Policy, Planning, and Research WORKING PAPERS Debt and Internallonal Finance International Economics Department The World Bank November 1988 WPS 132 Is the Discount on the Secondary Market a Case for LDC Debt Relief? Daniel Cohen A discount in the secondary market is a case for debt service relief but not necessarily for a write-off. The author derives a "maximum repayment" rescheduling program, which trades off higher current investment for lower current debt service. lhe Pdicy, Mng. nd Re-chCmnplex abut P RWo* ngPs todimnato the afs of wkmWfs in nd to a8getheeh ides f magBan sff anda otheuieatwdindevdpnenieThese ppcanythenamof the ao, rdect only theirviews and should heused and cted accomdngly hfindins. intea, and cuci aethe auhOWILow/lheyshoulddnwbeatubuedbtode WorddBank,itSBo rdofDict,is.lSmgexnei,ornyofitsmemberoumia. Polac,Pnnlng, and Ruch | Debt and Intemituonal Finance| Proposit.on 1: The "maximum repayment" wvile the market price of the debt is stabilized at program the lenders would like to monitor a constant equilibrium price below par. involve a fixed investment rate that is smaller than the socially optimal rate and larger than the (Implication: Observing a discount on the post-default rate. It involves a transfer of debt does not automatically warrant a write-off. resources from the debtor that is a fixed fraction The discount implies the possibility of default, of GDP - a fraction that is smaller than the cost but lenders should not write the debt off until the of default. possibility materializes. But the service of the debt shlould always be scaled down by its Proposition 2: When the debt-to-GDP ratio market value rather than kept in line with its face is above a floor value (h*), the lenders can value.) capture the "maximum repayment" value (V*) by fictitiously splitting the debt into performing Proposition 4: When the lenders reschedule and nonperfonning components. Each period, the debt on a period-by-period basis, they induce they should ask the borrower to service the the country to follow a growth pattem that perfonming component of the debt only, and let exactly mimics the post-default path. The the performing component grow at a rate equal lenders capture each period the penalty they to the economy's expected growth rate. Mean- could impose on the defaulting country. As a while, the nonperforming asset is automatically result, they get more on a period-by-period capitalized at the riskless rate. When the actual basis, but less on average than under the "maxi- growth rate of the economy is above (below) its mum repayment" schedule. Under such a ("time expected level, the performing part of the debt is consistent") rescheduling strategy, a write-off scaled up (down). When this "maximum and multiyear rescheduling may prove benefi- repayment" rescheduling strategy is undertaken, cial, but the gains fall short of the strategy the equilibrium market value of the debt is equal defined in Proposition 2. to V*. How relevant is the idea of "debt overhang" Proposition 3: When the debt-to-GDP ratio (according to which the market value of the debt is above the hreshold h*, the debt can be written may depend negatively upon its fact value)? down to h* GDP without impairing the lender's Empirical evidence presented here indicates that, return. If the write-off is repeated each time the at a 75 percent confidence level, 9 of 33 coun- economy declines, and if the rescheduling is tries studied may suffer from a debt overhang undertaken according to Proposition 2, the prblem. At a 90 percent confidence level, only lenders capture the "maximum repayment" 4 of them may be affected by it. This paper is a product of the Debt and Intemational Fmance Division, International Economics Department Copies are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Stre;t NW, Washington DC 20433. Please contact Maggie Luna, room S7-035, extension 33729. The PPR Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work under way in the Bank's Policy, Plaming, and Research Complex. An objective of the series is to get these fmdings out quickly, even if presentations are less than fully polished. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions in these papers do not necessarily represent official policy of the Bank. Produced at the PPR Dissemination Center Is the Discount on the Secondary Market a Case for LDC Debt Relief? by Daniel Cohen Table of Contents Introduction ............................................. 1 I. The Setup ............................................ 5 (a) Production ........................... . 5 (b) Preferences ........................... 7 (c) External Debt ........................... 7 II. The Optimal Growth Rate: The (Totally) Open Case and the Post-Default Case ................................ 9 (a) The open economy case ............................ 9 (b) The post-default case ............................ 10 III. The "Maximum Repayment" Which can be Extracted from an Indebted Country ................................ 11 IV. How to Implement the "Maximum Repayment" Scheme ...... 14 V. The "Debt Overhang" Problem Revisited ................ 17 VI. Empirical Evidence of the "Debt Overhang" Problem.... 20 Appendices ............................................... 