the
and the poor. Again, while the reduced earnings (or "sub-   risk of unemployment, and finds that countries can better
stitution effect") may offset the propensity to send chil-    match income support programs for the unemployed with
dren to work due to the subsistence constraint (or   the type and level of risk, and the level of sophistication of
"income effect") during short downturns, the latter may   the available instruments for self-insurance. Chapter 7,
dominate the former during downturns that are expected    which addresses the issue of what governments have done
to last longer. In any case, if confirmed for other countries    and how they could improve public interventions, finds
and settings, this finding, too, has important policy   that while "targeted" social spending is often both pro-
implications which are discussed in Chapter 7.           cyclical and poorly targeted, broader social spending such
as that on education and health is less subject to be cut
Conclusion                                               during economic downturns, but is often insufficient to
Large macroeconomic volatility in LAC both causes and    prevent a deterioration of performance indicators during
obscures even more substantial variation in the incomes   recessions. The findings of Chapter 5 actually imply that
and employment status of individuals and families in the   there is considerable scope for welfare gains from better
region. Although lack of consumption data prevented    policies for dealing with the risks of unemployment and
better estimates of variations in household welfare, the    aggregate economic fluctions that can lead to increased
magnitude of the income variations reported here (and    poverty. The final sections of Chapters 6 and 7 propose
which constitute an upper bound to the true welfare   how these gains can best be realized.
85



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
BOX 5.4
Do Families Mortgage Their Chldren's Future? Other Evidence
As with the evidence fom Brazil and Mexico, there is lit-    child wages dominates the income effect over the eco-
tie or only weak evidence from  other countries in the    nomic cycle).
region that fiailies &ced with income shocks either put          Cunningham (1 999), Parker and Skoufias (2000), and
children to work or pull them  out of school. The caimns    Cunningham  and Maloney (2000) focus on Mexico and
are made nevertheless.                                        study the impact of income shocks on child labor and
For Peru, using Living Standards Measurement Sur-    school attendance befre, during, and after the 1995 Cei-
veys for 199  and 1997, Ilahi (1999) found that when    sis, examining the effects of idiosyncratic shocks while
mothers become unemployed, children allocate less time    controlling for aggregate risk. All focus especiaLly on the
Ito household chores, but there is litde or no change in    effcts on children of involuntary loss of employment.
schooling or child labor. Schady (2000) found no signifi-    Parker and Skoufias focus especially on those due to ill-
cant difrece between school enrollment rates in Peru    ness, divorce, or other labor market reasons-of any of
in the crisis year of 1991 and in the growth yeas  of 1994    the pares. Their finding is that children-boys more so
and 1997. Once again, acyclicality is observed in the    than girls-are largely unafcted by household-specific
broader context of a secular rise in enrolment,               economic shocks, in periods of both aggregate downturns
Like the Neri and Thomas (2000) paper discussed    and recovery
here, Duryea (1998) examirne  the effects of shocks in           Exploiting the dynamic possibilities of the panel, Cun-
metropolitan Brazil. But the nature of shocks is idiosyn-    ningham and Maloney do find the predicted effects on girls
cratic rather than aggregate: unemployment of the father    in resonse to the father's job loss, but ambiguous evidence
lowers the probability of grade advancement of children    for boys. Fmuher they find that while in less well-off fam-
age 10 to 15 by about 4 percentage points, but Duryea    ilies children do work and drop out more, there is little
(1998) does not explore the reasons for this-fr exam-i   evidence of credit constraints that would cause poorer fain-
pie, whether this is due to a less favorable family envi-   ilies to put children to work. However, they do find that
ronment, reduced intputs such as books, or because the    where a wife or husband enters informal self-employment,
child has to begin or increase paid work. Recall that Neri    children are more likely to work. As with the evidence
and Thoomas (2000) fund no systemnatic evidence that    from  Brazil that the substitution effect dominates the
earolment or tpetition or dropout declines during pen-    income effect, starting a family tnicroenterprise may raise
ods of aggreate downturns, but fund some evidence    the value of a child's work time and encourage entry.
that child labor increases during periods of recovery (in    Finally, they find only ambiguous evidence of household
economic parlance, the "sibstitution effct" of changes in    adjustments lasting more than a quarter.
L                                             ..... .   -    ---- -- ------    ---- ---   ,__    ,.......... ..     .................... . . .............  -.. - - ---------- - .-          P.       
Notes                                                          seven contiguous EPH cohorts were combined beginning in May
1. See Caballero (2000), Calvo (1991), and Rodrik (1999) for a    1993 and rotated every six months.
sampling of possible explanantions on high volatility in the region.  5. This section is based on Ferreira and Gill (2000).
2. Cornia and others (1987) and the World Development Report    6. The consumption variations would only be equi-proportional
1990 played an important role in raising the profile of this issue in   if households were certain that the shocks were permanent.
the late 1980s.                                                    7. There are a number of good reasons to believe that the nature
3. For a path-breaking exception, see Glewwe and Hall (1998).  of this negative shock in 1997 did affect the rural poor more severely
4. Arango and Maloney (2000) use both the Mexican Household   than other segments. We will discuss some of these below. But it
Survey described in Box 5.2 and the Permanent Household survey    should also be noted that the ranking of households in this stuay is
(EPH) from Argentina. The EPH conducts extensive biannual inter-    based on an average of each household's income in 1995 and 1997.
views in Greater Buenos Aires and is structured so as to generate    This is arguably a less robust proxy for permanent income than either
panels that allow tracking a quarter of the sample across two years.   the neighborhood average used by Cunningham and Maloney (2000),
To generate a sufficiently large sample of roughly 5,700 observations,    or the Mincerian predicted income used by Neri and Thomas (2000).
86



THE RESPONSE OF LAC HOUSEHOLDS TO ECONOMIC SCHOCKS
8. Cunningham and Maloney (2000) show that when permanent    farming and nonfarming hours, while the loss of wage hours is dri-
incomes are weighted to give more importance to the poor, the pro-    ven principally by reduced agricultural wage employment.
portional losses accruing to the least educated-and hence likely the  12. See Box 3.1 for definitions of alternative insurance instru-
poorest-do indeed become greater than when that weight is 1. Like    ments; see Ehrlich and Becker (1972), and Gill and Ilabi (2000) for
them, other researchers making claims about who suffers dispropor-    details.
tionately during crises should make their welfare weights explicit.   13. See Ferreira and Gill (2000) for a fuller characterization of
9. See Conning, Olinto, and Trigueros (2000) for analogous    these opposing effects.
decompositions using other poverty indexes.                           14. This suggests a caveat to our earlier consideration of surplus
10. Depth and severity, as measured by other poverty indexes,    household labor as an asset with insurance value. It is likely that
rose in a more pronounced manner.                                  those family members were not completely idle. In fact, mothers
11. The "self-employment only" category into which many    were most likely being a highly productive input into the education
households fell in 1997 due to having lost jobs is not made up    of their children. Their joining the labor force is not without cost
mostly of the landless. In fact, most of these households are engaged  and, even if the evidence is largely against the proposition that this
at least in part in agricultural or animal husbandry activities. The    leads to massive increases in dropout rates, the quality and pace of
relationship between land ownership and poverty and vulnerability    their children's education may suffer nonetheless.
is complex. The main finding in Conning, Olinto, and Trigueros        15. Mizala and Romaguera (2000) report gender-disaggregated
(2000) is how much household labor allocation changes in a crisis.   time-series for labor force participation rates for people age 15 to 19
The large increase in self-employment hours is split evenly between    and 20 to 24 in Chile, from 1976 to 1993.
87






CHAPTER 6
Helping Workers Deal with
the Risk of Unemployment
L           ATIN AMERICA'S SHIFT AWAY FROM THE STATE-LED DEVELOPMENT MODEL TOWARD A MARKET-
based economic paradigm has rendered obsolete key components of the old income protection
system, such as layoff restrictions and the state as employer of last resort. On the one hand, inter-
national competition entails the need for firms to use greater flexibility in managing their staffs,
weakening the traditional lifetime relationship with their employees. On the other hand, pub-
lic finance constraints, privatization of public enterprises, and renewed emphasis on financial performance
of those remaining in public hands have all led to public sector downsizing and to a much-reduced role of
the state as employer. All these developments, together with the potentially adverse employment effects of
the economic reform process on some groups of workers documented in Chapter 2, have raised considerable
interest in Latin America and the Caribbean in income support programs that could mitigate the effects of
economic insecurity in general, and of job loss in particular. This chapter deals with the latter.
As in many other policy areas, developed countries have served as the reference when thinking about the
appropriate design of income support programs for the unemployed. Some analysts have discussed ways to
adapt unemployment insurance programs to developing countries (Hamermesh 1992), and some have even
tried to calibrate the parameters of such programs to the specific characteristics of those countries (Hopen-
hayn and Nicolini 1999).1 However, it is not clear that unemployment insurance is the best-suited income
support program under all circumstances. More recently,  This chapter assesses a set of income support programs that
there have been proposals to introduce individual unem-   have been tried in the Latin American context. Rather than
ployment savings accounts, whereby workers are forced to   starting from a theoretically "ideal" program and adjusting it
set aside money when at work, and are given access to these   to the characteristics of a specific country, the chapter consid-
savings in the event of job loss. While these programs do   ers specific programs that are currently in operation. Until
provide a more certain severance benefit to workers, these   recently, the accumulated knowledge on income support pro-
proposals are justified largely on theoretical grounds: indi-   grams for the unemployed in developing countries was quite
vidual savings accounts provide better incentives than con-   limited.3 Hence, while this chapter draws from existing liter-
ventional unemployment insurance to contribute to when   ature, it is mainly based on studies commissioned by the
employed and to search for a job when unemployed.2 But   World Bank specially for this report. These studies deal with
there are theoretical arguments against this proposal as   the operation and effects of specific income support programs
well. In particular, individual savings accounts do not pool   for the unemployed in Argentina (Ravallion 2000), Brazil
risk among individuals, and thus may be less efficient than   (Cunningham  2000), Colombia (Kugler 2000), Mexico
those that do so explicitly (such as formal unemployment   (Wodon 2000), and Peru (MacIsaac and Rama 2000).4
insurance) or implicitly (such as income support programs  The objective is not to generate an unambiguous "rank-
financed from general tax revenues).                 ing" of these programs; all of them can be expected to have
89



SECHURING OiLR FlTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONO)MY
both strengths and weaknesses under different objectives of   training for the unemployed (TG), unemployment insurance
policymakers, depending on the constraints they face. For   (UI) and individual savings accounts (IA). The main features
example, a program may do well at offsetting the losses    of these programs are summarized in Box 6.1. The timing
formal sector workers experience as a result of increased    and nature of the payments involved in each of these five
import competition or deregulation, but fail to reach infor-   income support programs is summarized in Table 6.1.
mal sector workers who risk poverty as a result of aggregate  To interpret Table 6. 1, consider the following stylized
fluctuations. Similarly, a program may have broad cover-   labor market sequence. In period 0 the worker loses work,
age, but also entail a large cost for the budget. Which pro-   in period F he or she finds a new job, D is the maximum
gram is best suited for a country depends especially on the    duration of benefits allowed by the income support pro-
state of labor markets (for example, the extent of informal   gram, and R is the worker's retirement age. The table is
employment and the frequency of joblessness) and the    constructed under the assumption that F comes before D,
administrative capacity of governments to implement dif-    but this is not necessarily so in practice. The rows in the
ferent public income support programs.                   table correspond to the five broad types of income support
This said, it should also be kept in mind that govern-   programs currently in operation in LAC. A zero indicates
ments can overcome some of these constraints over time:   that the program does not entail any payment, from or to
labor market reforms can reduce the difference between for-   the worker, in the corresponding period. Possible pay-
mal and informal activities, and administrative capacity can    ments include the salary received from a public works pro-
be built. In going from what governments have done to    gram (W), the training allowance (A), the amount: of sev-
facilitate income support to the unemployed to how they    erance pay received from the employer (S), the contribution
could do better, therefore, we bring in a medium- and    by worker and employer to an income-support program
longer-term perspective as well. While some of the policy    (-C), a benefit whose amount depends on past contribu-
recommendations are based on specific theoretical premises,   tions (+C), and an old-age pension (P).
we believe that a blend of practicality and analytical rigor  In the individual accounts program, the old-age pension
can help countries devise strategies that efficiently bridge    can be accrued by the portion of the forced savings that was
immediate action ancl long-term vision. This chapter intro-    not used as income support in periods of unemployment.
duces programs of income support in five countrics, distin-    While only workers cnrollcd with social security can par-
guishing their key features; summarizes the evaluation of   ticipate in the unemployment insurance and individual
these programs; and using the main findings of these and    accounts programs, the other three programs are in princi-
other studies and the comprehensive insurance framework    ple accessible to nonenrolled workers-hence the question
outlined in Chapter 3 as an organizing device, discusses the    marks in the postretirement columns of Table 6.1. Other
main policy implications for LAC economies.               question marks in this table reflect the possible inability or
unwillingness of the social security administration to mon-
A Typology of Programs                                    itor whether beneficiaries are actually out of a job.
At least five different types of income support programs for  In this report, we take one example of each of the five
the unemployed have been tried in LAC.5 All of them       programs and examine how well it has helped to deal with
involve a net transfer of resources to workers who lose their   job loss. Public works are represented here by Argentina's
jobs, but the amount, conditions, and sources of the trans-    Trabajar program. This program  was created during
fer differ substantially across programs. Conceptually, some    1996-97, in response to a surge in unemployment in
of these programs can be seen as a mere redistribution of   1995. Trabajar allocates funds across provinces based on
resources, from  taxpayers to the unemployed; others   the distribution of the unemployed poor. Proposals to use
amount to forced savings or self-insurance, made available   the funds are made by municipalities and non-government
in the event of job loss. Still others resemble market insur-   organizations. These proposals are approved at the regional
ance, with a premium being paid while at work and a claim    level, based on a system of points related to poverty in the
being made in the event of unemployment.                  area and the merits of the project. The government pays for
The five types of income support programs used in the    the costs of unskilled labor and the sponsoring units pay
region are public works (PW), mandatory severance pay (SP),   for materials and skilled labor. The wage of unskilled
90



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
BOX 6.1
Income Support Programs for Me Unemployed: Main Features
Public works. This income support program was used by   salary, and in other countries the gratuity formula is dif-
Chile in the 1970s and 1980s, and was introduced more   ferent when job separation is due to economic reasons.
recently by Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, and Mexico.   Employers are usually not mandated to set aside any
The program provides low-wage jobs to all those who are   resources to pay the end-of-service gratuity.
willing to take them. In principle most of the jobs are in  Individual accounts. This is a "funded" version of the
activities that do not compete with the private sector,   severance pay program. Workers have individual
and the jobs can be physically demanding and typically   accounts to which some percentage of their salary is
last for only a few months. Therefore, it is likely that the   transferred on a regular basis. In the event of job separa-
program attracts unemployed workers and those out of   tion, whether voluntary or involuntary, workers can draw
the labor force, and not the currently employed. High   resources from their accounts. Any resources left in these
effort, short duration, and low pay imply that only the   accounts at retirement can be used toward old-age pen-
neediest participate.                                sions. Workers can also "borrow" from their accounts
Training. To the extent that some training programs   under specific circumstances. A program  along these
are specifically targeted to the unemployed, and provide an   lines has existed in Brazil for more than three decades.
income allowance to the trainees, they can be viewed as a   More recently, Colombia has replaced its severance pay
form of income support. Mexico has a large program along    program with fully funded individual accounts of this
these lines. Training programs for the unemployed have   type. Unlike unemployment insurance and severance pay,
some similarities to public works programs: resources are   this program involves no net transfer of resources to
provided by the government, beneficiaries do not need to    workers who lose their jobs.
be enrolled with any social security program to have access  Unemployment insurance. This program, modeled
to the training, and being enrolled in a training program    after those in developed countries, can be found in
is usually incompatible with having a job, so that there is   Argentina, Barbados, Brazil, Ecuador, Uruguay, and
some self-selection of the beneficiaries. In addition, these   Venezuela. Workers and employers in the formal sector
programs generate a "product" in the form of better skills,   make regular contributions to a fund, generally managed
although the market value of these skills is open to debate.   by the country's social security administration. After a
They are different from public works programs in that eli-   specified contribution period, workers are entitled to an
gibility rules generally apply-only individuals of speci-   unemployment benefit in the event of job loss (but aot of
fied age or education levels are allowed to participate,  voluntary separation). The benefit is some percentage of
Severance pay. This program can be found in most   the workers' salary, typically declining over time. Bene-
Latin American countries, where the labor code mandates   fits are paid for as long as the worker remains unem-
employers to pay an end-of-service gratuity to the work-   ployed, up to a maximum of several months or years.
ers they fire without a "justified" cause (that is, for   However, monitoring whether beneficiaries take a job in
nondisciplinary reasons). The gratuity is a multiple of the   the informal sector is practically impossible, so somne of
worker's salary; in some countries, the gratuity cannot   the programs do not even attempt to make the payment
exceed a specified amount or multiple of the worker's   of benefits conditional on actually being unemployed.
laborers is set at two-thirds of the average wage for the   ing standards due to the 1982 economic crisis. The stated
poorest decile in the capital city. In principle, there are no   objective of the program is to improve the productivity of
restrictions on the eligibility to participate in the program,   unemployed workers to help them find jobs. The program
but in practice there is rationing.                    provides publicly funded training and a subsistence
Mexico's Probecat training program was created in 1984,   allowance during the training, with a maximum duration
in response to rising unemployment and deteriorating liv-   of six months. The allowance is equal to the minimum
91



SECURING OUR FUTULRE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
'IABLE 6.1
How Various Income Support Programs for the Unemployed Work
FINDS         INCOME
ANOTHER        SUPPORT                           AT
PERIOD                    EMPLOYED        LOSES JOB     UNEMPLOYED         JOB            ENDS        UNEMPLOYED   RETIREMENT
-I             0               1              F              D              D+1             R
Public works                  0               0              W               0              0               0              ?
Training for unemployed        0              0              A               0              0               0              7
Mandatory severance pay        0              S              C,              0              0               0               ?
Individual saving accounts    -C             +C              +C              0              0               0             P+C
Unemployment insurance        -C              ?              B              B?              B?              0              P
Note: The timing of events is at follows: in period 0 the worker loses his or her job; in period F he or she rakes a new job; D is the maximum duration of benefits; R is the retire-
ment age. The table is constructed under the assumption that F comes before D, but this is not necessarily so in practice. The programs involve the following payments or transfers:
W is the salary paid by the public works program; S is the amount of severance pay received by the worker; A is a training allowance; -C is the contribution by worker and
employer to a program; +C is a contribution-defined income transfer; P is the old-age pension, with the question mark indicating that beneficiaries of the program are nor necessar-
ily enrolled with social security; B is anemployment benefits, with the question mark indicating that the worker may not receive the benefit during that period.
wage plus transportation costs and health insurance cover-    low. It was part of a broader set of reforms, which included
age. Training was initially carried out in schools and train-    trade and financial liberalization. Under the new  system,
ing centers, but it was subsequently expanded to enter-    workers have to contribute 9.3 percent of their salary to an
prises as well. Participating enterprises are required to hire     unemployment fund. They are entitled to their savings in
at least 70 percent of the trainees. Beneficiaries are selected    the event of termination, but can also "borrow" from them
based on a system of points, and can get trained only once.    for housing and education purposes while employed. In the
For about a decade the program was small, but after several    old system, workers could also borrow part of their sever-
positive reviews the program  was expanded by a factor of    ance pay entitlement from  their employers, but the value
10. Two criteria are used to evaluate the program: success    of the loan was not appropriately adjusted for inflation.
in providing income support (that is, an income transfer or    Some specific groups of workers can opt out of the new sys-
"social insurance" function) and effectiveness in reducing         tem, and get a higher salary in exchange for not being cov-
future incidence or duration of unemployment (that is, aid-    ered by the program.
ing "self-protection").                                               Brazil has the largest unemployment insurance program
The mandatory severance pay program examined here is    in the region, though it is small in comparison with those
the one Peru had during the 1990s. Over the two previous    in OECD countries with relatively frugal UI systems, such
decades, this program had been part of an attempt to guar-    as the U.S. system  (see Table 6.2 and Gill, Dar, and
antee job security to workers after probation. Job security        Thomas, 1999). This program  was created in 1986, as part
regulations lost their teeth in the early 1990s and were for-    of a policy package (the Cruzado plan) aimed at price stabi-
mally abolished in 1993. But mandatory severance pay reg-    lization. The program is funded by taxes levied by employ-
ulations were not substantially eased. Although the formula    ers. To be entitled to unemployment insurance benefits, a
setting the amount to be paid in the event of "unjustified"        worker has to be covered during 15 of the 24 months pre-
dismissal was modified four times in the 1990s, the basic    ceding job loss. Benefits are in the range of one to two min-
structure remained the same. As of 1996, the employer had          imum  monthly salaries,6 depending on past contributions.
to pay one month of salary per year of service, up to a max-    Benefits are paid in monthly installments, up to a maxi-
imum of 12 months. In 1997, mandatory severance pay was    mum of 120 days, but they are not contingent on being out
raised by 50 percent. Since then, the mandatory severance          of work. Workers need to be present in person at social
pay program  of Peru has not been modified.                        security centers to collect their benefits.
Colombia is one of the few LAC countries that suc-
ceeded in replacing its mandatory severance pay program            Main Findings
with an individual accounts program. This change was    The five income support programs can be assessed along
made in 1990, at a time when the unemployment rate was    several dimensions (see Box 6.2). Proposals to introduce
92



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
TABLE 6.2
Contrasting the Brazilian and the U.S. Unemployment Insurance Systems
CHARACTERISTICS                                       BRAZIL                                               U.S.
Administered by                   Federal government                                 State and federal governments
Number of Claimants               3-5 million per year                               15-20 million per year
Objectives                        (i) Alleviate hardships due to [oss of earnings    (i) Alleviate hardships due to loss of earnings
(ii) Automatic macro stabilization                 (ii) Automatic macro stabilization
(iii) Improving quality of job matches            (iii) Help stabilize employment by experience-rating of
(iv) Making employers share burden of unemployment    employers
Tax Rate                          Federal tax = 0.65% of revenues of private firms,  Federal tax = 0.8% of taxable payroll; State Tax varies
1.0% of revenues of public firms, and 1.0% of     from 0-1 0% of taxable payroll according to employers'
expenditures of nonprofit firms                    experience-rating
Tax Base                          Firm revenues or expenditures (see box above)      Federal: up to $7,000 of each employee's payroll
States: at least $7,000 of each employee's payroll (80%
of states had tax base above $7,000)
Use of Funds                      40% of collections transferred to uses other than paying    Both principal and interest must be used to pay only
Ul benefits through mandated transfer to national  Ul claims
development bank
Benefit Replacement Rates         80% of reference wages up to R$220 per month;      Between 32-57% up to benefit ceiling. Lowest ceiling
50% of wages between R$220-254 per month;         is $180/week; highest is $390 ($575 with dependency
0% above this                                      allowance)
Reference Wage                    Average salary 3 months prior to dismissal         Last salary before dismissal
Duration of Benefits              3-5 payments depending on work history during      Regular benefits up to 26 weeks; extended benefits up
previous 3 years; can receive Ul payment package only    to 13 additional weeks; additional temporary benefits
once in 16 months                                  during recessions
Source: Gill, Dar, and Thomas (1999).
"optimal" unemployment insurance, or individual sav-                   *  Cost. How large are income transfers in the program
ings accounts, usually focus on the incentives these pro-                  considered? What fraction of the total cost of the
grams could provide for workers to actively search for                     program  is actually  received by the worker? Do
jobs. In countries with high informality, however, it is                   workers "buy"  income  protection  through  lower
also important to consider who these programs reach. In                    wages, or is the burden  shifted to employers or
addition, the burden of some of these programs does not                    taxpayers?
fall only on their beneficiaries. Depending on who "pays"               * Incentives. Do workers who are covered by the pro-
for the benefits, and how, the programs can have different                 gram  remain unemployed for longer periods than
implications on efficiency and equity grounds. Finally, in                those who are not? Do they find jobs with higher
the absence of income support programs, some of the                        earnings, or jobs that are "better" in any other sense?
unemployed could resort to their savings, or to transfers               *  Insurance. Do workers who are covered by income
from  relatives, to support their consumption. It is there-                support programs display  smoother consumption
fore important to assess whether formal income support                     patterns than those who do not? Does the consump-
programs really  help  smooth  consumption, or simply                      tion of covered workers fall less, other things equal,
replace other more informal self-insurance mechanisms.                     in the event of job loss?
Based on these considerations, the findings on these five              Not all these questions can be easily answered for all the
income support programs can be summarized along four    programs. This would require a vast amount of informa-
dimensions:                                                         tion on the employment, earnings, and consumption his-
*  Coverage, How many workers are eligible to partic-    tory of a representative sample of workers, and the data
ipate in the income support program  considered?              available in the five countries usually do not deal with all
How many actually benefit from an income transfer,    of these variables at once. Moreover, information on the
or have benefited from  one recently? How does cov-    individual characteristics of the workers (such as age and
erage vary with wealth?                                       education) is necessarily limited. Therefore, it is always
93



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Box 62
Data $Sorces and MethodO 
Agentina's Taba/r                                    Anoa de Hoga*, for all the years between 1986 and
The efftcts of the Tr4ba]r program aeassessed coibiot-   1997. Th   attibute all the observed changes in job
ing two househol surveys, One of them, the Ecs       tenure to the weakening of lob security reguiations,
Dearoli Soia MS, was carried out in 1997 and cov-   although this was not the only reform or shock that took
ered the population residing in localities with 5,000 or   place over this period
more inhabitants. Jalan and Ravallion (1999) constructed
a conparison gr    out of the EDS sample, using dmah.   Colmias lniil Sai    Acoutt s
ing methods. The other household surve used to assess  ITn the case of Colombia, a similar natural experiment is
the effects of Traba* is a 1997 sample of its participants,   provided by the 1990 laor market reform, which
covering 3,500 househds. The infrmation used by   replaced severance payments by individual accounts. The
Ravadlion (2000) on Trab  r is fom  government   dat used by Kugler (2000) to assess the efcts of this I
eords.                                               change are daw  fom the June 1998, 1992, and 1996
rounds of the E�nct Nacioal de R es (ENH). This
exoirols Poet                                        survey was administered in the seven largest metropoli-
The assessment of the Prba: progrm by Wodon and   tan areas of Colormbia. June waves of the EN   include
Minowa (199  combines da  from the 1993940 rouads   special modues on infrmality, thus allowing the identi-
of National Urban Employment Survy (ENEW  and   fication of workers who are covered by mandatoy sever- 
from a survey administered rhly at the same time to   ance pay reulations (until 1990) or included in the indi-
Ptvbecat trainees. The atter was desied to match the   vidual accounts progrm (afterward). Given the nature of
questions in the ENEU, so hat information        the two   the policy  hange in 1990, the results obtained refer to 1
surveys is comparable. The two samples a  combined by   the effets of replacing seveace pay with individual
Wodon and Mnowa (1999) usng matching methods.        accounts, not to the specific efcts of the ltter.
| Peru  Mandatory Sevrwne                            Brzis Unemplmnt Insorance
The study on the effects of mandatory severance pay in   Brazil's unemploytmt insurnce program is studied by
Peru by Macsaac and Rama (2000) uses panel data fiom    Cunningham (200  using diaa fom a sample of males I
rhe Living Standards Measurement Surve  (LSMS) of   and females of workin  age who left a nonagricultural
1994 and 1997. The panel nature of the data allows con-   job, spent at least one month unemployed, and found a
trol fbr unobservable difeences across individuals.   new job. This sample is drawn foim the Pesqsisa Naonal
faIsaac and Rama combine several job indicators (years   deAmosr deDomiio (PNAD) in all years from 1992 to
of service, written conttact, enroIlment with social secu-   1997, excpt 1994, when there was no sumey. Each
r4ity size of the establishment, and presence of a union) to   round of the PNAD srey has over 360,000 observa-
evalae whether a worker will get severane pay in the   tions. Despite being quite restrictive, the criteria used by f
event of unjustified dismissal, The survey also conais   Cuningham led to a pooW sample of more than 24,000
infomation on earnings at the indivdual level, and con-   individuals. The increase in the generosity of unemploy-
I sunption at the household level. Saavedr and Torero    ment insurance benefits that took place in 1994 serves as
f (1999) analyze the impact of mandatory severance pay on    a natural experimen, allowing a difference-in-differences
turnover using data on job tenure fiom the Encue    evaluation of the effects of participation in the program.
possible to argue that differences in employment, earnings,   acteristics of the workers (for example, talent) which are
or consumption are not due to participation in a specific   correlated with program participation. For these reasons
income support program, but rather to unobservable char-  the evaluations should not be considered definitive assess-
94



HELPING WORKERS DIAL WITH THF RISK OF UlNEMPLOYMENT
ments. But the studies commissioned for this report, and             not being covered by the individual accounts program
some  other recent papers, take advantage  of multiple    (Kugler 2000).
observations for the same workers, or of changes in the reg-            The relatively high coverage of the programs among
ulatory framework, to identify some of the effects of the            those at work is in sharp contrast with the relatively low
programs.                                                            number of beneficiaries among the unemployed, as shown
by the second column in Table 6.3. The interpretation of
Who Is Covered by these Programs?                                    the figures in this column is not straightforward because
All five income support programs cover, in principle, a              they compare a flow (the number of beneficiaries in a year)
considerable portion of the labor force. The highest cover-    with a stock (the average number of unemployed during
age corresponds to  Argentina's public works program,    the same year). In countries where movements in and out
because anyone willing to take a job at the prevailing wage          of unemployment are frequent, as in Mexico, the total
rate is supposedly allowed to do it. In practlce, however,    number of people who are unemployed at any point over
the coverage of the program is determined by the resources    the year could be several times higher than the average
available. Coverage is slightly lower for Mexico's training          number of unemployed. Taking this into account, it would
program, because eligibility rules apply. The first column           be safe to conclude that at best, no more than 1 out of every
in Table 6.3 shows that the other three programs reach a             10 unemployed workers benefits from the income support
smaller but still sizable share of the labor force. The share        programs considered.
appears to be much lower in the case of Peru's mandatory                There are several reasons for the discrepancy between
severance pay program, but this is due mainly to the way             relatively high legal coverage and relatively low actual cov-
the denominator is defined: while coverage rates for Brazil    erage. One of them  is self-selection. Public works programs
and Colombia refer only to workers in the largest urban              pay low  wages, offer little continuity, and require hard
centers, the coverage rate for Peru refers to all private sec-    work, so that only the neediest among the unemployed
tor workers, including those in agriculture. The relatively          apply. Because training programs are not as physically
high coverage of the programs is consistent with casual evi-    demanding, and have the potential to increase skills, they
dence that workers do not opt out of them  when given the            could attract a larger number of candidates. The other
choice. In Colombia, for example, as of 1995 only 1.5 per-    three programs could lead to self-selection by employers.
cent of workers in manufacturing and 0.6 percent of work-    The latter should have no interest in extending contracts
ers in commerce preferred a higher salary in exchange for    beyond  the probationary  period, hence incurring  addi-
IABLE 6.i
Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Beneficiaries Across Population Groups
WORKERS         ACTUAL
LEGALLY      BENPFICIARIES
PROGRAM AND               COVERED BY   AS PERCENT OF                            SHARE OF BENEFICIARIES IN POPULATION GROUP (N)
COUNTRY                  THE PROGRAM   UNEMPLOYED
Poorest      2nd poorest       Middle         2nd richest      Richest
Public works in
Argentina                In principle, all     7.5            78.6            15.3            3.5             2.1             0.4
Training in Mexico   Eligible by age, education   29.4        69.9            15.5            8.1             5.0             1.5
Severance pay in Peru  21.2% of all private sector   3.6      4.7             9.5             28.6            33.,3           23.8
Unemployment
insurance in Brazil   39.6% of urban workers   11.8           10.6            24.6            19.1            25.1            13.6
Individual accounts in
Columbia              47.29% of urban workers Unknown          0.0            4.3        Not applicable       19.1            76.6
Noe: Coverage is based on legal enttltement. The unemployed include fiest-time job seeker-. Data foe Argentina are from Jalan and Raval-itn (1999) and Jones and Ravallion (1999)
and refer to 1997: groups are population quinetles according to household earnings per capita, excluding benefits paid by the program. Data for Mexico are from Wodon and
Mi,orwa ( 1999). Data for Peru are from Maclsaac and Rama (21010) and refer to 1994, private sector workers include farmers, the self-employed, and unpasd family workers; groups
are sample quintiles according to household consumption per capita Data for Brazil are frem Cunningham (2000); coverage figures are for 1997; groups are defined based on earn-
ings in last job, as of 1992, with cutoff points at 1, 2, 3. and 5 minimum wages. Data fot Colombia are from Kugler (20(0)0), and refer to 1992-96; groups are workers quartiles
according to income in last )ob.
95



SECURING OU1R FLrUTRE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
tional costs in terms of contributions or severance pay-   programs reviewed in this paper have a higher ratio of ben-
ments for workers they may not want to retain.          efit to nonbenefit expenses.
Another potential explanation for the discrepancy       Income transfers are financed in two different ways. In
between legal and actual coverage is the weakness of   the case of Argentina's public works program and Mexico's
enforcement capabilities. In the case of Peru, MacIsaac and   training program, the funding comes mainly from the
Rama (2000) construct a coverage score that combines four   budget, hence from general taxation. In the other three
criteria, in addition to legal entitlement: having a written    cases, the transfers are funded by explicit or implicit taxes
contract, being enrolled in social security, working in a   on employment. In principle, taxes on employment could
firm where at least one trade union operates, and working    be either more or less distortionary than general taxation,
in a large firm. It can be assumed that the likelihood of   depending on the nature of the tax system in force. But all
actually getting severance pay in the event of dismissal   taxes carry a marginal burden, in the sense that they reduce
increases with the number of criteria met by the worker. If   economic efficiency. This burden should be factored in
only those workers who meet at least one of these criteria    when assessing programs such as Argentina's Trabajar or
do get severance in practice, the coverage rate falls from    Mexico's Probecat. More specifically, the value of the physi-
21.1 percent to 9.3 percent of the labor force. It drops to   cal or human assets generated by the programs should not
5.2 percent if workers have to meet any two of the criteria.   be high enough just to cover their cost, but also to cover
In the case of Brazil, Cunningham (2000) reports that a   the corresponding marginal tax burden. The last column in
significant portion of the unemployed is entitled to unem-   Table 6.4 suggests that in practice this is not the case.
ployment benefits, but does not collect them. This could   The employment tax is formally similar in the Brazil-
be due to the lack of social security offices nearby.   ian, Colombian, and Peruvian income support programs.
The actual beneficiaries of income support programs    In particular, contributing 9.3 percent of the workers'
tend to be relatively wealthy, with Mexico's Probecat and    salary to an individual accounts program amounts to set-
Argentina's public works program the exception. Trahajar   ting aside roughly one month of salary per year of work.
is a poverty alleviation program targeted through unem-   Therefore, in the mid-1990s the employment "taxes" in
ployment, rather than an income support program for the   the Colombian and Peruvian income support programs
unemployed. In all of the other programs for which the    were roughly the same. Some of the proponents of the indi-
information is available, the poorest population group has   vidual accounts system claim that an income support pro-
the smallest number of beneficiaries. Beneficiaries tend to   gram  along the Colombian lines is less burdensome to
be more numerous among middle- or upper-middle income    employers than a program along the Peruvian lines. How-
groups. Colombia's individual account program is the least   ever, Peruvian employers could set resources aside on a
pro-poor; more than three quarters of the beneficiaries can    monthly basis, if they wished to. It is not at all obvious
be found among the richest quarter of the urban population.   that forcing them to do so would make them better off.
However, savings accounts that are administered by third
How Much Do the Programs Cost?                          parties (not employers or workers) do facilitate labor
The average income transfer received by the beneficiaries of   mobility, reduce legal claims, and provide workers with
these programs ranges from roughly US$300 in Mexico to    more certain benefits.
US$1,300 in Argentina. The spending figures reported for   A  potentially more important difference between
these two countries in the first column of Table 6.4 are   income support programs relying on an employment tax is
higher, because they also include other costs of the pro-   related to the endogenous adjustment of wages. If a pro-
grams. In the case of Argentina, only one-third of each dol-   gram is valued by the workers, they should be willing to
lar spent is paid to laborers, with the other two-thirds    "pay" for it through lower wages. In principle, the net
going to materials ancl skilled personnel in charge of the   impact of a program on wages depends on its explicit or
activities supported by the program (Ravallion 1999a).   implicit employment tax, on how  much the workers
The ratio increases to roughly three-quarters in the case of   "value" the benefits from the program, and on the wage
Mexico, with the other quarter going to trainers' salaries   elasticity of labor demand and supply. This net impact was
and other related expenses. The other three income support   evaluated using panel data estimates for Peru by Mac Isaac
96



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF tlNEMPLOYMENT
TABLE 6.4
Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Cost per Beneficiary
BURDEN ON EMPLOYERS
AVERAGE
SPENDING PER                                  CHANGE IN                                 VALUE OF ASSETS
PROGRAM AND              BENEFICIARY          CONTRIBUTIONS           EQUILIBRIUM            BURDEN ON           GENERATED PER
COUNTRY                (IN U.S. DOLLARS)       OR PAYMENTS            WAGE (IN %)            TAXPAYERS            BENEFICIARY
Public works in Argentina    3,100                 None               Not applicable             All            Similar to spending
Training in Mexico           393                   None               Not applicable             All               Insignificant
Severance pay in Peru        760              1 monthly wage per       Insignificant            None              Not applicable
year, lump sum
Unemployment insurance       664               0.65% of firm's          Unknown            None (the system       Not applicable
in Brazil                                     revenue, monthly                              runs a surplus)
Individual accounts in     Unknown             9.3% of workers'        Insignificant            None              Not applicable
Colombia                                        wage, monthly
Nrte: Data foe Argentina are from Ravallion (1999a), Jalan and Ravallion (1999), and Jones and Ravallion (1999), and refer to 1997. Cost data for Mexico were kindly provided by
Quentin Wodon; the assessment of the value of the assets is from Wodon and Minowa (1999). Data for Peru are from Maclsaac and Rama (2000): payment by employer refers to
1994, whereas change in equilibrium wage was eseimated on 1994-97 panel data. Data for Brazil are from Cunningham (2000); spending refers to 1995. Data for Colombia are
from Kugler (2000): the change in the equilibrium wage was estimated using differences in differences for 199(1 and 1992-96
and Rama (2000), and using difference-in-differences esti-    when they were substantially weakened. But there was
mators for Colombia by Kugler (2000). In both cases, the           mandatory severance pay in both periods, whereas in the
net impact turned out to be statistically  insignificant,    meantime the economy was subject to many other eco-
implying  that the burden of these two programs falls    nomic reforms and external shocks. In the case of Colom-
entirely on employers.                                             bia, the shorter unemployment spells reported by Kugler
(2000) after 1990 could not be due to a change in the
What Are the Efficiency Effects and Insurance Benefits?            amount of the transfers received, or in the conditions
Proposals to introduce "optimal" unemployment insurance            attached to them. The only difference is that in the new
or individual savings accounts often emphasize the distor-    system  the beneficiaries can keep the unused portion of
tions to incentives created by conventional unemployment    their transfer in their individual accounts, whereas in the
insurance. Key among those distortions is the lower effort    old system they would have had to put that portion into a
devoted to a job search by those who collect unemploy-    bank account, or found some other form of investment for
ment benefits. On the other hand, it can be argued that    it. It is difficult to believe that the difference in returns
income support allows the unemployed to search for a    between these two alternatives is large enough to justify a
longer period, possibly leading to a better job match. More        difference of three weeks in the duration of unemployment
generally, income support programs for the unemployed              spells. The same reasoning casts doubt on the allegedly
could have effects on the duration of unemployment spells,    higher earnings observed upon reemployment.
on the earnings level subsequent to reemployment, and                 One of the few clear-cut results in Table 6.5 refers to
even on nonpecuniary characteristics of the new jobs. The          where people get jobs after unemployment ends. In the
evidence available in this respect is limited. However, the        case of Brazil, Cunningham  (2000) finds that unemploy-
results summarized in Table 6.5 suggest that all these             ment beneficiaries are more likely to become self-employed
incentive effects are weak.                                        than nonbeneficiaries. This result is consistent with credit
Some of the evidence on unemployment spells is diffi-    rationing at the household level. Under this hypothesis,
cult to interpret. In the case of Peru, the allegedly longer    unemployment benefits would provide start-up capital,
unemployment spells are derived  from  an analysis of    and the most profitable use of this capital would be to run
changes in  job tenure over time. Saavedra and Torero              an independent business. This choice would not be avail-
(1999) show that job tenure was longer in the 1980s, when          able to those who do not receive unemployment benefits.
job security regulations were in force, than in the 1990s,    This result is also consistent with the view that working in
97