24 References ............................................... 31 I gratefully thank Plutarchos Sakellaris for his research assis- tance, Homi Kharas for his insights on the last section of the paper, and the members of the Debt and International Finance Division for their comments and their warm hospitality. Introduction In 1988, the price on the secondary market of LDC dJebt averaged 50 cents per dollar of face value. This figure is certainly an indication that the lenders do not expect (on average) to be repaid the full value of their outstanding claims on LDCs and indeed that they expect perhaps no more than half the value of these claims to be serviced. 1/ Prom the observation of such a discount in the secondary markets, can one go one step further and argue that the debt should be written down in order to account for the discrepancy between the face and the market value of the debt? It is this question that this paper tries to shed some light on, both theoretically and empirically. Theoretically, the rough answer is as follows. A discount in the secondary market can be the effect of two distinct causes: one is that past shocks may have impaired the capability of a debtor to service its ;ebt. Another cause is that future shocks may be expected to impair, when they occur. .he servicing capacity of the country. Por instance, the fall in the price of oil that occurred in 1986, if viewed as permanent, is a shock which (at that time) certainly reduced the expected ability of Mexico to service its external debt, and, to some extent, was translated into a fall of the market price of Mexico's debt. On the other hand, the prospect of say, a Middle-Eastern peace settlement, which brings the expectation of increased oil 1/ The secondary market is a thin market in which, until recently, swap transactions have predominated. Hence secondary market prices may not accurately reflect market expectations. For the purpose of the analysis here, we assume that the secondary market price does reflect the expected value of discounted future debt service. - 2 - supplies, is also part of Mexico's debt value, but its implications for debt relief are dramatically different. As I will indicate in the theoretical part of this paper, only the shocks of the first kind--the "backward shocks"--are open to debt relief., As for the others--"forward shocks"--writing off and forgiveness is only optimal after the shocks occur but not beforehand. Even though it may not always be a good thing to write off the debt in order to account for the discrepancy between its face and its market value, I will show that the service of the debt should always be scaled down by its market value rather than kept in line with its face value. Specifically, I will show that the optimal rescheduling of the debt should proceed as follows. The lenders should split the debt into two components: a performing and a non-performing part. They should act "as if" the debt amounted to the performing component and scale how much money the borrower should pay in debt service on that part only (while the non- performing part is automatically capitalized at the riskless rate). The performing component of the debt should reflect the market value of the debt but it is important that the lenders calculate it themselves. If they were to rely on the market estimate, the borrower would have an incentive to bring down the market price through poor policies or through confrontations with creditors. Nevertheless, at equilibrium, the lenders' and the market's evaluation should coincide. 2/ On the other hand, the non-performing asset should not necessarily be written down. Good outcomes can occur (or expected bad outcomes may fail to materialize) and, conditionally on the good news, the size of the performing 2/ See the caveat in footnote 1. - 3 - asset may be scaled up. In brief, the answer to the question in the title of this paper is as follows: (1) Yes, a discount on the secondary market implies that the service of the debt should be scaled down in line with its market values (2) No, such a strategy does not necessarily imply that the face value should be written down. A discount in the secondary market is a case for debt service relief, not necessarily for a write-off. Obviously, there may come a point in time when the non-performing asset becomes so big as to warrant a write-ofi. However, if creditors operate optimally (along the lines sketched above), the write-off does not modify the market value of the debt; it simply raises the market price. This should come as no surprise. If they behave optimally, the lenders should not lose by having more nominal claims than less. How does this result relate to the "debt overhang" idea, according to which the market value may depend negatively upon the face value of the debt? The link may come as follows. In order to achieve their first best outcomep I will show that the lenders must reschedule the performing component of the debt generously enough to allow for the country's investment needs and, on average, they should let the performing asset grow along with CDP. While a strategy along these lines is shown to be optimal for the lenders, it is not however the case that such a strategy is "time-consistent" (as initially defined by Calvo and Kydland and Prescott). It is not a strategy which can be implmented on a period-by-period basis. Indeed, if dealt with on a period-by-period basis (without setting out the rules of future reschedulings) I will show that a self-fulfulling downward spiral is bound to appear: one in which the fear that the lender will not acknowledge the investment needs of the debtor immediately raises the - 4 - cost of capital in the debtor country, reducing investment immediately and making it ex post-optimal for the lenders to tighten their rescheduling strategy. In the previous literature on the "debt overhang" problem (originated by and Krugman (1987) Sachs (1988)), only these second best equilibria have been examined (for the technical reason that most of the models examined in this literature are two-period models in which the commitment issue could not be addressed). In such a case, when the lenders fail to commit themselves to their first best strategy, a write-off may indeed prove beneficial, by helping the lenders to commit themselves to let the country invest. In no case, however, can it help them get the first best repayment stream. Whether the "debt overhang" problem is empirically relevant has remained an open question (see Claessens (1988) for a review.). Following an idea in Krugman (1988), one may check whether the elasticity of the market price of the debt with respect to its face value is larger than one in absolute value. In the last section of the paper, I will indicate that, at the 75 per nt degree of confidence, 9 countries (in a sample of 33) may suffer (accord.ug to Krugman's test) from a debt overhang problem, while at the 90 percent degree of confidence, only 4 of them may be affected by it. Before closing this introduction, I should emphasize that the case for a write-off which is explored in this paper only rests upon the question of knowing whether the private lenders may find it in their best interest to do so. This is obviously only a narrow way of dealing with the overall question. A write-off may prove beneficial to the lending countries as a whole, when all the relevant spillovers are taken into account, and not to the private lenders themselves. (For such a broader viewpoint see Dornbusch (1988).) In any case, if the industrialized countries wanted to help the debtors (for whatever reason: altraism or educated selfishness), then a partial forgiveness of the debt may be . crucial preliminary step that the industrialized countries would want to encourage--perhaps through regulatory or tax measures--on the part of private lenders. Without partial forgiveness, the lenders may tend to be the main beneficiaries of the public funds poured into the debtor country.) All these crucial issues are outside the scope of this paper but should be kept in mind before any policy conclusion is drawn. Section 1 spells out the model. It is a stochastic version of the model examined in Cohen and Sachs (1986). Section 2 calculates the socially efficient and the post-default growth rates of the economy. Section 3 shows that the lenders, if they were to monitor the investment and the consumption strategy of the borrower (in order to maximize their return) would choose a lower investment strategy than the socially efficient one. Section 4 shows how an optimal rescheduling (based upon the distinction between performing and non-performing assets) can achieve the equilibrium described in Section 3. Section 5 shows the dynamic inconsistency of the optimal strategy spelled out in Section 4, and shows the link with the "debt overhang" literature. Section 6 investigates the empirical relevance of the "debt overhang." I. The Setup (a) Production I will consider a one-good economy, in which the same good can be used for export, consumption or investment. In each period, the available stock of capital is a pre-determined variable. The production, Qt' is a linear function of existing capital: -6- (1) Qt ' Kt Capital can be increased through investment, and investment itself is a costly process. Let us assume that an increase It of capital costs Jt: (2) Jt I ( 2 t t t 2 Q The investment decision It, while taken at time t, increases the capital stock at time t + 1, according a stochastic law of motion: (3) K t+l [ Kt(l-d) 4 It (l*+t,i) in which d is the rate of depreciation of installed capital and 3t is an iid stochastic variable which is worth: (4) et= u with probability p 3,= v with probability 1-p. Here, the investment decision It must be taken before its productivity (o t,) is known. One can think of Et as a stochastic shock which exogenieously increases (or decreases) the productivity of installed capital stock. I shall refer to the event of probability p (where the rate of growth of the productivity of capital is u) as of the "good state" and to the event of probability 1 - p (when productivity experiences a slower, possibly negative, growth rate) as the "bad state." I will call 8 the expected rate of growth of the productivity of capital: (1+0) - p (1+u) + (1-p) (liv). (See Gennotte, Kharas and Sadeq (1987) for a model with a similar structure.) (b) Preferences I will assume that the country is managed by a social planner who can impose on the country an investment and consumption decision. The planner's preferences are represented