SECURING OUR FUTURL  IN A GLOBAL FC(ONOMY
TABLE 6.5
Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Effects on Employment, Eamings, and Consumption
EFFECTS ON                 EFFECTS ON                 EFFECTS ON             CONSIJMPTION INCOME
DURATION OF                EARNINGS ON                  SECTOR OF                  RELATIVE ro
UJNEMPIOYMENT              REEMPLOYMENT                REEMPLOYMENT               NONPARTICIPIANTS
Public works in Argentina          Unknown                    Unknown                     Unknown               25.9c higher income
Training in Mexico               Insignificant               Insignificant                Unknown                     Unknown
Severance pay in Peru               Longer                    Unknown                     Unknown              Consumption rose 6.8%�
for beneficiar-ies;
fell 16.9% for
nonrbeneficiaries
Unemployment insurance            Insignificant              Insignificant             Self-employment               Unknowi
in Brazil                                                                                more likelv
Individual accounts           Three weeks shorter            5.5% higher                  Unknown                    Unknown
in Colombia
Noote: Information for Argentina is from Jalan and Ravallion (1999), based on 1997 data on household income per capita. Information on Mexico is from Wadon and Miscwa (1999.)
INfarmarian an Pero is from Ma,csaac and Ra-a (20011) far consumpesan. suing data for 1994-97. and Soa.odra and Torres- (1999) fo, athere; anmplovoe s1el Is are assme-d rob
longer because the average job tenure was longer in the late 198Os, when job security regulations were in force, than in the late 199()s. Information oB Brazil is trDm CLsnriogham
(21)()()). Information an Columbia is from Kogl-e (211011); un-mplopy-nc spells are shoter compared to chase ,f sorke-s -neirled to sooeroac pay, bhocnc nec-sa-ily -cp-.arad te
chose who are nor covered by ar, income support program.
the informal sector is not necessarily an inferior outcome,    market changes in the region, we offer some summary
but often a deliberate choice.                                       observations specifically for the five programs surveyed
Credit constraints at the household  level could also             above. First, nonlabor costs in Argentina's Trabajar appear
underlie the apparent effectiveness of income support pro-           to be high, so there is room  for improving the effectiveness
grams at providing insurance, which is suggested by the              of public works programs as instruments for income trans-
evidence from  Argentina and Peru. If households could    fers by lowering the non wage component, though this
borrow when one of their members is confronted with tem-    may jeopardize the quality and nature of the investments
porary job loss, they should not experience a serious drop           being made through the program  (see also the following
in consumption. In Peru, consumption per capita drops by             section). Second, the training in Mexico's Prohecat seems
more  than  16  percent when  one  household  member    ineffective, so there may be potential saving if the share
becomes unemployed and does not get severance; on the                spent on training costs is reduced or redirected. Third, sev-
other hand, consumption per capita increases by almost 7             erance pay in Peru appears to be excessively generous.
percent if the unemployed member gets severance. This                Fourth, individual savings accounts in Colombia seem  to
result suggests that the Peruvian program  mandates sever-           be used mainly by the wealthy, who are more likely to have
ance payments that are too generous. Jalan and Ravallion             voluntary savings anyway  Fifth, Brazil's unemployment
(1999) show that the foregone income from  participating             insurance scheme covers largely those who also have indi-
in Argentina's Trabajar program  amounts to only half of    vidual severance  accounts, thus providing  insurance-
the transfer received.7 For the average household, partici-          although quite frugal for most workers-to those who also
pation results in an increase of almost 26 percent in income         benefit from  mandatory severance laws. Finally, these pro-
per capita, a figure quite close to the 23 percent difference        grams cover little more than  10 percent of the unem-
in consumption per capita between beneficiaries and non-    ployed, implying that by themselves they fail to offer most
beneficiaries in Peru. Unfortunately, there are no similar    workers any insurance against job loss.
estimates available for the other three income support pro-
grams considered.                                                    Policy Implications
There Is an increasing clamor for greater unemployment
What Are the Aain Weaknesses of these Programs?                      insurance in the region. There is also a widely held view,
Bcfore drawing  the policy implications of these assess-    however, that given the nature of labor markets and the
ments in the broader context of macroeconomic and labor    extent of administrative capacity in developing countries,
98



HfELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
they should hesitate before setting up formal unemploy-   ment self-protection, or lower the probability of occurrence
ment insurance systems. In fact, extensive informality   of crises or shocks. Chapter 4 discussed the monetary, fis-
results in even greater problems in administering benefit   cal, and capital market policies that will help lower the
payments because it is difficult for the Ul agency to deter-   frequency and size of economic crises, including unem-
mine if claimants are in fact unemployed: many may be   ployment of workers. This section discusses another impor-
working in the unregulated sector while drawing benefits.   tant set of public policy measures in this regard: labor mar-
It also creates problems in financing the Ul system because   ket reforms.
it will be impossible to make a large number of employers  Each country has a unique social consensus on the desir-
and employees pay their contributions. The recent experi-   able balance between economic efficiency and social equity,
ence of Argentina is symptomatic of both problems (see for   and labor policies straddle both concerns. Different eco-
example, Mazza 1999). These considerations have led    nomic and political histories of countries can result in sig-
observers to argue that middle-income countries in East   nificant differences between the impact of seemingly iden-
Asia and Latin America would be better off reforming their   tical laws on wages and employment, so that the subset of
mandated severance payment schemes rather than institut-   binding laws-and hence the labor reform agenda-is
ing formal Ul systems (see, for example, Edwards and    country specific (see Box 6.3). Here we simply note that
Manning 1999). Variants of Brazil's individualized sever-   labor market reform has lagged behind other economic
ance accounts (Fundo Garantia por Tempo de Servicio [FGTS])   reforms in most countries in the region, with only a few
are sometimes recommended as a substitute for unemploy-   exceptions such as Chile. In fact, it has been described as
ment insurance.                                        the "forgotten" economic reform in LAC (Edwards and
Using the findings summarized in the last section and    Lustig 1997), or a major comnponent of an unfinished
the conceptual framework outlined in Chapter 3, this sec-   agenda of 'second generation reforms" in the region
tion reevaluates these and related propositions. This reeval-  (Guasch 1999a). For governments that wish to facilitate
uation is done not with the objective of recommending    comprehensive insurance decisions by their workers and
specific changes in existing mechanisms for income sup-   households in a rapidly changing global economy, labor
port for the unemployed-though there may be some    market reform should get high priority.
lessons to be learned-but to contribute to the general dis-
cussion that will gather steam as countries in the region    Self-insurance: Individual Savings Accounts
reassess whether the mechanisms they employ are indeed    Programs where a specified part of a worker's salary is set
appropriate for the types of product, labor, and financial   aside in an account-generally held in a government-
markets they have, and the types of aggregate and micro-   approved financial institution, sometimes with guaranteed
economic risks faced by workers and firms. In particular,   rates of interest as in the case of Brazil's Fundo Garantia por
we provide some tools and techniques to policymakers to   Tempo de Servicio-are a form of forced self-insurance. Since
determine the suitability and adequacy of the alternative    governments cannot credibly state that they will not "res-
programs of income support for the unemployed by asking    cue" people who did not save enough, people may not save
the questions: Do individuals have effective instruments of   enough on their own-hence the need to make the pro-
comprehensive insurance against the risk of unemploy-   gram compulsory (Coate 1995). The main drawback of
ment, that is, market insurance, self-insurance, and self-  these programs is that they do not involve pooling of
protection? If not, are government programs providing the   unemployment risks, and hence lead to lower consumption
missing instruments?                                   and investment by households than traditional unemploy-
ment insurance programs that are more "pay-as-you-go" in
Self-Protection: The State of Labor Markets            nature (see Gill, Haindl, Montenegro, and Sapelli 2000 for
The logical first step in examining whether enough is   more on this distinction). While this may not lead to
being done to help workers deal with unemployment   reduced welfare for wealthier households, poorer workers
shocks is to determine if more can be done to reduce the   would suffer more. Their main strengths are that they min-
probability of these shocks. In the terminology of Chapter   imize disincentive effects on work that are unavoidable in
3, this constitutes the set of government actions to aug-   programs that involve pooling, make severance benefits
99



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
l                                          '     ' r---   -'-   -' '' -'-^-' ''  -  ''  -  '--  ''-  ---''  > -  {'-'' " ''  >-'--'..''.''. .-'-. .--.''.---.-..-'. - - ---'-- --''--'---'--'-'    -' - e- ---'-- - ----^^--. .'''-'-''.   ' - - - ' -''- - -- -'- 
BOX 6.3
Labor Markets: Latin America's "Forgotten Refonnm"
This box describes the four main lessons of a recent study    Labor Outcomes Depd only Party on Labor Polies 
(Gill and Montenegro 2000) that quanitatively assesses    Labor reform  is neither necessary nor sufficient for
the main labor market issues in Argentina, Brazil, and    improving  labor outcomes. As the experiences of
Chile.                                                    Afgentina, Brazil, and Chile show, successfil stabiliza- E
tion unaccompanied by changes in labor policy in general
Labor Poli  issues are Country Speiof                     improves labor outcomes, though it also unmasks micro-
Ironically, the first general lesson is that regional gener-    economic imbalances (public-private compensation dif-
alizations abou0t labor policy are often pointless or mis-   ferentials in Brazil, relative prices of labor and capital in
leading. There are no shortcuts: implementable labor   Argentina, and the gaps between the rich and poor in
policies must be designed by understanding labor mar-    Chile). Similarly, fiscal adjustment col  also improve
kets country by country. For examle, there is evidence    employment and earnings outcomes, illustrating that
that a large number of workers are paid exactly the legal    actions such as putting government finances in order can
minimum wage even in Brazil's "unregulated" sector, and    improve outcomes in the private labor market, even if no
adjustments in this wage are matched by salary adjust-   labor reforms tke place. Further, moving fiom a period
iments. It is possibleand indeed has been confirmed-      of adjustmnent to sustained economic growth will
that in some other countries minimum  wages are not    mprove earnings and employment outcomes, even if
binding even in the regulated sector; but it would be    there are no accompanying improvements in labor poli-
unwise to assert either that mininum wage legislation is   cies, However, this does not mean that outcomes coldd
not imnportant for economic outcomes or that iQt is imnpor-    not be better still if appropriate labor reforms are made, I
tant for all or most countries. Again, the finding that sus-   though it is harder to make this case persuasively.
tained growth in Chile has not been associated with
increasing earnings inequality does not guarantee similar   Making Labor Pocies Better is Dfilt During
I results for other countriesi it merely weakens claims by    Good Times
I people who question the desirability of growth-orienrted    The first corollary of the above is that it is difficult to
i labor policies instituted during the 1980s in Chile.      carry out labor reform3s during economic booms. In  I
more certain for workers, and lower transactions costs.   of government (because market insurance would be avail-
These considerations present the challenge of balancing    able only at a high price given that the chances of a worker
labor market efficiency and poverty concerns.               being unemployed are high).
The framework set forth in Chapter 3 can help resolve       While considerable variation in unemployment rates
this dilemma. Following that framework, programs con-    exists among LAC economies, the regionwide average was
taining a significant mandatory self-insurance component   estimated to be about 10 percent in 1999.8 The likelihood
may be especially well suited for countries where workers    of becoming unemployed is anything but rare in most
face high risk, for example, those that have high average    countries, therefore, especially for the young, the less edu-
rates of unemployment. For workers in these countries-if   cated, and women, as seen in Chapter 5. For these reasons,
there were no public interventions to help the unem-    mandated self-insurance may be well suited for countries
ployed-comprehensive insurance against this risk would   such as Argentina and Brazil that have not carried out
entail a relatively large component of self-insurance rela-    comprehensive economic-especially  labor market-
tive to market insurance. Mandating such self-insurance    reforms. By the same token, they may be less suited for
ensures time consistency of government behavior, but does    countries such as Chile, where the risks of unemployment
not impose forms of insurance on individuals that would be    have been lowered through far-reaching economic reforms
purchased only in relatively small amounts in the absence    (see below). But even countries such as Argentina should
100



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
Argentina, for example, labor policies did not rise to the   of the likely effects of policy refbrm can help to advance
top of the reform agenda during 1990-94 even though   the reforms. Labor reform is always difficult and-when E
unemployment was increasing steadily, because of   attempted-reforms are usually piecemeal. In every
improving wage and employment conditions as a result   country, there are well-entrenched labor interests, politi-
of successful stabilization. When the Tequila Crisis hit   cal risks for reformers are high, and proponents of reform
Argentina, unemployment skyrocketed and labor   such as employers or economists are often ineffective in
reform  came to the forefront of discussions, only to   convincing people of the benefits of taking risks. To help
recede again when economic growth resumed as fiscal   policymakers focus their efforts and explain them to the
and financial reforms advanced. Again, in Brazil, labor   electorate, it is important to know whether labor policy
reforms only briefly dominated the political landscape    changes are necessary and, if so, which aspects of labor
when unemployment rates rose to historic levels in   policy are binding, which are irrelevant, and what are the
mid- 1 998 after the economy slid into a recession. When   likely benefits. Quantification of the benefits of labor pol-
the economic slowdown proved to be less severe than   icy reform-rather than relying only on economic
anticipated and unemployment rates fell, labor policy    growth-shows that Argentina probably has paid a high
reform was moved off the Brazilian government's list of   price for not reforming labor legislation between 1995
priorities. Finally, a decade of sustained growth and    and 2000. For Brazil, again using a quantitative
improving employment and earnings outcomes in Chile   approach, the aspects of labor legislation that are the
had the effect of prompting the reversal of labor reforms   most important for outcomes can be isolated. Quantify-
that may have made these outcomes possible in the first   ing the concept of "precariousness" helps to determine
place.                                                that Chile may be better off leaving labor policies largely
unaltered, and looking to other policy measures such as
Quantifying Key Magnitudes can Facilitate Labor       improved education quality to narrow the income gap
Reform                                                between the rich and the pOOr,
The second corollary of the finding that labor outcomes   b
only partly depend on labor policies is that quantification
not turn their backs to pooled-risk insurance schemes:   because the loss of employment is often too large a shock,
pooling offers immediate poverty-related advantages and,   or may affect a large fraction of the population at the same
over the longer term as labor reforms progress and unem-   time. Morduch (1999) argues that informal insurance, for
ployment rates fall, it becomes more and more preferred to   example, through reciprocal transfers within the extended
self-insurance (see Box 3.1). Guasch (1999b) proposes a   family or community, may thus be the least effective when
program that could address both short- and long-term con-   help is most needed. Private, market-based arrangements
siderations for countries embarking on labor reforms. A    may fail because of informational and incentive problems
study at the World Bank proposes to again address the   involved in insuring against even rare risks, toward which
suitability of mandated self-insurance as income support   individuals and households have a rational inclination, ver-
for unemployment (Vodopovic 2000).                      sus self-insurance (the "price" of which is the same for rare
and frequent losses, and self-protection, for which expendi-
"Market-Type" Insurance: Risk-Pooling Programs    tures may yield only small payoff when the probability of
While precise conditions for the introduction of public   the bad state occurring is already low; see Chapter 3).
programs are difficult to pinpoint, there are advantages of  While concerns that publicly provided insurance will
formal, public programs in addressing unemployment risk.   displace some private rtansfers are justified (see, for exam-
Informal insurance mechanisms may not be effective,   ple, Cox and Jimenez 1998), its introduction may improve
101



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
efficient because they can pool resources across larger
BOX 6.4
Combining Mandated Self-insurance and Mar*et-Type    . goups.
Unemployment Insurance
Severance Pay Provisions as Insurance for
Guasch (1 999b) recommends combining individual      Unemployment
savings accounts-which have the weakness that they   The most common form of public unemployment insur-
involve no pooling of risk and are simply fbrced self-    ance in most of Latin America has been mandatory sever-
insurance-and conventional uremployment itisur-      ance pay provisions, such as those evaluated in depth by
ance-which runs the risk of abuse in economies with  MacIsaac and Rama (2000) for Peru. Though not generally
high rates of formal unemployment combined with I   associated with "market insurance" that involves pooling
high shares of informal employmett,                  of risks, these programs in fact do pool risks to provide
The main characteristics of the proposed program.   insurance in the event of unemployment (with the
are:                                                 employer and/or all workers paying an "insurance pre-
E* ach employee is assigned an individlual account int    mium" through reduced salary and benefits while
an eligible financial institution of his or her choice,  employed). The problem is that because the employer is
* Each month, the worker and employer dits  a        responsible for severance pay, the pooling is at the level of
fixed fraction of wages inro the account.         the firm, and hence the risk is spread over only a small
* The money is invested in finamcial securities but  group. In the old economic environment protected by
with strong safeguards agalist loss of prtincip l    trade barriers, the risks were effectively pooled over a
value,                                        f greater population because consumers effectively subsi-
e The account is fully portable in the event of job sep-  dized potentially bankrupt firms through higher prices.
aration or rtirement.                             With globalization and reduced barriers to trade, however,
* Access to finds is permitted only in the eve of I   this is no longer possible because products must be sold at
uinemployment or retiremnent, and monthy with-    world prices.
drawals are limited to a fraction of last monthly   If this scheme had proved to be administratively
salary.                                           uncomplicated relative to other options, there might still
* A part of the worker's/employer's contribution goes  be a reason to recommend the use of severance pay provi-
into a general fum-ministerd at the firin, sec-   sions. But, as pointed out in Rama and Maloney (2000),
tor, or economywide level-to comtpement the       most of the grievances handled by labor courts in Latin
accounts of workers who may not h     rechd       America are in fact related to disputes over severance pay.
amounts that would allow  cettain minimum         Employment adjustments needed for economic reasons are
amounts when separated firm work,                 rendered complicated, and workers are deterred from seek-
* Minimum monthly withdrawals fbr a maximum          ing better job matches voluntarily. These mandates may
stipulated period are guaranteed only fbr certain  therefore be the worst among public "market-type insur-
types of workers (for example, heads of househod,  ance" programs: they involve high moral hazard with little
* firing with just cause should include dismissals by  pooling of risks, and may discourage hiring in the first
the employer due to economic reasons, and legisla-  place and hence raise the risk of unemployment for those
tion should be made clear and simple.             looking for jobs. They exist in most countries in the region
even today; these countries may be well advised to seri-
ously reevaluate the suitability of these mandates in rela-
both welfare and efficiency. For example, in poorer coun-   tion to other alternatives for ensuring income support for
tries the beneficiaries of private transfers are often the   the unemployed.
elderly, and keeping more income for themselves would
enable the young-who may also be poor-to invest more   Public Works Programs as Insurance for Unemployment
in their own education and health and that of their chil-   Again, though generally not regarded as "market-type"
dren (Morduch 1999). Public systems may also be more   insurance that involves pooling of risks and the charging of
102



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH TIHE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
premiums, public works programs of the type analyzed    cost per transfer and in the cost per job created, with no
above can in principle be treated as such.9 The question    obvious implications for policy. In other words, these pro-
addressed here is whether these programs have fulfilled this   grams appear to aim  at a combination of objectives-
role in the LAC region and whether there are any lessons   income smoothing, employment per se, provision of infra-
for the future.                                           structure-which  makes difficult the comparison of
The main strength of these programs is that if properly    workfare to other income support programs. Training pro-
designed as a "work guarantee" (low wages, no rationing,   grams, such as Probecat, can be seen as a special case of such
low nonlabor costs-see Ravallion 1999) they serve effec-   programs where the investment is now in human capital
tively as unemployment insurance for those who formerly   rather than infrastructure. Since matcrials costs are low, the
were employed (in formal or informal jobs) and for house-   rate of transfer is very high.
holds the coping strategy of which is for family members
to begin working when the main earner becomes unem-    "Conventional" Unemployment Insurance
ployed."0 The experience in the region and outside shows   One of the more attractive features of a well-designed
that these programs are able to target the poor when    unemployment insurance program is that it can simultane-
designed specifically for this purpose.                   ously help offset (part of) both microeconomic and macro-
Both Ravallion (2000) and Snyder and Yackovlev    economic fluctuations. In a study of the political economy
(2000) confirm that some leakage to the nonpoor makes for   aspects of social insurance and transfer programs in the
resilience in social programs during economic contractions.   U.S. and Latin America, Snyder and Yackovlev (2000) con-
But the results for Argentina's Trabajar suggest the pro-   duct cross-section, time-series analysis on 45 program-
gram was clearly subject to the same constraints in the    groups in the U.S. during 1962-98. Parr of the analysis
political economy that influenced the incidence of past fis-   focuses explicitly on what happens during the economic
cal contractions in Argentina. The program expanded into   cycle and major political changes, contrasting spending
poor areas when the budget increased, but it retreated from    levels just prior to recessions with the levels during reces-
poor areas when the budget was cut. It was the program's   sions. One of the findings is that the only class of programs
disbursements to nonpoor areas that were protected."1     which show a clearly countercyclical pattern of spending
Further, as Maloney (2000) argues, there is a question    are those classified as "income security programs" (for
about the cost-effectiveness of these programs and, even    example, social security, family assistance, food stamps,
more fundamentally, the proper means to evaluate them.   and unemployment insurance). Most of the other social
Measured against other income protection programs con-   protection functions exhibit no clear pattern, and some
sidered here which seek primarily to transfer income to   show evidence of procyclicality. Overall, spending on social
households experiencing shocks, the emphasis on employ-   protection program-groups appears countercyclical, but
ment through infrastructure projects means that a large   the most countercyclical program in the U.S., by far, is
fraction of the funds earmarked for income protection may    unemployment insurance.`'
be diverted to materials and capital costs. In noncrisis    Most observers would probably not find this surpris-
periods, these projects may be socially valuable when eval-   ing-as unemployment rises during a recession, unem-
uated at the market rate of discount. During crises, how-   ployment insurance expenditures should rise as well. But it
ever, when poor families facing credit constraints strongly   is not unreasonable to expect that in the fiscally con-
discount the future, they represent a diversion of resources   strained atmosphere of a recession, unemployment benefits
away from  present income transfers that is socially    might be cut or eligibility constrained, so as not to "bust
costly.12                                                 the budget." Evidently, this does not occur in the U.S.
In this regard, Chile and Mexico appear to place a high    Instead, a 1 percent increase in unemployment leads to
value on the transfer and less on the investment per se, so   somewhat more than a 1 percent increase in unemploy-
that they reach rates of transfer close to 70 percent (see    ment spending. This "automatic stabilizer" function makes
Wodon 2000). Argentina and Colombia seem to value the    it worthwhile to examine unemployment insurance pro-
project component more, so they transfer 40 percent or   grams more closely, especially that of the U.S., which has
less. This implies large differences across countries in the    several other attractive features as well."4
103



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Traditional unemployment insurance is usually financed          design. The U.S. federal government, for example, pays
through  conitributions by employers and/or employees,    state governments for administration costs. Countries such
though government subsidies-either to cover deficits or    as France, Germany, and the U.K. also pay the administra-
to fund programs such as means-tested  unemployment    tion costs of UI programs, while not subsidizing payments
assistance-are usually significant. Table 6.7 shows the            to UI claimants. Another exception may be the payment
extent of burden-sharing in the financing of UI (Gill, Dar,    by government of social security dues on beha]f of the
and Thomas 1999, based on data reported in Tzannatos               unemployed during the period he or she is eligible to
and Roddis 1998). In only 10 countries is the burden               receive unemployment insurance benefits-for example, in
entirely  borne  by  just one party. Brazil, where only            Germany and Portugal-though in principle this could
employers contribute to Ul financing, is the notable exam-    also be financed from  UJ contributions. It is easier to jus-
ple of such countries in LAC. Burden-sharing between two           tify government subsidies, for assistance, to those among
parties is more prevalent, especially between employers    the unemployed who are poor, determined through reliable
and  employees. In  13 countries, including  Argentina,    means-testing. Under such a system, the governmint pays
Ecuador, and Venezuela, the burden is shared by both. In    for modest benefits for those where the main eligibility cri-
Argentina, the UI program  is financed by a 1.5 percent    teria are not proof of past contributions and current invol-
payroll tax on employers and a 1 percent tax on workers'    untary  unemployment (as required  for unemployment
wages (Mazza 1999). The most prevalent means of financ-    insurance), but proof of current poverty (which is funda-
ing Ul systems is through contributions by all three par-    mental) and of current involuntary unemployment (which
ties, with 38 countries financing their UI system  through         is secondary). Governments in Austria, Finland, France,
these means. In 17 of these 38 countries, the role of the          and the U.K. finance unemployment assistance along these
government is limited to just paying off any deficit.15            lines.'6
Under most scenarios, it is difficult to justify large-scale       Table 6.6 provides information on who among workers
permanent subsidization of unemployment insurance pro-    or employers is legally responsible for contributing to the
grams by the government. The insurance aspect of the               scheme on behalf of workers. Who actually pays-In more
scheme implies that benefits should be paid from  contri-    general economic terms-is a far more complicated ques-
butions. One exception is, perhaps, the cost of administer-    tion, the answer to which depends on the design of the pro-
ing UI programs; it is reasonable to expect the government    gram  and  the  relative  market power of workers and
to pay the administration costs of a system  that it has set    employers, both of which are country-specific considera-
up, especially if it wishes to significantly influence its    tions (see Box 6.5). The relative market power of employ-
TABLE 66
Costs of Unemployment Insurance: Burden-Sharing Among Workers, Employers, and Government
PAID BY                            OECD                             LATIN AMERICA AND OTHER                    TOTAL NUMBER
Worker only              None                          None                                                           0
Employer only            Iceland                       Bangladesh, Brazil, Moldova                                    4
Government only          Australia, New Zealand        Chile, Estonia, Hong Kong, Tunisia                             6
Employer and government   Iraly                        Bulgaria, China, Georgia, Russia                               5
Employer and worker      Canada, Greece, Netherlands,  Algeria, Argettina, Barbados, Ecuador, Hungary, Serbia        13
Sweden, U.S.                 and Monrenegro, South Africa, Venezuela
Employer and/or worker;   Belgium, Denmark, Ireland,   Albania, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Czech Rep., Egypt,     17
government pays any deficit   Norway                   Iran, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Turkmenistan, Ukraine,
Uzbekistan
All three; goverrinrent's  Austria, Finland, France,   Croatia, Cyprus, Guernsey, Israel, Kyrgyscan, Latvia,         21
contribution is nonresiduai    Germany, Japan, Luxembourg,    Liechtenstein, Malta, Slovak Rep, Slovenia, Uruguay
Portugal, Spaii, Switzerland,
U.K.
Nate: Turkey and Mexico are the onlv OECD countries wichout formal unemployment insurance systems as defined in this paper.
Source: Tzannatos and Roddis (1998), using data reported in Shanil Securiy Systers Throughout the World-1997, published by the U.S. Social Security Administration.
104



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
BOX 6.5
Who Really Pays for Unemployment Insurance?
Who bears how much of the burden of contributions to   FIGURE 6.1
formal unemployment insurance depends on two factors:   Workers Pay for Ul even Though the Contributions are Levied on
(a) the extent to which the design of the UI program dif-   Films
fers from what workers would have chosen for themselves
as insurance against unemployment; and (b) to the extent                             Labor
that some differences exist, Ul contributions will be                               Supply
viewed as a tax, the incidence of which will depend on
the demand and supply elasticities of labor (see Gill, Dar,
and Thomas 1999).                                       w --------------
If the government-sponsored Ul program is exactly
WI  --- --- -- --- --- ---   .     Labor
what every worker would have chosen by themselves, w'
then the cost will be borne entirely by the worker (who                                           e
will willingly accept a wage net of all UI contributions).
If-as is likely-the government program is different                           Employment
from the insurance against unemployment the worker
would buy privately, the tax burden will in general be   done if the contributions had been raised directly from
shared by the worker and the employer. The higher the   their paychecks.
elasticity of demand for labor, other things being the    Figure 6.2 shows the outcome of an employer contri-
same, the larger the share of the tax borne by the worker.   bution if the supply of labor is more sensitive to the
The higher the elasticity of supply of labor (or the ease of   FIGURE 6.2
becoming informal), the higher the share of the tax borne    Workers and Finns Share Ul Costs even Though Contribtdions
by the employer. Who actually pays (that is, bears the    are Levied on Finns
incidence) therefore depends not on whom the tax is
wage
levied but the design of the scheme and the relative mar-
ket power of the worker vis-a-vis the employer.                     \
Figures 6.1 and 6.2 illustrate this point. Figure 6.1                              Sup
shows the effect of imposing a UI contribution on
employers in a labor market in which the supply of labor  wo ..... ......
is highly inelastic. This has the effect of reducing the  w2      -----
labor demand of firms at any given wage (the demand                                                Labor
curve shifts down by the amount of the employer contri-
bution). In the new equilibrium, after the imposition of
the Ur contribution, workers receive a wage which is
Ernployment
lower by the amount of the contribution w1 (as opposed
to the previous equilibrium of w ); employers end up    wage. Now the incidence is shared. Rather than falling
paying the same gross wage as they did before. In other   all the way from w0 to wI, the supply response pulls the
words, the fact that the contribution is nominally raised    wage back up to w2. Workers still "pay" for a part (w.-
on employers makes no difference to the outcome, which    w2) of their UI contributions by receiving lower wages,
is that workers end up paying, just as they would have    while employers pay the difference (w2-w).
ers and workers is not something the government should   of central importance to government. In this regard, the
try to influence, but the design of the program should be    key question is how well the program's design "mimics the
105



SECtURING OLUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 6.7
Income Support Programs for the Unemployed: Summary of Findings and Policy ImplicaUons
NATURE OF
MEASURE                        INSTRUMENT                  ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES                    POLICY IMPLICATION
Individual savings    Self-insurance-no pooling of risk    Low labor market efficiency costs, but welfare   Should be considered by countr-ies that
accounts                                               reduction especially for poorer workers.   have high unemployment, especially
where labor reforms are only a distant
possibility.
Severance pay          Pooling over small group-       Almost no advantage. Little pooling of risk,  Possibly the worst form of unernploy-
globalization makes group even  entails labor market inefficiency, makes labor    ment support in a globalized economy.
smaller                          relations contentious, and is administratively
challenging.
Public works and       Market-type insurance           Can reach informal sector workers and the  Should be considered for a part of work
training programs      elements -implicit pooling of   poor, bue can entail high leakages in the form    force, but not a oiniversal scheme. Perma-
risk                            of nonlabor costs when investment element is   nent schemes allow for better balance
made a priority. Training programs show less    between consumption smoothing and
leakage but also lower coverage potential,  investment over the economic cycle.
Unemployment          Market-type insurance-explicit   Most pooling of risk, can be used both to  Should be considered by governments
insurance             pooling of risks                 address idiosyncratic and aggregate risk, and    that have carried out compreherisive eco-
hence, serve as a "automatic fiscal stabilizer."    nomic reforms; labor market disincentivc
Generally politically popular. May be admin-    effects can be reduced by keeping benefits
istratively demanding.                    frugal and "mimicking the marker" as
much as possible in design.
market." One of the principal features of private insurance          stands out as a rare government program  that is strongly
markets is that the price reflects the degree of risk, even if    countercyclical in nature.
imperfectly. This is a noteworthy feature of the U.S. sys-              There are several ways to move from the current systems
tem, perhaps the only one that tries to match unemploy-              of mandated severance pay to such unemployment systems.
ment tax rates to risk through employer "experience-rat-             Coloma (1996) proposes an unemployment insurance sys-
ing," where rates of tax vary according to the frequency             tem  for Chile-which has severance pay provisions but is
with which an employer's former workers have filed for    considering the introduction of a new  system-that uses
unemployment benefits.17  Mimicking  the  market, and                severance pay benefits as a "deductible." Under this pro-
more particularly, the insurance that workers would choose           posal, the unemployed would first have to draw down the
to buy, is also essential to the long-run goal of covering the       accumulated severance benefits, and only then have access
informal sector. If wages fall to reflect the cost of insurance      to unemployment insurance payments. The effort to make
that workers do not want, then they have the incentive to    the hybrid system  resemble the structure of private insur-
avoid the implicit "tax" and become informal (see Maloney            ance schemes-where the insured are not paid the full loss
1998).                                                               but the loss minus a deductible-makes the proposal an
The U.S. unemployment insurance program  may be a                 improvement over a system  of mandated severance pay.
good model for LAC countries that arc considering such               Following the line of reasoning developed in Chapter 3,
systems: there are minimal mandated severance pay rules              countries that have low  unemployment risks because of
under the general labor laws, the system  mimics the mar-            comprehensive economic reforms and strong information
ket as much as countrywide public systems can, benefit    systems, (for example, strong administrative data and reg-
level and duration are modest, the rules are relatively uni-         ular households surveys), have the "insurance fundlamen-
form  throughout the country even though states collect    tals" that make for moves toward unemployment sapport
taxes and pay benefits, and the design of the program  in            systems that pool risk to be welfare-increasing for its citi-
general makes it an automatic fiscal stabilizer. While this          zens, even when some efficiency losses are involved. For
role may not be large in quantitative terms, the program             countries such as Brazil, that already have minimalistic
1 06



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
unemployment insurance systems but may or may not have   framework presented earlier in the report, do provide for
these preconditions, Box 6.6 provides some tentative    some broad but potentially useful guidelines.
guidelines.                                                Table 6.7 presents these findings, which draw from both
theoretical considerations and the regional experience. They
Conclusion                                              should be viewed as a starting point for closer policy analy-
This chapter summarized the experience in five countries   sis from a country-specific perspective. With this objective,
with five types of income support programs for the unem-   the table casts each available policy instrument in the gen-
ployed, and then drew some policy lessons. While it is dif-   eral framework of Chapter 3 and notes their respective
ficult to determine an unambiguous ranking of these pro-   advantages and disadvantages. Based on this, the rightmost
grams independent of country-specific circumstances, these   column of the table outlines the conditions under which
experiences, combined with the comprehensive insurance   each instrument may represent an appropriate policy choice.
BOX 6.6
Some Guidelines for Countdes that Have Unemployment Systems
International experience appears to suggest the following    made on grounds of administrative ease for both govern-
lessons for LAG economies that currently have unem-   ment and employers. Ideally, the base should be the same !
ployment insurance (Ul) systems, but which cover only a   or similar to that used for other taxes collected. Thus, if
small fraction of the workforce.                      the system is administered by states, the tax base should
It does not appear necessary to extend the UI tax to   be the same as that used for other state taxes. If the sys-
iworkers. Having a levy only on employers is in line with   rem is federally administered, there may be grounds to
international experience in the OECD and middle-income    make the tax base the same as that used for the main fed-
countries. Besides, economic theory suggests that the final   eral tax on employers, usually the social security tax.
burden of UI taxes has less to do with who bears the ini-  Experience-rating of employers can be a reasonable
tial impact and more with the design of the scheme and    medium-term goal. While experience-rating has many
the elasticities of demand and supply of labor.       attractive features, it is administratively demanding.
Keep the role of government in Ulfinance minimal.   Before making any decisions in this regard, countries in
Governments should pay only for the costs of adminis-   the region would be well advised to seek technical assis-
tration of the UI system. This is in line with interna-   tance from experts in the U.S., especially UI administra-
tional experience, and in keeping with the principle of   tors from states that have relatively recently and success-
employers and employees together insuring workers   fully instituted experience-rating.
against drastic income loss during unemployment.         Government financing of unemployment assistance
Frugality of benefits should be maintained. Because   could he considered. Most countries in the region have a
of the high degree of informality, it is difficult for the UI   high degree of informal employment, often synonymous
agency to determine if claimants are in fact unemployed.   with noncompliance with social security laws. The region
Keeping a waiting time of about 30 days before benefits   confronts the challenge of extending income support to
commence and the benefit levels low-as Brazil has suc-   those in the informal sector as economies are opened up to
ceeded in doing so far-circumvents this problem some-   the rigors of international competition. One option could
what and also reduces work-related disincentives associ-   be for the government to finance a system of unemploy-
ated with all UI systems. Financing a more generous UI   ment assistance with low, uniform benefits to those who
system will also be difficult because it will be impossible   are currently unemployed and who satisfy a means test, do
to make a large number of employers and employees pay    *ot qualify for unemployment insurance because their
their contributions,                                  employers have not paid UI taxes, but who can prove that
Decisions on the tax base sbould be made on admin-   they have contributed their social security dues for the
istrative grounds. The decision on the tax base should be   same length of time as required for UI eligibility.
107



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
However, a major conclusion of this chapter is that in    1999a and 1999b; Wodon and Minowa, 1999), the literature is
designing an effective strategy to help workers deal with        much more scant.
the risk of unemployment, administrative capacity should            4. The chapter also draws from a series of independently pro-
duced studies dealing with one income support program  in
be an imoratutntverdigocenfgoe Argentina (Ravallion 1999a, 1999b, and 1999c; Jalan and Ravallion
ment. Most countries in the region are capable of building       1999; Jones and Ravallion 1999).
this capacity. The more important questions are whether             5. Sections 2 and 3 of this chapter are based on Rama and Mal-
there are government actions that can rapidly lower the          oney (2000).
risk of unemployment, and what are the type of unem-                6. In 1999 the monthly minimum salary was less than $100.
ployment support programs that are in demand but the                7. It follows that the public works program is not merely dis-
supply of which is constrained. These questions can be    placing other, roughly equivalent ways of generating income. Raval-
posed as follows:     lion does assume, however, that jobs displaced are lost and not taken
posed as follows:                                                by other unemployed. Relaxing this assumption would lead to
* What are the measures that would augment the self-    higher estimates of benefits to the target population.
protection efforts of workers-that is, reforms that           8. Countries such as Argentina have rates as high as 15 percent,
lower the risks of unemployment? Labor policy mea-    while those in Chile are less than half these rates.
sures are a leading candidate, though their impor-            9. Programs with large transfer elements can be treated in an
insurance setting as market-type insurance with a negative loading
tancet and nature hostpravetobe deid red by eachgontr    factor, that is, those for which the price of insurance is better than
*What are the most practical measures to auglment           acurlyfi.
actuarially fair.
market-type insurance involving pooling of unemploy-          10. Montenegro and Gill (2000) and others find that in the 1980s
ment risks? These measures invariably imply effi-    a large share of the participants of Chile's Minimum Employment
ciency costs but suit countries better and better as they  Program were formerly our of the labor force.
successfully  implement self-protection-augmenting            11. Given the low wage rate offered, the direct benefits from the
policies that lower the risk of unemployment.              program are still likely to have favored the poor, even after the cuts.
�  What are the most practical measures to augment    Thus, the design features of the program undoubtedly helped protect
*  What are the most ptactical measures to augment    the poor from cuts.
se/f insurance efforts of workers? These mneasures gen-       12. This diversion may be justified by appeals to the dignity of
erally minimize labor market distortions and best    work, or avoiding the adverse social consequences of mass unem-
suit countries where self-protection  augmenting           ploymenr, although such considerations tend to receive less discus-
efforts are underway, but may require that special    sion when programs affecting middle-class workers are discussed.
attention be paid to poorer workers.                       From the political economy perspective, governments may also be
more willing to finance investment projects than simply transfers, or
While the relative weight on each of the three measures
even workfare projects that have low materials costs and are essen-
will differ across the economies in the region, a sound pol-    rially recurrent in nature (maintenance, cleaning, repairing). In this
icy mix involves pursuing all three objectives so that work-    case, benefits to the unemployed may be higher when packaged in an
ers obtain not a full guarantee against all shocks, but com-    investment project than simply as a transfer.
prehensive  insurance  that allows them  to  seize  the             13. Another important finding in Snyder and Yackovlev (2000) is
opportunities presented by globalization, and to see that    that there is a difference between programs that are targeted at the
risk is a fact of life in a world that grows smaller every year.    poor and those-such as unemployment insurance-that are nor;
that is, spending on programs that are targeted at the poor is much
more sensitive to party control in Congress than spending on non-
Notes                                                            targeted programs.
1. Argentina, Barbados, Brazil, Ecuador, Uruguay, and Venezuela  14. Gill, Dar, and Thomas (1999) summarize the features rhat
have unemployment insurance programs, though some of these are   lead to this strong countercyclicality as (a) stringent legal restrictions
quite limited in scope.                                          that unemployment tax proceeds can be used only for paying unem-
2. Chile is currently debating the merits and demerits of intro-    ploymenr benefits, (b) established rules by which the federal govern-
ducing individual saving accounts for dealing with the risk of unem-    ment provides loans to states whose UI trust funds are drying up,
ployment.                                                        and (c) rules that the federal government uses its own UI trust fund
3. Only for public works programs was there a substantial litera-    to extend unemployment benefits during long recessions-the max-
ture available (Ravallion, 1990; Ravallion, Datt and Chaudhuri,   imum duration can be doubled to 26 weeks.
1993; Dart and Ravallion, 1994). For other income support pro-      15. While in some countries the government may directly con-
grams, and with a few exceptions (Cunningham, 1997; Kugler,   tribute into the UI fund (for example, Israel, Japan, and Malta),
108