by an intertemporal expected utility function: (5) UO a E 0 B u (C) 0 0 t in which C. is the aggregate consumption of the country at time t; and u (C) - 1 Cy 1 y < 1 and Y * o, or u (C) Log C when y = �. (c) External Debt In order to focus on the question raised in the title, I will simply assume that the country inherits an initial debt Do (assumed to be short-term) which is large enough to be quoted below par on secondary markets; and I will investigate the optimal rescheduling strategy for the lenders. It is not difficult to show how the framework which is used here could imply that the optimal borrowing strategy does involve such a risk. But some technical issues (such as that of calculating the optimal maturity of the debt) would take this paper too far afield. (See e.g. Cohen (1988) for an analysis, in a - 8 - three period model, of the difficulties at hand.) Following the Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) approach and my earlier work with Sachs, I shall assume that the country always has the ability to repudiate its stock of outstanding debt while the lenders can retaliate and impose on the borrower the following two sanctions: (a) A defaulting country is forced to financial autarky forever after it has defaulted. (b) The productivity of capital of the defaulting country is reduced by a factor A so that the post-default technology of production is: (6) Q (1 - A) t In all that follows, I will assume-that the len.ders are risk-neutral, act competitively, and have access to a riskless rate of interest which stays constant all along. I will assume that 8 is low enough to insure that the country will be constrained on the borrowing side. Furthermore, I will leave aside all bargaining issues and assume that the lenders can credibly make (at each point in time, but not necessarily for the entire future) a take-it-or- leave-it offer to the debtor. - 9 - II. The Optimal Grovth Rate: The (Totally) Open Case and the Post-Default Case In this section, I would like to calculate the optimal investment strategy in the two extreme cases when the country has a free access to the world financial markets en the one hand and when it is forced to a post- default path on the other hand. (a) The open economy case Assume in this sub-section that A I in equation (6) above, i.e. assume that the country cannot repudiate its external debt (because it is too costly). With that assumption, the model boils down to the standard Fisherian case where the investment decision can be separated from the consumption decision. I will simply solve, here, the optimal investment decision. The country wants to maximize its productive wealth when the return on its investment is taken to be the world riskleas rate of interest. Kathematically, this amounts to solving the following program: (7) Wo - Max Eo { 1 [ IK - I (1.1i It) (I)t > � (I + r) t|Kt I(1 20t) The solution to this program is given in Appendix 1. Given the linearities in the model, Wo is shown to be a linear function of initial output: (8) w0 w QO and is obtained by picking up a fixed investment rate: - 10 - i It (9) x associated to a fixed rate of gross investment (iO) y t i + (All the technical conditions for the equilibrium to exist are spelled out in appendix). The equilibrium growth rate of the economy oscillates. It is high in the good state of nature [ (l*u) 'l4x-d) ] and low in the bad state of nature t (l+v) (l-d) ]. From here on, I will refer to this equilibrium as the socially efficient equilibrium. (b) The post-default case Assume now, as another extreme case, that the country has defaulted upon its external debt. In that case, the social planner must choose its investment decision so as to allocate consumption optimally over time. Kathematically, the planner must solve the following programs ()u d(Qo) Mix I u [Qo 11 - (1 + + O) + B p Ud[QO(lOu) (l*x-d)J + 8(l-p) Ud [QO(lIv)(l*x-d) } in which Ud is the utility level that the planner can reach when the available output is QO at the initial time. - 11 - The solution is spelled out in Appendix I where it is shown that the solution Ud (QO) can be written: (12) Ud (Q) C QY if y * o and I log Q+ CO if y - o Yo ~~~~1-s in which CY is a constant. The solution is also shown to involve a fixed investment rate: It which is smaller than the socially efficient investment rate (obtained in the open economy case). III. The "Maximum Repayment" Which Can Be Extracted from an Indebted Country In this section, I will consider the following simple problem. I will assume that the lenders can monitor both the invPstment and the repayment strategy of the debtor in such a way as to maximize the value of the transfers made abroad by the country. While the borrower will be assumed to give up its sovereignty over its consumption and investment decision, it will nevertheless keep its sovereignty over the matter of defaulting: at any point in time, the borrower will stay free to break the lenders' rule and to follow afterwards the post-default path defined by equation (12). In other words, the rules of the game in this section are as follows: the lenders monitor the debtor's economy so as to maximize the value of the transfers channelled abroad by the debtor, subject to the constraint that the program is never expected (neither today nor later on) to be dominated by a post-default path. Clearly, under - 12 - this set of hypotheses, the value of the transfers channelled abroad by the debtor will provide an upper bound to the market value of any debt accumulated by the country. Formally, the problem can be written as follows. Call Pt the amount of transfers abroad made by the debtor, Yt the gross investment rate (inclusive of the cost of installation) achieved by the country, and Ct the consumption left to the country. One has: Ct Qt (I-y) -p Call: (14) Ut E t I !St atu (C")} the level of utility which the lenders' program is expected to deliver to the country. With this notation, the program that the lenders must solve is as follows. (15) Maximize E 0 o 0 t subject to Ut ! Ud (Qd) for all t. in which Ud (Qt) is the post-default level of utility (as defined in equation (12)). This problem is solved in Appendix 2. Given the many linearities built in this model, the problem boils down to finding a fixed (gross) - 13 - investment rate y and a fixed debt service ration Pt/Qt which solves the problem (15). The solution is shown to involve an investment rate which lies between the socially efficient rate and the post-default rate. One can state: Proposition 1: The "maximum repayment" program which the lenders would like to monitor involves a fixed investment rate which is smaller than the socially optimum one and larger than the post- default one. It involves a transfer of resources from the debtor which is a fixed fraction of GDP, a fraction which is smaller than the cost of default. From Proposition 1, we therefore see that the idea according to which the debt may have a "pro-incentive" effect is not granted in the context of the exercise which is carried through here. (For another approach see also Corden (1988) or Helpman (1988).) Even when it is the banks themselves that design the investment and consumption policy of the borrower, they will choose a lower investment rate than is socially desirable. The reason is that the banks must take care to avoid a situation in which the country may one day choose to default. A too rapid path of capital accumulation, even while socially desirable, will raise the post-default utility of the country and, if not carefully balanced, can be counterproductive to the banks. Prom here on, I will call V the "maximum repayment" that the lenders can expect to receive from the debtor. Due to the linearities involved, Vt can be written as a linear function of current output: (16) V* = Z Q - 14 - In appendix 2, I also show that the fraction of CDP which is channelled abroad can be written: (17) b = z [(1 + r) - (1 + 0) (1 + x- d)J in which z is the net investment rate that is described in Proposition 1. IV. How to Implement the "Maximum Repayment" Scheme I will now indicate how the lenders can indeed capture the "maximum repayunt" even when they do not monitor the investment and consumption choice of the borrower. Consider the following decomposition of the debt: (18) Dta V + R= in which Dt is the face value of the debt, Vt is the maximum value calculated above, and Rt is the residual. Assume that the lenders fictitiously regard Rt as a non-performing asset and only insist on V being serviced (while Rt is automatically capitalized). Furthermore, assume that, each period, they ask the borrower to transfer an amount Pt which is the amount necessary to keep v* growing at the expected rate of growth of the economy. Under these assumptions Pt must solve: - 15 - (19) V* = (+r) V P = (1+0) (1+x-d) V t+l t t t in which (1+) (l+x-d) = p (l+u) (l+x-d) * (l-p) (l+u) (l+x-d) is the expected growth rate of the economy when the investment rate x has been selected by the debtor. Pt is then given by: Pt = l(lr) - (1+0) (lex-d)] Vt Pt = [ (l+r) - (1+e) (lex-d) ] Q t ~~~~~~~~~~~t and the optimum investment decision chosen by the country will coincide with the "maximum repayment" strategy designed in equation (17). (See Appendix 2, And Portes (1987) for a suggestion in the same spirit.) Provided that the non-performing asset is initially large enough, which amounts to assuming that D/Q > h with h a given threshold, this scheme can be shown to be repeated for ever and indeed deliver the "maximum repayment" scheme (see Appendix 2 for further details). If D/Q is below h , then the non-performing asset should be charged a larger interest rate until the face value of the debt reaches the h Q ceiling. It is crucial to note that this fictitious decomposition of the debt into a performing and a non-performing part is updated each period. Indeed, along equation (19) V* is only teft to grow at a rate (1+0) (l+s-d) which is the average growth rate of the economy. If things go well the actual growth rate will be larger and Vt+l must be scaled up; conversely, Vt+l will be scaled down if the bad state occurs. The second crucial remark to make is the following: the performing - 16 - asset is not calculated from the observation of the market value of the debt but from the theoretical computation of the maximum repayment scheme. Even though they do coincide at the equilibrium, it is crucial that the lenders do not let Pt depend upon the observed market value of Dt. Indeed, if they were to do so, they would ask to be repaid: Pt = 8 (X) [ (1*r) - (1+8) (1+x-d) t and tL. country would be induced to bring down the market value of the debt. Theme results can be summarized as follows: Proposition 2: When the debt to GDP ratio is above a floor value h*, the lenders can capture the "maximum repayment"' value V* by proceeding as follows. They should fictitiously split the debt into a performing and a non-performing component, the performing component being equal to V*. Each period, they should ask the borrower to service the performing component of the debt only, and let the performing component grow at a rate equal to the expected growth rate of the economy. Meanwhile the non-performing asset is automatically capitalized at the riskless rate. When the actual growth rate of the economy is above (below) its expected level, the performing part of the debt is scaled up (scaled down). When this rescheduling strategy is undertaken, the equilibrium market value of the debt is equal to V . - 17 - Now obviously, as time passes, the size of the non-performing asset grows relative to the performing one, and some write-off of the debt may become possible without impairiag the lenders' ability to capture V*t. One can actually show: Proposition 3: When the debt-to-GDP ratio is above the threshold h*, the debt can be written-down to h* CDP without impairing the lenders' return. If the write-off is repeated each time the economy goes into the bad state and if the rescheduling is undertaken according to Proposition 2, the lenders capture the "maximum repayment" while the market price of the debt is stabilized at a constant equilibrium price below par. One important implication of Proposition 3 is that it is not enough to observe a discount on the debt to warrant a write-off. The intuition is that hinted at in the introduction: the discount on the debt takes into account the possibility that the economy may go into a bad state. But lenders have no reason to write-off the debt before that prediction materializes. It is only in the deterministic case when u = v that the optimal strategy is indeed to write-off the debt "once and for all" (in order to erase whatever backward shocks may have lifted the debt-to-CDP ratio above h*) and let the debt be quoted at par. V. The "Debt Overhang" Problem Revisited In view of Proposition 2, it appears that the face value of the debt is of little importance in assessing the optimal rescheduling strategy of the - 18 - debt. This should come as no surprise: when they behave optimally, lenders get as much as the country can transfer and more nominal claim cannot imply less actual payments. (See also Bulow and Rogoff (1988).) This result, however, contradicts the "debt overhang" argument according to which too large a nominal claim may excessively discourage investment and reduce the market value of the debt. I would now like to indicate how these two conflicting views can be reconciled. A key feature of the optimal rescheduling strategy described in Proposition 2 is that lenders should let the performing asset grow at the expected growth rate of this economy. As apparent from equation (17) this implies that the service of the debt is negatively correlated with the investment decision of the borrower. Even though such behavior is in the lenders' self-interest, I now want to show that this is not a "time- consistent" decision, that is: it is a decision which is an optimal one to take only if the lenders can commit themselves (in whatever way: sophisticated contracting or a built-in reputation) to implement it later on. In order to see why such a commitment is necessary, assume instead that the lenders operate on a period-by-period basis and simply reschedule the debt each period to the best of their ability, taking for granted that they will do the same (and will be expected to do so) later on. Such a policy can be characterized as a "time-consistent" policy: it -is one which is found to be optimal to implement today, when it is expected to be implemented in the future. Since the work of Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Calvo (1978), it is well known that such a policy maybe intertemporally sub-optimal (even though it is pointwise optimal). Let us see what the outcome of such a "time-consistent" rescheduling strategy would be. - 19 - As shown in Cohen and Michel (1988) calculating a time-consistent policy simply amounts to finding a feed-back decision rule which, here, can be writtent ( 19 ) Pt , bQt in which b is the largest amount that the lenders can ask at time t #hen it is expected that future payments will be set according to another rule: (20) Pt+ b~ Qt.s which they take as given. A time consistent strategy is one for which, at the equilibrium, b - b. The equilibrium is calculated in Appendix 3. It is shown that the equilibrium growth rate is nothing else but the post-defauLt path and that b ) X In other words the "time-consistent" policy is simply one in which the lenders take every period the costs that the borrower would incur by defaulting and, as a result, their rescheduling strategy simply mimics the post-default path that the country could follow on its own. As apparent from equation (19) a time consistent rescheduling strategy act as a tax on outputs the borrower expects that the lenders will ask for