HELPING WORKERS DEAL WITH THE RISK OF UNEMPLOYMENT
more often this may involve the government's financing of means-    ance is time of contribution, while eligibility for assistance is based
tested unemployment assistance programs (for example, Austria,    on a means test that qualifies the recipient as needy.
Finland, France, and the U.K.), social insurance programs (for       17. Note again that, given the design of the program, who actu-
example, Germany and Portugal), or even active labor market or    ally pays the contribution does not depend on whom the tax is
social assistance programs (for example, Latvia and the Slovak    levied. In essence, the U.S. system transfers the problem of deter-
Republic).                                                        mining unemployment risk onto the employer. Thus employees who
16. The main difference between unemployment insurance and    have filed for UI benefits more frequently are likely to be less attrac-
unemployment assistance is that the eligibility condition for insur-    tive to future employers.
109






CHAPTER 7
Helping Poor Households Deal
Better with Economic Crises
G            IVEN THE FINDINGS IN CHAPTER 5 ON HOW HOUSEHOLDS RESPOND TO ECONOMIC CRISES,
designing minimalistic and.effective interventions to help households-especially poor fam-
ilies-deal better with crises is not easy. While more investigation is needed to confirm the
findings of panel studies in Argentina, Brazil, El Salvador, and Mexico, what we found appears
to suggest three fundamental points.
� First, the poor, like the rest of the population, are reluctant to take actions that are not in their own long-
term interest-such as withdrawing children from school during short or moderate downturns. But they
have to draw down their assets like everyone else and-since reserve labor is a primary asset of such house-
holds-greater labor force participation of secondary workers (mainly women) in the household is
observed. Since this takes time away from household production, these changes are likely to affect the
quality of education and health.
* Second, steeper or longer downturns do have negative effects even on education enrollment and basic
healthcare decisions. For example, children may be withdrawn from school or attendance reduced, and
the incidence of child labor increases. That is, both quantity and quality of schooling and healthcare are
reduced: as shocks become more serious, "good coping" appears to give way to "bad coping" as assets are
exhausted.
* Third, the poor do gain from economic growth episodes-in fact, good times appear to be more benefi-
cial for the poor than the non-poor.
These findings should influence policy choices of any gov-  While the first two findings involve government actions
ernment concerned with sustainable poverty reduction. Gov-   that are treated in Chapter 4 (macroeconomic, financial sec-
ernments should not be reluctant to carry out growth-   tor, and capital markets policies) and Chapter 6 (labor pol-
enhancing liberalization and reform  that may mean   icy), the third-spending on social services-is the focus of
somewhat greater volatility during the transition, because   this chapter. Protecting the quality of selected social ser-
while short downturns may not hurt the poor much,   vices that the poor need during economic crises is a difficult
increased growth helps the poor a lot. Further, the findings   task for even a determined government. This generally
suggest that macroeconomic policies should be oriented not   involves maintaining the level of spending per poor person
to avoid downtums at all costs, but to prevent them from    during economic downturns, which is doubly challenging
becoming long or deep. In addition, the quality of social pro-   because the fiscal envelope shrinks at the same time that the
grams used by the poor should be smoothed over the cycle-   number of poor increases. This is where the appeal of pro-
protecting the quantity and quality of public education and   grams that are well targeted to the poor is highest: even if
health services used by the poor is critical in both long and   governments cannot maintain social spending per poor per-
short downturns.                                      son at their normal levels, the adverse effects of the down-
111



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
turn may be reduced if a subset of this spending that is used  Briefly, what we find for governments contrasts with our
mainly by the poor is maintained or even increased.       findings in Chapter 5 on how households respond to eco-
This chapter examines whether governments in Latin    nomic risk. While poor households in LAC tend not to rely
America have maintained social spending over the economic   on "bad coping" over the economic cycle, for example, by
cycle, distinguishing as much as possible between "general"   sharply cutting investments in the education of their chil-
social spending and its more targeted components. Two    dren during downturns, governments in the region do
studies of cyclical fluctuations in government spending in    behave in ways that are shortsighted by sharply increasing
Latin American countries commissioned for this report form    spending when times are good, and decreasing critical
the core of this section, but the section also uses more   investments such as in education and health when times
detailed examinations of public education in Chile, and    are bad. This report provides some conjectures as why this
health insurance in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Colombia.    may be so, and suggests policies that can help make gov-
We briefly study the characteristics of five poverty-targeted    ernment behavior conform  to the principles of effective
programs in Brazil, Honduras, Mexico, and Nicaragua that   insurance.
aim to reduce current and future poverty by giving cash      Before we discuss how governments in the region have
transfers conditioned on health and education decisions by    tried to help the poor deal with economic shocks, it is use-
recipient households. Given the concerns that the poor may    ful to briefly discuss what sound insurance principles
reduce education and health investments when their income    would require of governments. Figure 7.1 presents an ideal
falls, these are considered prime candidates for the type of   scenario where the targeted social spending per poor per-
programs that should be protected or even expanded during    son increases steadily or acyclically at the long-term rate of
economic downturns. However, their suitability as an effec-   growth of per capita income (which is subject to cyclical
tive instrument for countering cyclical fluctuations in   fluctuations). This implies, however, that the share of tar-
income and human capital investments is not self-evident   geted spending to total government spending or GDP
from either their design or their track record. We evaluate    must be strongly anticyclical. Maintaining a noncyclical
whether they can in fact serve this function well, and pro-    pattern of targeted social spending is a tall order for even
pose some policy lessons based on our findings in the light   the most pro-poor and determined government, but it may
of evidence on how households respond, bringing in politi-   be a good measure against which governments can judge
cal economy considerations.                               their own performance. This chapter will show that gov-
FIGURE 7 1
Targeted Social Spending Over the Economic Cycle
Per Capita Income
(Economic Cycle)
-      -       ~~~~~~Targeted Spend ing per
Poor Person (A(yclical)
Share of Targeted
Spending in Total
Government Spending
, ...-- ...   --......                                                            (Anticyclical)
1 1 2



HELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
TABLE 7.1
Targeted Public Spending per Poor Person in Argentina and Mexico, 1994-96
ARGENTINA                                                 MEXICO
SHARE OF                                                SHARE OF
REAL   TARGETED                    TARGETED             REAL  TARGETED                     TARGETED
PER    SOCIAL             NUMBER  SPENDING              PER    SOCIAL             NUMBER  SPENDING
CAPITA  SPENDING  POVERTY  OF POOR  PER POOR            CAPITA  SPENDING  POVERTY  OF POOR  PER POOR
GDP    IN GDP    RATE    PEOPLE   PERSON                GDP    IN GDP    RATE    PEOPLE   PERSON
(1994 = 100)  (%)    (%)    (MILLION) (1994=11)0)       (1994 = 101))  (%1   (N)   (MILLION) (1994=100)
Level                                                     Level
1994        100     1.24      21.6      7.5      100      1994      100      1.36     46.95    42.04      100
1995       94.68     1.21     27.2      9.6      63.12    1996      95.07    1.23     60.93    56.51     67.30
Change                                                    Change
1994-95    -5.32%                               -27.88%    1994-96  -4.93%                              -23.70%
Soarce: Hicks and Wodon (2001)).
ernments in the region have found it hard both to keep tar-    more closely how social spending by government varies
geted spending per poor person from falling during bad    over the economic cycle. Of special concern is how public
economic times, and to keep it from rising "too fast" dur-   spending that is targeted to the poor is affected by expan-
ing good times.                                          sions and recessions (see Box 7.1). Another commissioned
paper, by Snyder and Yackovlev (2000), examines these fac-
Social Spending Over Economic Cycles                      tors for the U S. and for Latin American countries within a
For social spending that is targeted toward the poor to    political economy framework.
reduce the losses incurred by them because of an economic
downturn (that is, for it to act as a complement to self-   How Do Governments Vary Spending Over the
insurance and a substitute for missing market insurance),   Economic Cycle?
governments should design social spending to be counter-   In this section, we first summarize the findings for seven
cyclical. In fact, we generally observe the opposite in Latin    LAC countries regarding how the elasticity to growth of
America. Table 7.1 summarizes the findings for both   targeted spending for the poor behaves during booms and
Argentina and Mexico during the 1994-96 recession in    busts. The countries are Argentina, Chile, Costa Rica, the
these two countries. As one might expect, the natural effect   Dominican Republic, Honduras, Mexico, and Panama.
of the recession is to lower GDP per capita and to increase    They were chosen because data available were more reliable
the headcount poverty ratio, as was observed in both cases.   for them than for other LAC economies. The data cover the
To increase social spending per poor person, the govern-    1980s and 1990s, generally between 1981 and 1997-98.
ment should have therefore considerably increased its share  The data are not refined enough to test whether govern-
of GDP in targeted spending. Instead, that share fell in    ments are "pro-poor" in the sense required by Wodon and
both countries. The result was that targeted spending per   others (2000) (see Box 7.2). Assuming that social spending
poor person declined by about 28 percent in Argentina and    (for example, on education and health) is more pro-poor
24 percent in Mexico (Hicks and Wodon 1999) during the    than nonsocial spending, testing whether governments
economic crisis.                                          have been pro-poor can then be done using social spending
We also recognize that the pattern observed by Hicks    as a proxy for targeted spending. The share of social spend-
and Wodon (1999) is almost certainly not the result of   ing in total spending is found to increase during booms,
ignorance on the part of governments. There are obviously   and is not reduced during busts (see Table 7.2). This sug-
some factors-both economic and political constraints-    gests that these governments are "prosocial," that is, they
that prevent them from following policies that are so obvi-   make special efforts to protect social expenditures.
ously in the interests of their citizens. In a paper commis-  This should help to protect the poor during a crisis, but
sioned for this report, Wodon and others (2000) analyze   it is not enough. Despite efforts by government to main-
113



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
How Do PoPoor ommonts Viry Spendig Over the EcooMic C
According to Wodon aad others (2000) gvermments are      T assess how gowth affects how much targeted pub-
"pro-poor" if the groh elsicity of targeted public   lic spentding reaches each poor person, this can be trans- I
spending is at leas I during booms, and smler thao 1   formed to yield:
during recessions. This asymmetry between booms and              ,Sp               SP
busts is tested empiricatly using pael data on pubic       DLog(-.--)       Do -);         
expenditumres for seven Latin American countries. The              DP            GDP         GD P 
,    , DLog(-) DLqg(
tesults suggest r  governments are  opoor or at least             N                N            N
tend to vary social spending over the cycle to conform to  That is, the growth elasticity of targeted spending per
this rule. But this is not enough to protect the poor dur-   poor person is I pus the growth elasticity of the share of
ing a recession. The reason is that during a downturn, the   targeted spending in per capita GDP, ninus the growth
economy (aid government spending) contracts at the    elasticity of poverty.
same time that the number of poor increases.             To increase targeted spending per poor person dutiWng a
To more formally understand why, denote the tota    cisis, the lefthand side of the equation should be negative.
targetd spendig for the poor by the government by SP,   Wodon and others (2000) estimae the elasticity of poverty
the headcount index of poverty by H, and the size of the   reduction to growth to be rminus 1, that is, a 1 perent
total population by N, so that the tareted public spend-   increase in per capita GDP  reduces the number of poor by
inig per poor person is SPI(H*N). This can be expressed    1 percent. T maintain tagWed public spending per poor
as a function of thee parameters: ( the targeted bud-   person constant, theefr, the growth elasticity of the share
getary spning as a share of GMP denotd by SPIGP       of targeted sending in GDP must be less than -2. This is
(b) the level of GDP per capita, denotd by GDN  and    a difficut task for any government. For the seven Latin
(c) the inverse of the headcount index of poverty, denoted    American countries studied, dhe observed elasticity during
by 1/H:                                               recessions is not statistically different from zero, so that a
- :$P  am     1 XP   ]             1 percentage point negaive growth dAces targeted social
IH *     GP   N s                        spenig per poor peron by 2 percentage points.
tain targeted and social spending constant as a share of total   The Importance of Political Factors
spending during a crisis, a 1 percentage point decrease in    The procyclicality of social spending in Latin America is
GDP still reduces targeted public spending per poor person   also confirmed by Snyder and Yackovlev (2000) using data
by about 2 percentage points during a recession. Half of   over roughly the same period as that analyzed by Wodon
this impact (1 percentage point) is due to the reduction in   and others (2000), but for 19 countries in the LAC region.
GDP, which leads to reduced total spending even when the    While they do not distinguish between targeted and gen-
share of targeted spending in GDP remains constant. The   eral social spending, they examine the influence of political
other half is due to the increase in the number of poor peo-   factors as well as economic cycles. One of their main find-
pie due to the economic contraction.'                  ings is that while both authoritarian and democratic gov-
Another test of the pro-poor tendency of governments is   ernments behave similarly during recessions (cutting social
to see how they spend during times when budgets are not   spending per capita), the behavior during good times
as tight, for example, during economic expansions. For   appears to be more pro-poor under democracy (see Box 7.3
these seven countries, the elasticity of social spending to   and Table 7.3). They also find that the relatively nontar-
GDP growth is found to be larger than 2. Thus, in the   geted parts of social spending (for example, higher educa-
most general terms, governments expand spending on   tion) tend to be more procyclical than those that help the
social programs twice as fast as overall budgets during    poor more (primary and secondary education), which is
periods of economic growth.                             encouraging.
114



HELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
BOX 7.2
Data Sources and Classification into Targeted and Social Spending
Although Wodon and others (2000) carefully construct   side program targeted according to malnutrition rates and
the data using both the General Financial Statistics of the    providing cash stipends for nutrition and school enroll-
International Monetary Fund and country-level data pro-   ment-see following section), some general subsidies, and
vided by governments, social spending information is   expenditures for a number of smaller programs.
more reliable than data for targeted spending. Targeted
spending is not strictly comparable between countries   Mexico
because while some countries classify certain programs as   The data are for the federal government only but, since
targeted, others may classify similar programs as social,  the decentralization process in Mexico started only in
but not targeted. Social spending is more reliable because    1998, this is not of major concern. Social spending con-
it includes all targeted expenditures as well as spending    sists of spending for education, health and social security,
for education and health (plus a few small items).     labor, regional development, water, environment, and
social assistance. Targeted spending is the sunm of social
Argentina                                               assistance and spending for labor, which includes pro-
Annual GDP and budgetary data for 1980-97 are from    grams such as Empleo Temporal (public works in rural
the Ministry of the Economy. Apart from information on    areas) and Probecat (job training in urban areas), rnen-
total spending, the Ministry provides consistent series for   tioned earlier. Health spending includes social security
social spending (education, health, water and sanitation,   expenditures, so that health as a share of social expendi- j
social assistance, labor, housing, and other services for   tures is overstated.
urban areas excluding those expenditures allocated in the
social security budget). Within social spending, the data    Chile, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, and
identify targeted spending as consisting of spending for   Panama
housing and urban development, social assistance, and    The expenditure data for these four countries are from the
I labor. This includes Trabajar, the public works program    IMPFs Government Financial Statistics, combining the
discussed in Chapter 6. The data include spending at fed-   series for consolidated central government, state or provin-
eral, provincial, and municipal levels. Health excludes   cial govermnents, and local government where available.
health expenditures allocated in the social security budget.   When data on transfer payments from the central govern-
ment to other levels of govemment are available, these 1
Honduras                                                were added to the consolidated expenditures in education,
The data are from the Ministry of Finance and are not   health, and targeted spending. Targeted spending was cal-
available in published form. The expenditures are for the    culated by subtracting social security spending from
I central government (but the level of decentralization is low    "Social Security and Welfare" expenditures. This yields an
in Honduras). Targeted expenditures exclude the expendi-   approximate measure of spending that is targeted because
rtures for the social investment fund, but include all other   countries do, for example, grant noncontributory pensions
expenditures directed specifically at the poor. Programs    targeted at the poor. These countries were selected because
included in targeted expenditures are PRAP II (a demand-   of data quality considerations.
Overall, the results suggest that governments do make    spending per poor person falls despite their efforts. And
efforts to protect the poor-or at least to protect social   equally worrisome is that government behavior in expan-
expenditures during crises-and that they increase these   sions may be pro-poor but shortsighted-democratic gov-
expenditures faster than economic growth during periods    ernments expand too fast, perhaps responding to strong
of expansions. Unfortunately, the findings also indicate   political pressures to "make up" for their inadequacies
that their efforts during contractions are not enough-    during recessions. The finding in Chapter 5 that the poor
115



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
TABLE 7.2
Elasticities of Spending to Growth, by Type of Spending
ELASTICITY WITH RESPECT
TO GROWTH OF                   TARGETED SPENDING       NONTARGETED SPENDING    EDUCATION SPENDING            HEALTH SPENDING
Targeted spending/GDP
Overall                               0.75*                     0.31                     0.35                      0.24
In expansions                         1.06*                     0.55*                    0.43*                     0.55*
In contractions                       0.44                      0.07                     0.27                     -0.04
Total spending/GDP
In expansions                        -0.08                     -0.08                    -0.02                     -0.07
In contractions                       0.o4                      0.04                     0.23                      0.18
Social/total spending
In expansions                         0.69*                     0.69*                    0.74*                     0.75*
In contractions                       0.07                      0.07                     0.13                      0.08
Targeted/social spending
In expansions                         0.46                     -0.06                    -0.29                     -0.14
In contractions                       0.32                     -0.05                     -0.09                    -0.30*
* Denotes significant at 10 percent level of significance or better. Otherwise the coefficient should be interpreted as zero elasticity.
Note: These are elasticities of shares. A zero growth elasticity of the ratio of total spending to GDP implies that spending increases in proportion to GDP
Source: Wodon and others (2000).
register strong income gains during growth episodes also          The Quality of Social Services Over the Cycle
means that governments help them  most when they least    These findings suggest that the quality of social services
need the help.                                                    consumed by the poor should be even more procyclical
iB�)X 7.3
Social Spending Over Economic and Polital Cyles I Ltin  merca
Snyder and  Yakovlev (2000) Conduct cross-seti                         not statistically diferent  om  zero-that is, per
time-series (panel) regressions fbr 19 Latin AmericAn                  cata socia security spending is not prcyclical.
contries firom  1980-96, for eight sendi   variables                *  Breakig  down  education  speig  into  three
(totai social spending-consisting of social security edu-              bad    e riesmar   secondary, an  higher
cation, heath, and housin g-n  education  pending at                   education-Snyder and  Yakkovlev  (2000) find
primaryf secondary and tertiary levels). The independet                icome elasticities of about I for prtmary and sec-
variales are growth of GDP (curnxat and lagged), gov-                  ondary educaton, but a noticeably higher elasticity
ernment deficit (lagged), regime type, and governing                   of about L.  fbr higher education spending, which
party "ideolo " The maii results ale                                   is the least taqgeted of these categories.
*  The income elasticity of overall per capita social            *  Authoritarian and. democratic regimes appear to
spending with respect to GDP is cleay positive,                  respon   similarly to economic crises. Both cut
but less than 1.                                                 social spending per capita, and about equally. But
For the four broad categories, educatio%, health,                there is a large difference by regime type on spend-
housing, and  social security  they find that the                ing changes during expansions: geater increases in
income elasticity of spending on educatiom   and                spending take place under democratic true. Social
bealth is about 1; the elasticity is also 1 ft rhousin           spending increases only when theme Is both democ-
but it is imprcisey estimaed. Interestingl  ifr                  ratic rule and a nonshrinking economy.
i       soci security-which is probably ls tatgeted than                 Thee appears to be little effect of the executive
public education and health care-the elasticity is               bratnch's "ideology" or populist leanings.
116



HELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
TABLE 7.3
Changes in Latin American Social Protection Spending, 1970-95
(Broad Spending Categories)
DEPENDENT VARIABLE = PERCENT CHANGE IN PER CAPITA SPENDING
TOTAL SPENDING            4 BROAD CATEGORIES            4 BROAD CATEGORIES
%A in per capita GDP                              .73*                         -                             -
%A in per capita GDP x social security             -                           .24                          .25
%A in per capita GDP x education                   -                           .90***
%A in per capita GDP x health                      -                           .97***
%A in per capita GDP x housing                     -1 60*
%A in per capita GDP X not soc. sec.               -                           -1.07*
Lagged deficit                                    _.01*                       -._01*                        -l*
New democratic regime                             .05***                       .09**                        .08**
Old dcmocratic regime                             .04                          .06                          .o6
# of observations                                 226                         835                           835
*   Significant at the .10 level.
** = Significant at the .05 level.
*    Significant at the .01 level.
Nste: Country-specific, fixed effects included In all specifications.
Source: Snyder and Yackovlev (2000).
than social spending because government spending on    forces cuts in targeted programs intended to benefit disad-
social services such as education and healthcare is cut at the    vantaged students.
same time that private capacity to pay for them  declines.         While the issue of cyclical fluctuations in education
But there are mechanisms specific to education and health-    quality requires much more study, it appears that during a
care that may offset some of these effects. In education, for    downturn there is a negative effect on the quality of educa-
example, governments may  reallocate spending  from             tion for the middle and upper-middle classes, who generally
higher education toward primary and secondary education         send their children to private subsidized and unsubsidized
during downturns-the previous section discusses some    schools. For poor children things may be even worse: they
evidence that suggests this. In healthcare, the reforms in    use public schools which may be even more vulnerable to
countries that have strengthened health insurance for those    expenditure cuts, and they benefit from special public pro-
employed, as well as others, may provide some relief dur-    grams that are threatened as well. The only group whose
ing economic cycles.                                            education quality may be unaffected by cyclical fluctuations
There is no systematic evidence on this question of how      is the wealthy. Economic volatility may thus, through its
quality of social services varies with aggregate economic    effects on government spending, make it harder to narrow
shocks. Two studies commissioned for this report, Mizala    the educational gap between the rich and poor.
and Romaguera (2000) and Jack (2000), address this issue           This is especially unfortunate because education has
for public education and health, respectively, but the    been found to be related to the ability of workers and fam-
results should be regarded as preliminary. Mizala and    ilies to withstand aggregate shocks (see Chapter 5). Many
Romaguera (2000) approach the question by studying              countries in the region have chosen to not redistribute
changes in the quality of educational outcomes in Chile in    assets such as land, focusing instead on improving the dis-
the mid-1990s. They find that the quality of educational    tribution  of human  capital assets such as education
services, using two standardized school achievement test    through aggressive public education initiatives for the
scores as proxies, behaves procyclically.2 There are two pos-    poor. This is in all likelihood the most sensible policy, but
sible explanations. First, a downturn  reduces private    the rewards will be seen only after some time. Violent
incomes for the wealthier households, thus reducing the    cycles in public education spending and the quality of edu-
demand for places in fee-charging private schools that tra-    cation services push the rewards from public-education-as-
ditionally have displayed higher educational attainment.    redistribution policies even further into the future. Pro-
Second, decreased educational spending affects schools,    grams such  as Mexico's Progresa and  Brazil's Bolsa
teacher incentives, and other inputs generally, but also    Escola-if used as instruments to reduce this cyclicality in
117



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
education quality-have the attractive feature that they    -BO - 4---    .. ...... .                           l
can reduce the amplitude of these quality swings for poor    Iolnbias Healthcare Reform
families. The usefulness of these programs is evaluated in
some detail in the next section.                           Colombia's health sector reforms initiated in the early
In Latin America, the regulatory role of governments is  1990s represent one of the most ambitious policy inter-
becoming more complex, especially in two areas: the regula-  ventions undertaken in Latin America. Before the
tion of financial markets, and the regulation and public pro-  reforms, Colombia had a centralized, budget-financed,
vision of health services. A critical review of the recent expe-  and poorly organized public health delivery system,
riences with health insurance reform in Argentina, Brazil,  and many infrmal sector workers and their families
Chile, and Colombia can be found in Jack (2000). The study  were uninsured. The general goal of the Colombian
finds that the traditional approach of public health systems  reforms was to ensure a basic level of coverage for all
in LAC attempted to provide free universal coverage, moti-    individuals, that could be inproved upon for those
vated more by a concern for equity than for the efficiency of  willing and able to pay more.
the insurance arrangements available to households. This      Although no formal voucher scheme exists, the
was, in turn, caused by the highly unequal income distribu-  scheme is equivalent to a two-level voucher system.
tions prevalent throughout most of the region.             Effectively, rnembers of one group of families (those
During the 1980s and 1990s a number of governments      with workers in the formal sector) receive a voucher for
in the region, including the four studied by Jack (2000),  insurance that covers a wide range of services at high
sought to improve the efficiency of public health provision  quality, while all others (many of whom  are poor)
by relying on or mimicking private insurance mechanisms,   receive a voucher for a less generous packae of insur-
albeit to varying degrees. In some cases, like that of the  ance. Members in the first group are said to be in the
obras sociales in Argentina, this was achieved by reforming  "contributory regime," and those in the second are
the focus of existing institutions. In others, entirely new  referred to as participating in the "subsidized regime."
institutions were created, such as Chile's Instituciones de   The tax base consists of a payroll tax plus general
Salud Previsional (ISAPRE).                                revenes. Participants in the contributory regime are
Because health insurance and health care are almost     require  to pay a 12 percent payroll tax to help finance
always integrated, the task of reducing the exposure of indi-  health care. This tax is earmarked for health services
viduals to health risks is intimately connected to the organi-  provision. Participants in the subsidized regime also
zation of health care delivery and financing mechanisms.   contribute, but these contributions are means-tested.
Colombia's health insurance reform appears to have been       There has been a marked increase in formal coverage
explicitly market-augmenting: the reform aimed at ensuring  of the population, particularly among lower-income
that those who could pay for coverage-employees in formal   igroups. Overall, the proportion of individuals with
sector jobs-were guaranteed access to quality healthcare,   Iinsurane more than doubled during this period from
while those from whom contributions are harder to collect-  24 percent to 57 percent, with the largest proportion-
the unemployed, the self-employed and the poor-were        ate gains among the poor-the lowest quintile group's
guaranteed access to services as well, but of modest quality.  coverage rate rose firom about 5 percent to 45 percent.
The performance of such "dual-voucher" systems during    i                   .               . .
aggregate shocks should be studied in greater detail. How-
ever, with evidence that health system coverage for the poor  On the whole, health insurance functions in LAC are
increased from 5 percent to almost 50 percent because of the    still covered by a dichotomous system. On the one hand,
reform, the new system is almost certainly better for helping    most countries now have a private or quasi-private mar-
those affected adversely by aggregate fluctuations (see Box    ket for actual insurance policies, with explicit premiums,
7.4). This does not rule out cyclical fluctuations in quality as   coverage rules and deductibles, which gives access to
the relatively high quality unsubsidized subsystem contracts   varying degrees of reasonably high-quality services. On
and the subsidized subsystem expands during downturns,   the other, there remains almost everywhere a large public
and vice versa during upturns.                           or publicly subsidized provider of health services, such as
118



IHELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
Brazil's  Sistema  Unico  de  Saude  (SUS)  or Chile's    grams focused on the poor, some countries have tried to
FONASA, which is quantity-rationed and provides low-    make the programs more self-targeting, for example, by
quality care. Reform  of these health systems must con-    using low-wage work as the targeting device (as in public
tinue in most countries. Given the complexity of health              works programs in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile). While
insurance markets, governments throughout the region                 LAC followed countries such as India in these second-gen-
would be well advised to invest in a greater understand-             eration programs, the region has led the world in what can
ing of the main design and regulatory principles that    be considered the third generation of antipoverty programs
need to be set in place.                                             "targeted conditional transfers," which make means-tested
cash transfers, but make them conditional on "socially
Targeted Spending During Booms and Busts                             desirable  behavior"  of recipients. The  five  programs
Marny countries in the region have steadily moved from               reviewed in this chapter belong to this class of targeted
using general subsidies (especially for food and fuel) as the        programs that provide social assistance to poor families
major instrument of support to poorer households, to pro-    with children, on the condition that these families invest
grams aimed at providing income transfers to the poor.    in their education and health (Sedlacek, Ilahi, and Gustafs-
Facing administrative difficulties in keeping these pro-             son-Wright 2000).
TABLE 7.4
Main Characteristics of Targeted Conditional Transfers
PROGRESA                PRAF-I1                  RED               BOLSA ESCOLA               PETI
INDICATOR                   (MEXICO)             (HONDURAS)             (NICARAGUA)              (BRAZIL)               (BRAZIL)
Implementing Agency          Federal                National               National            Municipal/State           Federal
Objectives
Education enrollment          Yes                     Yes                    Yes                    Yes
increase
Health and nutrition           Yes                    Yes                    Yes                    Yes
improvement
Child labor reduction          Yes                    Yes                    Yes                    Yes
Poverty alleviation
Supply-side support            Yes                    Yes                    Yes                    No                    Yes
Current coverage        2.3 million families   Under preparation      Under preparation       200,000 families       131,000 children
(1997)                                                               (1995)                (1996)
Size of monthly         US$10 per person        US$5 per person       US$9.3 per person    US$32-$65 per family     US$12 per person
education grant
Geographical                National               National               National               Municipal              National
targeting level
Beneficiary selection  Income means-tested           None             Under preparation     Income means-tested    Income means-tested
criteria                                                                                         and score
Targeting outcome      Low leakage, but high                                                Low leakage, but high
undercoverage                                                        undercoverage
Outcomes
- Improvements in         Yes: enrollment                                                    Yes: lower dropout,      No evaluation
education                  increases                                                       promotion increases
- Better health and
nutrition                    Yes
- Child Labor                Mixed                                                                Mixed
Suitability for
expansion in crisis
- Intensive                   Yes                     Yes                    Yes                    Yes                   Yes
(more for old covered)
- Extensive                 Difficult              Difficult               Difficult             Difficult              Difficult
(new participants)
Sourre: Sedlacek, Ilahi, and Gusrafsson-Wrighr (2000).
119



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
BOX 7.5
Mexico's PVo  Program: Works WellO But Would It Do as Well in C,ises
Prors gives cash grants to poor famiies in rural areas    househols in non-Pgtsa localities (Schultz 2000). ihe
on the condition that their children attend school and    inreases in enrollments were largest in the grades in
visit heat centers regulady. The stated objective of the    whih earollments wer  lowest-between completing
program is to reduce current and fiure poverty; the lat-   elemeary school (grade 6) and starting junior second ary
ter by increasing investments in children's human cao-    school. These ects imply, fior example, that a 16-year- 
tal. This demand-side intervention is also accompanied    old copleted on average 1.1 more years of schooling
by sizable supply-side support in the form of increases in   than a poor child in a community without Pesa. The
teacher salaries and the supply of medicines. Prors      interal rate of etu   on Prgea grants is 9.2 percent.
began in 1997 and today covers 2.6 million rural fmi-    The program  also improved health indicators (Gertler
flies-about one-tenth of all families in Mexico-at a cost   2000). Clinic visits iPrgma localities were 18 percent 
of $800 mnilion, or 0.2 percent of GDP. Thee questions    higher than in non-Prowa areas, the number of prenant
are of primar conern fr this report, Does the program    women making their irst visit in the first trimester
i target well? Does the program improve child school and    increased by about 8 percent, and prenatal care visits
health outcomes? And can the program  be alered to   Increased by 5 percent. Participation lowers the probabil-
serve the purpose of a social safety net in a world with   ity of illns by 22 perent among children aged 0 to 2.
risk? Evaluations of the program being carried out by the
International food Policy Research Institute (IFPRJ) in    Suitabi  in Cnses
collaboration with Progesa can provide answers to these    While the targeting and outcomes are enicouraging, Pro-
questionsm.                                              gsa  desip  suggests that its ability to serve as an
instnment of social insurance might be limited. It is
rting                                                    usefil here to distinguish between the program's ability
Prgs was found to be the most efective of the tareted    to expand ntsiel and its ability to expand ext       y.
progams in Mexico-both in terms of selecting poor   It would do better in the former-that is, it might be rel-
localities and selecting poor househols within ther.    atively simple to increase the amount of benefit distrib-
Prgra is not effective, however, when it comnes to dis-    ued to households already in the program during perif
Iinguishing between localities in the middle of the scale.   ods of economic crises so as to continue providig the
As Pro   exands into less-poor communities, selection    incentive to beneficiary failies to keep their children in
error is higher. It also did nor do well in selecting mod-   school. However, any attempt to expand the program  i
etately poor households. Thus, as Prors expands into    extensively-that is, to include households that experi-
less marginal communities, leakages are likely to cor-   ence transitory income or employment shocks-would
pound at both the locality and the household  evel   require changing selection methods and criteria. In addi-
(Skoufias, Davis, and Behrman 1999).                     tiotn, a"n major exansion would also necessitate defining
exit rules-that is, how fimilies that "improve" after a
daon" and H th Outcomes                                  positive shock will be dopped fiom the rolls. Otherwise,
Systematic evaluations of Prga have revealed signifi-   the program wilU not be financially sustainable over the
cant impacts on education and health. tinrolment rtes of   long ran.
c children in househols in P ea localities are higher
t compared to the enrollment rates of childtren in similar   AdEeSa   gmmaunel 5fias, International Food Policy esearch Institute,I
cornpard to te elitlimentrates o childen in imliat and U4i.er of the Progrrs Evaluairin Project.
J.
Table 7.4 summarizes the principal features. Broadly    health, and nutrition (and hence a subsequent reduction in
speaking, these programs have three objectives: the allevi-   long-term  poverty); and the reduction of child labor
ation of poverty; improvements in educational attainment,   (explicit in some of the programs such as Brazil's Programa
120



HELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
de Erradicacio do Trabalho Infantil (PETI), and implicit in    nerability to risk in the long run-than in providing mar-
others such as Mexico's Progresa, Honduras' PRAF II, and    ket-type insurance during crises for all or many of those peo-
Brazil's Bolsa Escola. The programs are demand-side inter-   ple who fall into poverty. As the next section proposes,
ventions, with some supply-side support. The largest of   however, these programs may have the attributes that
these programs is Progresa, which covers more than 2 mil-   make transfer programs resilient to cuts over the economic
lion households (or about 10 percent of total households in   cycle. Political economy considerations may overturn their
Mexico).                                                 purely economic drawbacks.
Regarding their effects on poverty, human capital, and
child labor, rigorous evaluations are scarce, but the pro-   Designing Economic Policy Under Political
grams appear to work well. Progresa has been systematically    Constraints
studied, though, and appears to have improved education,   In examining the role of governments in assisting their
health, and nutrition (see Box 7.5). The programs have low    citizens in dealing with economic risks, we found three
leakage to the non-poor. However, there is also consider-   findings of note. First, social spending by LAC govern-
able undercoverage of the eligible poor both because the    ments is generally highly procyclical: even when the
programs are relatively new and expansion has been cau-   share of social spending in total budget outlays rises dur-
tious, and because of the inevitable fiscal constraints facing    ing bad times, total spending shrinks and headcount
some of the programs such as Bolsa Escola.               poverty increases, so that social spending per poor person
Because eligibility requires having school-age children,   is procyclical. Second, the spending-which includes
the programs will exclude some of the poor even if all eli-   most expenditure on social insurance and safety net pro-
gible families are covered. This makes it relevant to ask if   grams-is often poorly targeted. Third, the quality of
it is the behavioral condition that leads to the observed    social services-especially education-also behaves pro-
gains, or if this is the effect of the income transfer making    cyclically. These are not desirable characteristics of poli-
the household somewhat better off. In determining this,   cies for facilitating comprehensive insurance by individu-
however, both administrative and political economy con-   als and families.
siderations are important. First, the additional condition-  Insurance principles require that governments transfer
ality may somewhat paradoxically lead to lower adminis-   resources from good times to bad-"saving" during good
trative costs: the programs anchor the monitoring system    times, and "dissaving" during bad, or borrowing during
in established schools and clinics, and therefore circum-   bad times and repaying loans during expansions. It is clear
vent the need for completely new administrative arrange-   that this is not what has happened over the last two
ments. Second, this conditionality may be key to their   decades in Latin America. Whether governments are pre-
political popularity, and may make them resilient to cuts   vented from doing so by political and economic factors is
even when budgets are being cut.                         important to understand. What is clear is that govern-
For the purposes of this report, however, the critical   ments seem to treat changes over the economic cycle as
question is how well the programs can serve as a safety net   permanent-being shortsighted when times are good, and
over the economic cycle. They come up somewhat short in   engaging in "bad coping" when times are bad by cutting
this regard. The programs do not cover families that are   down on critical investments such as education and
non-poor in good times, but who fall into poverty during    health. That is, governments respond to economic shocks uncan-
a recession. Thus, while the amount of the cash transfer to    nily like the stereotyped responses that poor households allegedly
those already covered can be increased quickly when    display. Ironically, in Chapter 5 we found that the poor
incomes fall (thus being responsive on what can be called    actually do not behave as stereotyped-in bad times that
the "intensive margin of poverty"), the programs cannot   appear to be temporary, (that is, short or mild recessions),
by their design cater to the transient poor (and hence are   the poor draw upon assets such as reserve labor, and do not
unsuited on the 'extensive margin of poverty").          sharply cut investments in health and education.
In the terminology of Chapter 3, these targeted condi-   The factors that make governments poor practitioners
tional transfer programs may therefore be more effective    of the most basic insurance rules are worthy of closer
in augmenting self-protection-decreasing household vul-   study. In proposing policies, this section makes some sum-
121



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
mary observations on this subject. There are four major   decrease in per capita GDP. There are two reasons for the
policy implications that follow from the analysis of how    failure of targeted public spending to protect the poor.
households respond to economic volatility (in Chapter 5)   First, when GDP falls, even if targeted spending remains
and what governments in the region have done to help.    constant as a share of GDP, there will be less money avail-
able to distribute to the poor through targeted programs.
The Long-Term Goal of Social Policy Must be to           Second, when GDP falls, poverty increases, which means
Improve the Distribution of Assets                       that targeted spending for the poor must be distributed to
First, since assets are crucial to enable households to self-   a larger number of poor people. These two factors com-
protect and self-insure against shocks, a better distribu-    bined make targeted spending for the poor highly pro-
tion of assets should reduce ex post variations and thus    cyclical, which leads to a lack of protection during hard
improve welfare. Our findings provide additional support   times. The same is true for social spending. Our results
to the already traditional emphasis on more and better   suggest that additional efforts should be made to create
education: in addition to the impact it has on income lev-   effective countercyclical programs and safety nets to pro-
els, education appears to reduce the vulnerability to   tect the poor during crises.
shocks and enable both rural and urban workers to cope      With governments cutting targeted spending per poor
better with them.                                        person during economic crises, the finding that during
expansions targeted spending per poor person increases by
Targeted Programs Should be Permanent and Better         more than 2 percentage points for every percentage point
Protected During Crises                                 increase in per capita GDP may seem like good news.
Second, the temporal profile of social spending-especially    However, for several reasons, this finding is not as encour-
on targeted programs-needs considerable realignment.   aging as it seems. There is evidence that the income of the
Targeted social spending accounts for small shares of GDP,   poor grows rapidly-generally even faster than that of the
but the programs it makes possible can make such a large    nonpoor-during growth episodes so that, as a rule, they
difference to poor people affected by a negative shock that   need government transfers the least in these times. In addi-
governments should make an effort to protect them from    tion, rapid increases during good times make the subse-
the great budgetary pressures which arise during reces-   quent cuts in spending during bad times seem  much
sions, and to design them as much as possible to be auto-   worse, and may be politically destabilizing. Moderation in
matically countercyclical. Unemployment insurance pro-   spending during good times lowers the risk of large reduc-
grams, public works guarantees, and poverty-targeted    tions in spending during crises-especially if accompanied
human development programs can all be designed to have    by transferring resources from good times to bad.
this property. Other budget items that deserve attention
during recessions are those which relate to the quality of   International Financial Institutions Can Help
selected social services, such as the salaries of teachers and    Overcome Political Constraints to Insurance
primary healthcare workers, and the maintenance budgets   Fourth, for democratic governments, the pressures to spend
of the facilities with which they work.                  during economic recovery can be ignored only by risking
loss of political power. Because economic and political
Keeping Increases in Social Spending Moderate in Good    cycles seldom coincide, it is equally difficult to ensure that
Times is Important Too                                  the savings during good times are spent only for the right
Third, while the evidence is not definitive, there is enough    things (social services and targeted programs) at the right
to suggest that it may be as important not to increase social   time (during economic crises)-the record of such self-
spending during good times as rapidly as countries have, as   insurance efforts by governments, such as fiscal stabiliza-
it is to protect it during bad times. The empirical evidence   tion funds, is patchy at best.
for LAC summarized in this chapter indicates that despite  Under these political constraints, governments that
efforts to restrict cuts in social spending, targeted and gen-   have taken appropriate self-protection measures through
eral social spending per poor person are reduced during    comprehensive reforms should adopt strategies that
recessions by 2 percentage points for each percentage point   involve a good measure of market insurance. Recall from
122



HELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
Chapter 3 that at the margin, rarer losses are better insured  ties. The presence of these provides an efficiency-
through market insurance than self-insurance, and Chapter      based reason for government subsidy or direct pro-
4 applied these principles at the level of the country. In the  vision. An additional equity-related rationale may
absence of a well-developed market for insuring against        arise if these activities, in addition to contributing to
aggregate risk, the strategy that suggests itself is for gov-  self-protection, also increase lifetime earnings. Edu-
ernments to borrow during bad times to prop up social          cation and health care qualify under this heading
spending and repay during good times. The problem, of          and, in practice, most "social spending" finances
course, is that the private market for countercyclical         these services.
finance is also thin or nonexistent. Governments that have  * Second, the provision of market-type insurance for risks
carried out comprehensive economic reforms deserve access      where markets may be missing or underdeveloped,
to countercyclical finance from multilateral financial insti-  and some scope for risk-pooling exists. Unemploy-
tutions. For governments that have yet to carry out the        ment insurance and public works guarantees are typ-
required economic reforms-and face a high likelihood of        ical examples. Public health services, either in the
crises-the  appropriate mechanisms for transferring            form of direct provision or of cash subsidies to users
resources would be of a more self-insurance nature. Recall     or suppliers of private services, are another important
from Chapters 3 and 4 that more frequent risks may be          category of social insurance against idiosyncratic risks
better insured against through self-insurance than through     which may be unrelated to aggregate income risks.
market-type insurance. Setting up programs that build up    * Third, regulation of private insurers helps to extend
reserves during good times which are strictly earmarked to     insurance to many who would be excluded without
he spent only for these purposes during bad times may be       such rules. Additionally, other forms of regulation-
the main viable option for such governments until they         notably prudential regulation of financial intermedi-
carry out comprehensive economic reforms.                      aries-may reduce aggregate risk in an economy and
provide safer instruments of self-insurance to individ-
Conclusion                                                     uals. Financial and capital market sector strengthen-
The foregoing policy recommendations aim either to bet-        ing may be the most seriously underemphasized
ter enable households to self-insure and self-protect, or to   instrument of social policy.
improve the government's role in assisting them. When all   In practice, almost every example of governmental
is said and done, however, these are necessary steps largely   action that successfully fulfills one of these three roles will
because insurance markets are either missing or seriously   also to some extent fulfill one or both of the others. In addi-
imperfect. Ultimately, risk is best dealt with through a    tion, many social insurance policies will also perform social
combination of market insurance, self-insurance, and self-   assistance (that is, redistribution from  richer to poorer
protection. Policymakers should recognize this, and note   households).
especially that the market for insurance with pooling of    Many countries in the region have improved the poverty
risk is highly prone to failure. The best solution will usu-   impact of social spending through reform  over the last
ally be to correct and complement the market, rather than    decade, for example, by replacing generalized subsidies with
to replace it. Intelligent regulation is essential for this, be    programs specifically designed to help the poor. Evidence on
it in labor markets, financial markets, or health services.  government spending over the cycle for several countries is
Following the comprehensive framework outlined in   consistent with the view that LAC governments are sincere
Chapter 3 for understanding household behavior in the face   about protecting social spending during downturns: spend-
of risk, the absence of insurance markets would generally   ing on education, health, housing, and social security gener-
make households worse off. Governments may be able to   ally does not fall by as much as GDP. However, social spend-
improve matters through public action (see Gill and Ilahi   ing per poor person does fall-roughly equally because of the
2000). This can be of three types:                       reduced overall budget and the increased number of poor
* First, the provision of or subsidy to activities used by    people during economic contractions.
households to generate self-protection, but the produc-  Social spending-while being generally pro-poor-
tion of which is characterized by positive externali-   directly benefits the nonpoor as well. Spending on more
123