as much as it can pay and this is an amount which, it can foresee, will be proportional to how much output it can generate. These expectations increase the shadow cost of capital in the debtor country and reduce investment immediately, making it optimal for the lenders to do what they are expected to: disregard the incentive to invest and ask for as much as they can. - 20 - It is this downward spiral that most people (I think) have in mind when discussing the debt overhang problem: debt acts as a tax which inefficiently discourages investment and less annual payment from the debtor would imply more overall income to the lenders. Under these circumstances, a write-off may help the lenders. In fact, a write-off cum a multi-year rescheduling can perform even better inasmuch as it helps the lenders commit theuselves to put an explicit ceiling on how much money they will ask for each period to come. It should be clear, however, that neither a write-off nor a multiyear rescheduling can help the lenders get the first best, unless, the rescheduling is made contingent upon the investment decision of the borrower. (See Appendix 4 for a formal proof of these statements). To summarize, one can state: Propomition 4: When the lenders reschedule the debt on a period-by-period basis, they induce the country to follow a growth pattern which exactly mimics the post-default path. The lenders capture each period the penalty that they could impose on the defaulting country. As a result they get more on a period- by-period basis, but less on average than under the "maximum repayment" scheme. Under such a ("time-consistent") rescheduling strategy, a write-off and a multi-year rescheduling may prove beneficial, but the gains necessarily fall short of the optimal strategy defined in Proposition 2. VI. Empirical Relevance of the "Debt Overhang" Problem Let us now investigate whether the "debt-overhang" problem is or not empirically relevant. - 21 - Krugman (1987) has suggested that we regard the "debt-overhang" as a "Debt Laffer Curve" problem, the question at hand being: does more nominal debt imply a lower market value for this debt? A test of the "debt overhang," according to this formulation, therefore amounts to deciding whether the elasticity of the market price of the debt with respect to its face value is strictly larger than one (in absolute value). Certainly if this elasticity is larger than one, then one can make the case that the lenders operate inefficiently. However, an elasticity equal to or smaller than one is not in itself sufficient to accept the hypothesis that the lenders reschedule the debt efficiently. In this section, we shall stick to Krugman's test, but certainly more work is needed in order to investigate the efficiency of the rescheduling process which has been undertaken since 1982. Previous attempts to measure the elasticity of the price of the debt with respect to its nominal value systematically found a low estimate. A study by Purcell and Orlanki, following a previous estimate by Sachs and Huizinga, reported an elasticity of 0.34. We have estimated an equation, representative of these earlier studies, as follows: (21) Log p = 5.06 - 0.653 log D/X - 2.231 A/D - 1.016 R/D (0.152) (0.603) (0.373) - 0.274 Dummy 1987.12 (0.132) B2 * 0.560 pooled equations for 1986.12 and 1987.12 data; 60 degrees of freedom. (Standard errors in parenthesis). p: price of the debt (cents on the dollar). D: debt; X: exports; A: arrears; RB amount of rescheduling since 1982. - 22 - From this equation, one would tend to reject at the 95 percent level of confidence that the elasticity of the debt was larger than one. Before comnenting on the insufficiency of such an equation, it is interesting to report that the price of the debt seems to be very poorly correlated to macroeconomic data related to the country. For instance, the most important of these macroeconomic data (one would guess), such as the non-interest current account or the domestic inflation rate, never appeared to be significantly correlated with the price. On the other hand, arrears or rescheduling data (as we can see from equation (21)) alurays perform extremely well. These rasults are summarized in diagrams 1 to 3. They tend to indicate that the market is extremely sensitive to the "punctuality" of payments and pay little attention to overall macroeconomic performance. Finally, one also sees from equation (21) that a dummy separating the 1986 and 1987 data appears to be significant. This may be a reflection of Citibank's decision to build up $3 billion of reserves against developing country exposure, a move which significantly influenced the market. Despite its appeal and its simplicity, an equation such as (21) is extremely misleading. First, it leads us to reject the hypothesis that the elasticity of the price with respect to debt is larger than one for the entire sample. But it may very well be the case that only a sub-group of countries was hit by the debt-overhang problem. Running, for instance, the same regression for the sub-sample of countries for which the debt-to-export ratio is larger than 3 (a sub-sample of 16 countries) would yield a larger elasticity, which we estimated to be at 1.183 (with a standard error of 0.339). Second, and perhaps more