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
~~~---X~ 7.-6~ ~ ^ ~ ~ ~ ^-~~ ^~~ ~~ ~~~~~-~  ~ ~--~t    tightly targeted programs for the poor does appear to suf-
ocidal Prorams, Entitlements, and C:ounterlcaflty in tim  - fer more during crises. Governments could do better to
protect these programs from cuts. Experience in the region
and in the U.S. shows that a successful strategy requires
Since the New Deal launched by President Fraklin       explicitly accounting for political economy factors that
Roosevelt in the 1930s, the U.S. has had mnan  of the  make programs resilient to both political and economic
programs being considered in LAC. Some of the U.S.     changes (see Box 7.6). Such factors may include deliber-
I experience may be relevant for coutrites in the rgion.  ately building in some features that have been associated
Snyder and YckovIlev (200   provide a quantitative     with longer-lived government interventions, such as
analysis of social Spending in the U.S. during 1962487,  designing and marketing them as countrywide programs
using detailed spending series and controlling for both  aimed at the poor, rather than programs targeted at partic-
political and economic factors. Some of their results are-  ular parts of the country.
Overall, spending on social protection is quite      There is room for improving the design of targeted pro-
countercyclical in the U.S. The analysis deals    grams, however, especially how they relate to the economic
only with ongoing programs, though it pearsp      cycle. While meeting many of the goals they were
that extending the analysis to new progms will    designed to accomplish in various settings (for example,
make the spending appear somewhat mote pro-       both rural and urban), targeted conditional transfer (TCT)
cyclical.                                         programs such as Mexico's Progresa and Brazil's Bolsa Escola
* The most countercyclical program, by far, is      do not seem to be especially well suited to assist those vul-
unemployment insurance (see Chapter 6). Social    nerable to poverty with cash assistance in economic down-
securi  is also relatively countercyclical. these  turns. Through their innovative links with human capital
programs are distinguishable from others in ha-   accumulation, TCT programs may be better suited than
X ing a strong 'enttitement" factor: because people  earlier interventions to address structural poverty concerns,
see them as something they have specifically con-  and even to counter the cyclical swings in quality of edu-
tributed to, they are difficult for poit'icians to  cation and healthcare services. They look even better when
alter over the cycle.                            political economy factors are explicitly considered-the
*  argeted and nontareted programs appear to be     programs appear to have increasingly broad political sup-
equally countercyclical. Prgrms can be quite      port, which is rather rare for transfer programs. More con-
well targeted and still be resilient over both eco- I   ventional instruments such as public works programs-
nonic and political cycles-that is, it is not true  when designed well-may be better safety nets, but have
that programs must help both the poor and non-    not enjoyed the same degree of popular support in the
poor to attain resilience in a democracy. Avoiding  region. Based on these considerations, targeted conditional
overt "welfare" labels, keepi  eligibility flxble  transfer programs should be viewed as a strong contender
so that the transient poor also can benefit fiom   for forming the third leg of a comprehensive and perma-
the program (for example, food stamps) and aim-   nent safety net-the first two being social security for the
ing to help poor children rather than adults can  elderly and disabled, and income support for the unem-
keep support fbr the programs high among even     ployed in both the formal and informal sectors.
the nonpoor.                                        In conclusion, governments in the region do appear to
* Programs that aretaeted at (poor placs Appear     have behaved in a pro-poor manner in the most general
to fiare worse than nationwide programs targeted  terms, especially since the rise of democracy in the last two
at the poor.                                      decades. While authoritarian and democratic regimes in
* Which party is in control of Contgress clearly i   LAC appear to have responded similarly to economic
matters-all social protection progras grow        crises-both  cut social spending sharply and about
faster under Democratic control. However, party   equally-greater increases in spending take place under
ontrol matters even more fbr targeted programs.  democratic rule. However, this is also where governments
run the greatest danger of adding policy risk to economic
124



HELPING POOR HOUSEHOLDS DEAL BETTER WITH ECONOMIC CRISES
risk. Well-intentioned governments or those under politi-   times and repay during good times, The main problem in
cal pressure to sharply increase spending on social pro-    this regard is that private markets for such instruments do
grams during growth episodes, only to have to reduce    not exist: short-term capital usually flows out of countries
spending in the next contraction, both raise risk and sow     during economic downturns, to return only in good times.
the seeds of social discontent.                                  Discipline on the part of both governments and inter-
The obvious solution for governments is to rely less on    national financial institutions can help countries deal bet-
ex post coping and more on ex ante insurance-that is,   ter with aggregate economic volatility. Countries that
move resources from good states to bad. This report takes    institute effective self-protection (that is, through compre-
the view that the reason why governments have not been    hensive economic reforms) and self-insurance (that is,
doing this is neither ignorance nor indifference, but lies in    through well-designed and efficiently run social programs)
an interplay of political and economic factors. Self-insur-    should be rewarded with credit at reasonable terms. These
ance at the country level (for example, through fiscal stabi-   loans should be repaid during good times. Lending by
lization funds) is a difficult option for democratic govern-    these institutions should therefore be both strongly coun-
ments: saving during good times runs the risk of being    tercyclical so that it serves as insurance, and discriminating
punished by the electorate, and the funds may be used up    so that it encourages self-protection by governments.
by more short-sighted successors. There are two viable
options. The first is to create a sense of entitlement among    Notes
the electorate for programs that have a genuine insurance        1. Wodon and others (2000) find that this is roughly propor-
component, such as that displayed by unemployment insur-    tional: a I percent fall in per capita GDP leads to a I percent rise in
ance and social security in the U.S. The second is access to    headcount poverty.
2. As measured by the SIMCE Mathematics, Spanish, and Gen-
financial markets in a manner that serves the purpose of    eral Knowledge tests, taken ar the fourth and eighth grades in all
market insurance: governments can borrow  during bad    Chilean schools.
125






Bibliography
The word processed describes informally reproduced works   Blanchflower, D., and S. Burgess. 1996. "Job Creation and
that may not be available through libraries.            Job Destruction in Great Britain in the 1980s. Indus-
trial and Labor Relations Review 50(1) :17-38.
Aizenman, Joshua, and Nancy P. Marion. 1993. "Policy   Caballero, Ricardo. 1999(a). "Structural Volatility in Mex-
Uncertainty, Persistence and Growth." Review of Interna-  ico: A Policy Report." MIT mimeo. Cambridge, MA:
tional Economics 1 :145-163.                          Massachusetts Institute of Technology, October 28.
Allen, Steven G., Adriana Cassoni, Gaston J. Labadie.     . 1999(b). "Structural Volatility in Chile: A Policy
1994. "Labor Market Flexibility and Unemployment in   Report." MIT mimeo. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts
Chile and Uruguay. "Estudios de Economia 21 (Special  Institute of Technology, October 25.
Issue) :127-46. Santiago, Chile, November.                . 1999(c). "Structural Volatility in Argentina: A
Amadeo, Edward, Indermit Gill, and Marcelo Neri. 2000.  Policy Report." MIT mimeo. Cambridge, MA: Massa-
"Do Labor Laws Matter? The Pressure Points in Brazil's  chusetts Institute of Technology, October 17.
Labor Legislation." In Indermit Gill and Claudio Mon-   Caballero, Ricardo. 2000. "Aggregate Volatility in Latin
tenegro, (eds.), Readdressing Latin America's Forgotten  America: Diagnostic, Analysis, and Policy Recommen-
Reform: Quantifying Labor Policy Challenges in Argentina,  dations." Paper written for the Regional Study Dealing
Brazil and Chile. Unpublished manuscript. Washing-    with Economic Insecurity in Latin America and the
ton, D.C.: World Bank.                                Caribbean. Office of the Chief Economist, Latin Amer-
Arango, Carlos, and William F. Maloney. 2000a. "Trade   ica and the Caribbean Region. Washington, D.C.:
Reform  and  Income Insecurity  in Mexico and         World Bank.
Argentina." Mimeo, Latin America and Caribbean Sec-   Caballero, Ricardo, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. 1999.
tor Management Unit for Poverty Reduction and Eco-    "Emerging Market Crises: An Asset Market Perspec-
nomic Management. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.      tive." MIT mimeo. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts
. 2000b. "Unemployment Dynamics in Latin Amer-      Institute of Technology, August.
ica: Estimates of Continuous Time Markov Models for     . 2000. "International Liquidity Management: Steril-
Mexico and Argentina." Mimeo, Latin America and       ization Policy in Illiquid Financial Markets." MIT
Caribbean Sector Management Unit for Poverty Reduc-   mimeo. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of
tion and Economic Management. Washington, D.C.:       Technology, April.
World Bank.                                        Calvo, Guillermo, and Carmen M. Reinhart. 1999. "Capital
Arias, Omar. 1999. "Marginalization of Men in Latin     Flow Reversals, the Exchange Rate Debate, and Dollar-
America." Mimeo, Latin America and Caribbean Sector  ization." Finance and Development: A Quarterly Publication
Management Unit for Poverty Reduction and Economic    of the International Monetary Fund 36 :13-15, September.
Management. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.          Carleton, D. 1979. "Why New Firms Locate Where They
Athanasoulis, Stefano, and Eric Van Wincoop. (Forthcom-  Do: An Econometric Model." In W. Wheaton, (ed.),
ing). "Growth Uncertainty and Risk-Sharing." Journal  Interregional Movements and Regional Growth. Washing-
of Monetary Economics.                               ton, D.C.: The Urban Institute.
127



SECURING OUJR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Cardenas, Mauricio, and Raquel Bernal. 1998. "Labor Mar-   Cunningham, Wendy, and William Maloney. 2000. "Mea-
ket Regulation and Labor Demand in Colombia,          suring Vulnerability: Who Suffered in the 1995 Mexi-
1976-1996." Mimeo, Project on Labor Demand and        can Crisis?" Latin America and Caribbean Sector Man-
Labor Market Reform. Washington, D.C.: Inter-Ameri-   agement Unit for Poverty Reduction and Economic
can Development Bank.                                 Management. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Cassoni, Adriana, Steven G. Allen, and Gaston J. Labadie.   Datt, Gaurav, and Martin Ravallion. 1994. "Transfer Ben-
1999. "Union, Labor Market Regulation, and Employ-    efits from Public-Works Employment: Evidence from
ment in Uruguay." Mimeo, Inter-American Develop-      Rural India." Economic Journal 104(427) :1346-1369,
ment Bank. Washington, D.C.                           November.
. 2000. "The Effects of Unions on Employment: Evi-   Davis, S., and J. Haltiwanger. 1990. "Gross Job Creation,
dence from an Unnatural Experiment in Uruguay."       Gross Job Destruction and Employment Reallocation."
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper     QuarterlyJournal of Economics 107(3) :819-864.
7501. Cambridge, MA.                                Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay. 2000. "Growth Is Good for
Coate, Stephen. 1995. "Altruism, the Samaritan's         the Poor." Mimeo. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Dilemma, and Government Transfer Policy." The Amer-   Dunne, T., M. Roberts, and L. Samuelson. 1989. "Plant
ican Economic Review 85 :46-5 7.                       Turnover and Gross Employment Flows in U.S. Manu-
Coloma, Fernando C. 1996. "Seguro de Desempleo: Teoria,  facturing."Journal of Labor Economics 7(1) :48-71.
Evidencia y Una Propuesta." Cuadernos de Economia Ano   Duryea, Suzanne.  1998. "Children's  Advancement
33(99) :295-320, August.                              Through School in Brazil: The Role of Transitory
Conning, Jonathan, P. Olinto, and A. Trigueros. 2000.    Shocks to Household Income." Mimeo. Washington,
"Managing Economic Insecurity in Rural El Salvador."  D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank.
World Bank and Williams College, Department of Eco-   Easterly, William Russel, and Aart Kraay. 1999. "Small
nomics, processed.                                    States, Small Problems?" Policy Research Working
Cox, Donald, and Emmanuel Jimenez. 1998. "Risk-Shar-     Paper 2139. Washington, D.C.: World Bank, June.
ing and Private Transfers: What About Urban House-   Easterly, William  Russel, Roumeen Islam, and Joseph
holds?" Economic Development and Cultural Change 46(3)  Stiglitz. 2000. "Shaken and Stirred: Volatility and
:621-639.                                             Macroeconomic Paradigms for Rich and Poor Coun-
Cunningham, Wendy V. 1997. "Unemployment Insurance       tries." Michael Bruno Memorial Lecture. Washington,
in a Multi-Sectoral Labor Market: The Case of Brazil."  D.C.: World Bank.
Unpublished manuscript. Washington D.C.: World   Eaton, Jonathan, and Gene M. Grossman. 1985. "Tariffs as
Bank.                                                  Insurance: Optimal Commercial Policy when Domestic
-   1999. "Breadwinner versus Caregiver: Labor Force     Markets are Incomplete." Canadian Journal of Economics
Participation and Sectoral Choice over the Mexican     18: 258-72.
Business Cycle." World Bank draft. Washington D.C.,   Edwards, Alejandra Cox, and Chris Manning. 1999. "The
October 28.                                           Economics of Employment Protection and Unemploy-
. 2000. "Unemployment Insurance in Brazil: Unem-    ment Insurance Schemes: Reflections on Policy Options
ployment Duration, Wages and Sectoral Choice." Paper  for Thailand, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Indonesia."
prepared for the Regional Study on Economic Insecu-    Paper prepared for the OECD, presented at World
rity, Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and  Bank-International Labour Organisation-JMOL/JIL
Caribbean Region. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.        Seminar on Economic Crisis, Employment, and Labour
Cunningham, Wendy, and Raquel Artecona. 2000. "Labor     Markets in East and South East Asia. Tokyo, October
Market Outcomes: Recent Trends and the Role of Gen-    13-15.
der in Three LAC Countries." Latin America and    Edwards, Sebastian. 1999. "How Effective are Capital Con-
Caribbean Sector Management Unit for Poverty Reduc-   trols?"Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(4) :65-84.
tion and Economic Management. Washington, D.C.:   Edwards, Sebastian, and Miguel A. Savastano. 1999.
World Bank.                                            "Exchange Rates in Emerging Economies: What Do We
128



BIBLIOGRAPHY
Know? What Do We Need to Know?" National Bureau      Preliminary Report prepared as part of International
of Economic Research, Working Paper Series No. 7228  Food Policy Research Institute's evaluation of the Pro-
:1-72. Cambridge, MA.                                gresa program. Washington, D.C., March.
Edwards, Sebastian, and Nora Lustig, (eds.). 1997. Labor   Ghosh, Atish R., Anne Marie Gulde, and Holger C. Wolf.
Markets in Latin America: Combining Social Protection with  1998. "Currency Boards: The Ultimate Fix?" Working
Market Flexibility. Washington, D.C: Brookings Institu-  Paper 98/8. Washington D.C.: International Monetary
tion Press.                                          Fund, January.
Ehrlich, Isaac, and Gary Becker. 1972. "Market Insurance,   Gill, Indermit, Amit Dar, and Mark Thomas. 1999.
Self-insurance and Self-Protection." Journal of Political  "Financing Unemployment Insurance: International
Economy 80 :623-648.                                 Experience and Lessons for Brazil." Unpublished manu-
Eichengreen, Barry, and Ricardo Hausmann. 1999.         script. Washington D.C.: World Bank.
"Exchange Rates and Financial Fragility." National   Gill, Indermit, and Claudio Montenegro, (eds.). 2000.
Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper Series    Readdressing Latin America's Forgotten Reform: Quantifying
No. 7418 :1-52. Cambridge, MA, November.             Labor Policy Challenges in Argentina, Brazil, and Chile.
Fajnzylber, Pablo, and William F. Maloney. 2000. "Labor  Unpublished manuscript. Washington, D.C.: World
Demand and Trade Liberalization in Latin America."   Bank.
Mimeo, Latin America and Caribbean Sector Manage-   Gill, Indermit, and Nadeem Ilahi. 2000. "Economic Inse-
ment Unit for Poverty Reduction and Economic Man-    curity, Individual Behavior, and Social Policy." Paper
agement. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.               prepared for the Regional Study on Economic Insecu-
. 2000. "Labor Demand in Colombia, Chile and Mex-  rity, Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and
ico, Dynamic Panel Modeling." Mimeo, Latin America   Caribbean Region. Washington D.C.: World Bank.
and Caribbean Sector Management Unit for Poverty   Gill, Indermit, Erik Haindl, Claudio Sapelli, and Claudio
Reduction and Economic Management. Washington,       Montenegro. 2000. "Chile: Has Employment Become
D.C.: World Bank.                                    More 'Precarious'?" In Indermit Gill and Claudio Mon-
Fajnzylber, Pablo, Eduardo Ribeiro, and William F. Mal-  tenegro, (eds.), Readdressing Latin America's Forgotten
oney. 1999. "Turnover, Exit/Entrance Decisions and   Reform: Quantifying Labor Policy Challenges in Argentina,
Labor Demand in Chile." Mimeo, Latin America and     Brazil, and Cbile. Unpublished manuscript. Washing-
Caribbean Sector Management Unit for Poverty Reduc-  ton, D.C.: World Bank.
tion and Economic Management. Washington, D.C.:   Gill, Indermit, Eric Haindl, Claudio Montenegro, and
World Bank.                                          Claudio Sapelli. 2000. "Has Employment in Chile
Ferreira, Francisco H. G., and Indermit Gill. 2000.     Become More Precarious?" In Readdressing Latin Amer-
"Weathering Storms: Households, Governments and      ica's Forgotten Reform: Quantifying Labor Policy Challenges
Aggregate Income Shocks in Latin America." World     in Argentina, Brazil and Chile. World Bank draft. Wash-
Bank draft. Washington, D.C.                         ington, D.C.
Frankel Jacob E., Sergio Schmukler, and Luis Serven. 2000.   Glewwe, Paul, and Gillette Hall. 1998. "Are Some Groups
"Verifying Exchange Rate Regimes." Mimeo. Washing-   More Vulnerable to Macroeconomic Shocks Than Oth-
ton, D.C.: World Bank.                               ers? Hypothesis Tests Based on Panel Data from Peru."
Garibaldi, P. 1999. "Job Flow Dynamics and Firing      Journal of Development Economics 56(1) :181-206.
Restrictions." European Economic Review 42(1) :245-275.   Gonzalez, Jose Antonio. 1999. "Labor Market Flexibility in
Gavin, Michael, and Ricardo Hausmann. 1995. "The        13 Latin American Countries and the U.S." World Bank
Macroeconomics of Capital Flows to Latin America:    Latin American Viewpoints Series and Latin America
Experience and Policy Issues." Inter-American Develop-  and the Caribbean Regional Study. Washington, D.C.
ment Bank, Office of the Chief Economist, Working   Guasch, J. Luis. 1999a. Labor Market Refowm andJob Cre-
Paper 310. Washington, D.C., October.                ation: The Unfinished Agenda in Latin American and
Gertler, Paul. 2000. "A Preliminary Evaluation of the   Caribbean Countries. Directions in Development Series.
Impact of Progresa on Health and Health Utilization."  Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
129



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
_-   1999b. "An Alternative to Traditional Unemploy-   Jalan, Jyotsna, and Martin Ravallion. 1999. "Estimating
ment Insurance Programs: A Liquidity-Based Approach    the Benefit Incidence of an Antipoverty Program by
Against the Risk of Earnings Losses." Unpublished      Propensity Score Matching." Unpublished manuscript.
manuscript. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.             Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Haindl, Erik. 1985. "Un modelo para la determinacion de   Jones, Polly, and Martin Ravallion. 1999. "The Trabajar
flujos y parametros dinamicos en el mercado de trabajo."  Program  in Argentina." Unpublished manuLscript.
Estudio de Economia 12, marzo. Santiago: Universidad de  Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Chile.                                              Kalbfleisch, J. D., and J. F. Lawless. 1985. "The Analysis
Hamermesh, Daniel S. 1992. "Unemployment Insurance       of Panel Data under a Markov Assumption." Journal of
for Developing Countries." Policy Research Working    the American Statistical Association 80(392) :863-871.
Paper, No. 897. Washington, D.C.: World Bank, May.    Kaminsky, Graciela, and Sergio Schmukler. 2000. "Sever-
-  1993. Labor Demand. Princeton: University Press.      ing International Financial Links: A New Look at Cap-
Hatzius, Jan. 2000. "Foreign Direct Investment and Factor  ital Controls." Mimeo. Washington, D.C.: World Bank,
Demand Elasticities." European Economic Review 44 (1)  April 17.
:117-43.                                            Klein, M., S. Schuh, and R. Triest. 2000. "Job Creation,
Hicks Norman, and Quentin Wodon. 2000. "Economic         Job Destruction and the Real Exchange Rate." National
Shocks, Safety Nets, and Fiscal Constraints: Social Pro-  Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 7466.
tection for the Poor in Latin America. In XII Seminario  Cambridge, MA, January.
Regional de Politica Fiscal: Compendio de Documentos 2000.   Konings, J. 1995. "Job Creation and job Destruction in
Economic Commission for Latin America and the         the U.K. Manufacturing Sector." Oxford Bulletin of Eco-
Caribbean. Santiago, Chile, United Nations, 381-407.   nomics and Statistics 57(l) :5-24.
Holzmann, Robert, and Steen Jorgensen. 1999. "Social Pro-   Kraays and Nran 57(1) :5-24.
tection as Social Risk Management: Conceptual Under-   Kraay, Aarr, Norman Loayza, Luis Serven, and Jaumre Ven-
tection asocilRskMangemnt:Cocepuatura. 2000. "Country Portfolios." Mimeo. Washington,
pinnings for the Social Protection Sector Strategy Paper."  D.C.: World Bank.
Journal of International Development 11(7) :1005-27.   D.C.: Adriank.
Hpenhyn, Hugo A., and Juan Pablo Nicolini. 1999.   Kugler, Adriana D. 1999. "The Impact of Firing Cosso
"Hopeterogenei      andO.ial Unmloyment 1nsur         Turnover and Unemployment: Evidence from  the
"Heterogeneity and Optimal Unemployment Insur-        Colombian Labour Market Reform." International Tax
ance." Paper presented at the Conference on Social Pro-   ColiancLaournal                           Tax
tection and Poverty. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American  and PulcFnneJourna 6(3).
Development Bank, February.                              . 2000. "Does Replacing Employer Insurance for Self-
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank). 1995. Economic    Insurance Improve the Performance of the Labor Mar-
ID  (ItrAeia Deeomn Bak) 195 Economic ,               ket? The Case of the Colombian Severance Payments
and Social Progress in Latin America. Office of the Chief
Economist. Washington D.C., January.                  Savings Accounts." Paper prepared for the Regional
. 2000. Social Protection for Equity and Growth. Wash-  Study on Economic Insecurity, Office of the ChieftEcon-
ington, D.C.                                          omist, Latin America and Caribbean Region. Washing-
Ilahi, Nadeem. 1999. "Children's Work and Schooling      ton, D.C.: World Bank.
Under Shocks: Does Gender Matter? Evidence from the     . 2000. "Job Security Provisions, Labor Market Flexi-
Peru LSMS Panel Data." Background paper for Engen-    bility and Non-Compliance: Evidence from Colombia."
dering Development, Technical Report. Washington,      Forthcoming in Daniel Hamermesh, James He,ckman
D.C.: World Bank.                                     and Carmen Pages, (eds.), Labor Market Regulation in
International Labour Office. 1999. Decent Work and Protec-  Latin America. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American
tion for All: Priority of the Americas. Report of the Direc-  Development Bank.
tor General. Geneva.                                Leiderman, Leonardo, Ricardo Hausmann, and Gavin,
Jack, William. 2000. "The Evolution of Health Insurance  Michael. 1995. "Macroeconomics of Capital Flows to
Institutions: Theory and Four Examples from Latin      Latin America: Experience and Policy Issues." Working
America." World Bank draft. Washington, D.C.           Paper No. 310, Oct.
130



BIBLIOGRAPHY
Levenson, Alec R., and William F. Maloney. 1998. "The   Mizala, Alejandra, and Pilar Romaguera. 2000. "The
Informal Sector, Firm Dynamics, and Institutional Par-  Quality of Social Services: The Case of Chile." World
ticipation." Policy Research Working Paper No. 1988.   Bank draft. Washington, D.C.
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.                       Montenegro, Claudio E. 1998. "The Structure of Wages in
Levinsohn, J. 1999. "Employment Responses to Interna-    Chile 1960-1996: An Application of Quantile Regres-
tional Liberalization in Chile." Journal of International  sion." Estudios de Economic 25(1) :71-98.
Economics 47(2) :321-344.                           Montenegro, Claudio E., and Indermit Gill. 2000. "Chile's
Lewis, Karen K. 1999. "Trying to Explain Home Bias in    Public Work Programs: Did They Work Then and
Equities and Consumption." TheJournal of Economic Lit-  Would They Work Now?" Paper prepared for the
erature 37(2).                                         Regional Study on Economic Insecurity, Office of the
Loayza, Norman. 1995. "The Economics of the Informal Sec-  Chief Economist, Latin America and Caribbean Region.
tor: A Simple Model and Some Empirical Evidence from   Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Latin America." World Bank draft. Washington, D.C.  Montiel, Peter, and Carmen M. Reinhart. 1999. "Do Cap-
Lustig, Nora. 1999. "Crises and the Poor: Socially Respon-  ital Controls and Macroeconomic Policies Influence the
sible Economics." Poverty and Inequality Unit,        Volume and Composition of Capital Flows? Evidence
processed. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American Develop-   from  the 1990s." Journal of International Mone' and
ment Bank.                                             Finance 18(4) :619-35.
MacIsaac, Donna, and Martin Rama. 2000. "Mandatory    Morduch, Jonathan. 1999. "Between the State and the
Severance Pay in Peru: An Assessment of its Coverage   Market: Can Informal Insurance Patch the Safety Net?"
and Effects Using Panel Data." Paper prepared for the  World Bank Research Observer 14(2) :187-207, August.
Regional Study on Economic Insecurity, Office of the   Narayan, Deepa, Raj Patel, Kai Schafft, Anne Rademacher,
Chief Economist, Latin America and Caribbean Region.   and Sarah Koch-Schulte. 2000. Voices of the Poor: Can
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.                         Anyone Hear Us? (World Bank.) New York: Oxford Uni-
Maloney, William. 1999a. "Does Informality Imply Seg-    versity Press.
mentation in Urban Labor Markets? Evidence from Sec-   Neri, Marcelo, and Mark Thomas. 2000. "Household
toral Transitions in Mexico." World Bank Economic      Responses  to  Labor-Market Shocks  in  Brazil:
Review 13(2) :275-302, May.                            1982-1999." World Bank draft. Washington, D.C.
. 1999b. "Self-Employment and Labor Turnover:   Obstfeld, Maurice. 1994. Foundations of International
Cross-Country Evidence." Policy Research Working       Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Paper No. 2102. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.       Olson, Mancur. 2000. Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Com-
. 2000. "How Should We Think about Emergency         munist and Capitalist Dictatorships. New York: Basic
Programs?" Unpublished manuscript. Washington,         Books.
D.C.: World Bank.                                   Paes de Barros, Ricardo, Carlos Henrique Corseuil, and
Maloney, William F, and Eduardo Ribeiro. 1999. "Effi-    Gustavo Gonzaga. 1999. "Labor Market Regulations
ciency Wage and Union Effects in Labor Demand and      and the Demand for Labor in Brazil." Mimeo. Wash-
Wage Structure in Mexico: An Application of Quantile  ington, D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank.
Analysis." Mimeo. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American    Paes de Barros, Ricardo, Carlos Henrique Corseuil, Miguel
Development Bank.                                      Foguel, Gustavo Gonzaga, Ricardo Henriques, Rosane
Marquez, Gustavo. 1999. "Labor Markets and Income Sup-   Silva Pinto de Medonca, and Danieli Milton. 1998.
port: What Did We Learn from the Crises?" Unpub-       "Labor Market Regulations and the Demand for Labor
lished manuscript. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American    in Brazil." Mimeo, Project on Labor Demand and Labor
Development Bank.                                      Market Reform. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American
Mazza, Jacqueline. 1999. Unemployment Insurance: Case    Development Bank.
Studies and Lessons for Latin America and the Caribbean.   Pagnagariya, Arvind. 1999. "Trade Openness: Consequences
RE2/SO2, Technical Study. Washington, D.C.: Inter-    for the Elasticity of Demand for Labor and Wage Out-
American Development Bank, May.                        comes." Mimeo, University of Maryland Regional Study.
131



SECURING OUR FUTURE IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY
Parker, Susan W, and Emmanuel Skoufias. 2000. "Job    Roberts, M. 1996. "Employment Flows and Producer
Loss, Change in Marital Status, and the Allocation of  Turnover." In M. Roberts and J. Tybout, (eds.), Industry
Time within Families: Evidence from Urban Mexico."    Evolution in Developing Countries. New York: Oxford Uni-
Draft, Programa de Educaci6n, Salud y Alimentaci6n    versity Press.
and International Food Policy Research Institute.   Roberts, M. J., and E. Skoufias. 1997. "The Long-Run
Washington, D.C.                                      Demand for Skilled and Unskilled Labor in Colombian
Perry, Guillermo, and Daniel Lederman. 1999. "Adjust-   Manufacturing Industries." Review of Economics and Sta-
ments After Speculative Attacks in Latin America and  tistics 79 :330-334.
Asia: A Tale of Two Regions?" World Bank Latin Amer-   Roberts, M. J., and J. R. Tybout. 1996. Industrial Evolution
ican and Caribbean Studies, Viewpoints. Washington,  in Developing Countries: Micro Patterns of Turnover. Produc-
D.C.: World Bank.                                     tivity, and Market Structure. New York: Oxford Univer-
Pindyck, Robert S., and Andres Solimano. 1993. "Eco-    sity Press.
nomic Instability and Aggregate Investment." National   Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far;) Wash-
Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No.       ington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
4380. Cambridge, MA, June.                              . 1999. "Why is There So Much Economic Insecurity
Rama, Martin, and William Maloney. 2000. "Income Sup-   in Latin America?" World Bank draft, processed. Wash-
port Programs for the Unemployed in Latin America."  ington, D.C., October.
World Bank draft. Washington, D.C.                 Saavedra, Jaime. 1999. "Labor Demand of Formal Firms in
Ramey, Garey, and Valerie A. Ramey. 1995. "Cross-Coun-  Peru." Mimeo, Project on Labor Demand and Labor
try Evidence on the Link Between Volatility and       Market Reform. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American
Growth." American Economic Revieaw 85 :1138-51.       Development Bank.
Ravallion, Martin. 1990. "On the Coverage of Public   Saavedra, Jaime, and Maximo Torero. 1999. "Labor Market
Employment Schemes for Poverty Alleviation."Journal   Regulations and Employment in Peru." Unpublished
of Development Economics 34(1-2) :57-79, November.    manuscript, Grupo de analisis para el desarrollo. Lima,
-  1999a. "Appraising Workfare." World Bank Research    Peru.
Observer 14(1) :31-48.                                  . 2000. "Trade Liberalization, Labor Market Reforms
_-   1999b. "Is More Targeting Consistent with Less     and Labor Demand." Mimeo, Project on Labor Demand
Spending?" International Tax and Public Finance. Wash-  and Trade Liberalization, W. F. Maloney, (ed.), Washing-
ington, D.C.: World Bank.                             ton D.C.: World Bank.
-   1999c. "Monitoring Targeting Performance when   Schady, Norbert. 2000. "The Impact of Economic Crises on
Decentralized Allocations to the Poor are Unobserved."  School Attendance: Evidence from Peru-A  Research
Unpublished manuscript. Washington D.C.: World        Proposal." East Asia and Pacific Region, processed.
Bank.                                                 Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
. 2000. "Can Public Works Programs Protect the   Schultz, T. Paul. 2000. "The Impact of Progresa on School
Vulnerable during Macroeconomic Downturns?" Paper     Enrollments." Final Report prepared as part of Interna-
prepared for the Regional Study on Economic Insecu-   tional Food Policy Research Institute's evaluation of the
rity, Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and  Progresa program, April.
Caribbean Region. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.    Sedlacek, Guilherme, Nadeem Ilahi, and Emily Gustafs-
. 2000. "The Incidence of Fiscal Contractions: Theory  son-Wright. 2000. "Targeted Conditional Transfers in
and Evidence for Argentina." Mimeo. Washington,       Latin America: An Early Survey." World Bank draft.
D.C.: World Bank.                                     Washington, D.C.
Ravallion, Martin, Gaurav Datt, and Shubham Chaudhuri.   Serven, Luis. 1999. "Macroeconomic Uncertainty and Pri-
1993. "Does Maharashtra's Employment Guarantee        vate Investment in Developing Countries: An Empirical
Scheme Guarantee Employment? Effects of the 1988      Investigation." Mimeo. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Wage Increase." Economic Development and Cultural       . 2000. "Note on the Evolution of Macroeconomic
Change 41(2) :251-275.                                Risk in Latin America." Mimeo, Latin America and
132



BIBLIOGRAPHY
Caribbean Sector Management Unit for Poverty Reduc-   Weller, Jurgen. 1999. "Crecimiento, empleo y equidad."
tion and Economic Management. Washington, D.C.:      Mimeo, Economic Commission for Latin America and
World Bank.                                          the Caribbean. Santiago, Chile.
Serven, Luis, and Andres Solimano. 1993. Striving for   Wodon Quentin. 2000. "Income Mobility and Risk Dur-
Growth After Adjustment: The Role of Capital Formation.  ing the Business Cycle." Mimeo, Latin American and
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.                        the Caribbean. Washington D.C.: World Bank.
Serven, Luis, and N. Gonzalez. 2000. "A Note on Aggre-    . 2000. "Poverty and Policy in Latin America and the
gate Employment/Wages in LAC." Mimeo, Latin          Caribbean." Regional Study, Latin America and
America and Caribbean Sector Management Unit for     Caribbean Sector Management Unit for Poverty Reduc-
Poverty Reduction and Economic Management. Wash-     tion and Economic Management. Washington, D.C.:
ington, D.C.: World Bank.                            World Bank.
Skoufias, Emmanuel, Benjamin Davis, and Jere Behrman.     . 2000. "Public Works Employment and Workfare
1999. "An Evaluation of the Selection of Beneficiary  Programs: Optimizing the Timing of Benefits for Poverty
Households in the Education, Health and Nutrition    Reduction." Mimeo. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Program (Progresa) of Mexico." Final Report prepared as   Wodon, Quentin, and C. Siaens. 1999. "Training for the
part of International Food Policy Research Institute's  Urban Unemployed: A Reevaluation of Mexico's Probe-
evaluation of the Progresa program, June.            cat. In Government Programs and Poverty in Mexico, Report
Snyder, James, and Irene Yackovlev. 2000. "Political and  No. 19214-ME. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Economic Determinants of Government Spending on   Wodon, Quentin, Norman Hicks, Bernadette Ryan, and
Social Protection Programs." MIT Department of Polit-  Gabriel Gonzalez. 1999. "Are Governments Pro-poor? A
ical Science and Economics. Paper prepared for the   Test Based on Targeted and Social Spending During
Regional Study on Economic Insecurity, Office of the  Booms and Busts." World Bank draft. Washington, D.C.
Chief Economist, Latin America and Caribbean Region.   Wodon, Quentin, W. Maloney, and M. Barenstein. 2000.
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.                        "Self-Employment as an Explanation for High Inequal-
Tybout, J. 1996. "Chile, 1979-86: Trade Liberalization  ity in Latin America." Processed. Washington, D.C.:
and its Aftermath." In M. Roberts and J. Tybout, (eds.),  World Bank.
Industry Evolution in Developing Countries. New York:   Wodon, Quentin, and Mari Minowa. 1999. "Training for
Oxford University Press.                             the Urban Unemployed: A Reevaluation of Mexico's
Tzannatos, Zafiris, and Suzanne Roddis. 1998. "Unem-    Probecat." Paper prepared for the Regional Study on
ployment Benefits." SP Discussion Paper No. 9813,    Economic Insecurity, Office of the Chief Economist,
Social Protection Unit, Human Development Network.   Latin America and Caribbean Region. Washington,
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.                        D.C.: World Bank.
van Wincoop, Eric. 1999. "How Big are Potential Gains   Wodon, Quentin, R. Ayres, M. Barenstein, N. Hicks, K.
from International Risk Sharing?" Journal of Interna-  Lee, W. Maloney, P. Peeters, C. Siaens, and S. Yitzhaki.
tional Economics 47(1) :109-135.                     2000. "Poverty and Policy in Latin America and The
Vodopovic, Milan. 2000. "Income Support Systems for     Caribbean." Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Unemployed Workers." Research Project (in Progress),   World Bank. 1990. World Development Report 1990. New
Human Development Network, Social Protection Unit.   York: Oxford University Press.
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.                          . 1997. The Long March, A Reform Agenda for Latin
Vroman, Wayne. 1998. Topics in Unemployment Insurance   America and the Caribbean in the Next Decade. World
Financing. Kalamazoo, Michigan: W. E. Upjohn Insti-  Bank Latin American and Caribbean Studies, View-
tute for Employment Research.                        points. Washington, D.C.
133









THE WORLD BANK
I 8 IS H Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A.
Telephonie: 202-477-l234
Facsimile: 202-477-6391
Telex: MCI 64145 WORLDBANK
M\4CI 248423 WORl.DBANK
NVlorld Wide 'Web: wwNv.\vorldban k.org/
E-mail: hooks@worjldbanik.org
ISBN 0-8213-4730-6