importantly, an equation such as (21) takes - 23 - the arrears and the rescheduling variables as exogeneous, while these variables obviously depend upon debt and perhaps upon the price itself. In order to overcome these two difficulties (to which one should also add a more technical one which is that the price being smaller than one hundred, log p cannot be normally distributad), we have estimated a reduced form equation in which the dependent variable has the logistic form log (p /100 - p), so as to let the elasticity depend upon the level of the price. The result comes as follows: (22) Log P u 2.152 - 1.509 log D/X lOO-P (0.318) (0.305) -0.048 X growth - 0.583 Dummy 87.12 (0.024) (0.288) *2 u 0.389; pooled equation for 1986.12 and 1987.12 data; 60 degrees of freedom; X growth: rate of growth of exports. According to this equation the elasticity of the pricw with respect to debt (100 - p) is 1.509 (with a standard error of 0.305). This indicates that the debt overhang problem could not be rejected at the 95 percent level degree of confidence for these countries in the sample for which the price was almost zero (such as Sudan). More generally, Table 1 indicates the countries for which the debt-overhang problem could not be rejected at various degrees of confidence. At the 90 percent level of confidence, only 4 countr-es pass the test. - 24 - Table 1 Countries with a Potential Debt Overhang Problem (as of 1987.12) At the 501 level of Argentina (34) confidence: p < 34 Jamaica (33) 1 Nigeria (29) At the 75X level of Dominican Republic (23) confidence: p c 23 Congo (23) Zaire (19) Zambia (17) Costa Rica (15) At the 90X level of Bolivia (11) confidence: p ! 11 Peru (7) Nicaragua (4) At the 951 level of confidence: p - o Sudan (2) (The numbers in parenthesis are secondary market prices in cents per dollar). Appendix 1. Optimal Growth in the (Totally) Open and In the Post-Default Economy Cases. A) The open economy case Prom equation (7), doubling QO would also double 0 so that one can look for * such as in equation (8). w is the solution to the following Bellman equation underlying the definition of W0 in equation (7): (Al.l) c Mnax { 1 - x (I + x) + @ r p(l + u) + (1 - p)(l * v)+ (1 * x - d)) - 25 - The equilibrium value of x is ;a1 (1*o -- (A1.2) s * I(i+@)+r , with 1 + 0 a p (lou) + (1-p)(l+v). We shall assume * to be positive. Equation (Al.I) yields that x is a solution to: (Al.3) 1 20 (A1.3) X x2 _ X Ir @_ + d) + O(l - t _ 0+e The solution that is socially efficient is: (AY.4)( + d) [I - VI (1-+- --i ) I which exists and is positive if: (Aoi5) in2(1 rc s ) /(hl as- s t o); l+ o a condition which we shall assume to hold. - 26 - B) The Post-Default Case Let us "guess" that the solution to equation (11) can indeed be written: (Al.6) Ud (QO) a C Q� Then the "guess" will prove to be the right one if (Al.7) C - Miz { [1-k-yly+ B p 1(14u) (lex-d))YCy+ B [ (l-p) (lv) (l+x-d) IYCYi By the envelope theorem, the derivative of the right - hand side is maller than one when B is small enough to induce the country to be in the borrowing side. Appendix 2: The "Maximum Repayment Scheme" Because of the linear structure of the model, one has to find b and s such that -b Q* b, x (1c+ r) *0 subject to to (IBt u [(1 - b - y ) Q )> Ud(Qo) t = o (The statinarity of the problem implies that this inequality, if it holds at time o, will also hold at later times). - 27 - CSll w (x) the solution to: (A2.1) a c(x)Qo Q * ,.,t 3lr)-lO)(1z^d) QO when the investment rate is x. The problem at hand is therefore simply that of finding: (A2.2) z* Max b w(x) b;x subject to: A2.3) 80 0 t (1 - b - y)Q Ud (Qo) Let A2.4) ut- B E I 8o 4 Ui)I (A2.3) can be written: (A2.5) �t p(I - b - y)Y (I + s - d) ty > U d(Qg By duality, maximizing z* in (A2.2) subject to (A2.5) amounts to finding z which is a solution to: ud ( QO) - Hex ! ut( 1 - Z* y)Y (I + s - ) tY - 28 - From the definition of w (x) - (1 + r) - (1 + e) (1 + x - d) in equation (A2.1), this amounts to asking the country to transfer: Pt abQt a Z (1 + r) - (1 + 8) (1 + s - d) Q in which x is freely chosen by the country so as to maximize its utility. Since Ud (Qo) = 6 Pt (1 - A - Yd)Y(l d5 one can see from (A2.5) that bt< A and x > x The investment rate is larger under the optimal scheme than under default. Agpendix 3: The Time Consistent Path For equation (17), the lenders want to induce the country to repay in each period: (A3.1) Pt m Z ((l + r) -(1 + )(1 + * - d)] Qt in which z and x are the optimal choice defined in Proposition 1. Let us show that Proposition 2 solves this problem when h* is defined as (A3.2) h* = ^* (1 + r) - (1 * x - d) (1 + e) (1 + r) - (1 + x - d) (1 + u) - 29 - and when the price of the debt is (A3.3) q* ,( + r) -(I + zs M )l + u) (1 + r) - (1 + x - d)(l + 0) If (A3.1) and (A3.3) are satisfied, the market value of the debt is Z Qt (the maximum value) and Proposition 2 indicates that the borrower should repay Pt so that, when measured in market terms, the debt grows at the rate (1 + ) (1 + x - d). This implies that Pt must be such that q D5 1 (I + r) q Dt Pt a q Dt (1 + )( + X - d) so that ? *[(l + r) - (1 + e)( + *x - d)| Qt Given this rule of the game, the country must: Naxi idze ' ( 1 + x J)t Y { (1 - z ((1 + r) - (1 + x - d)] - y P 0 which is exactly the problem at hand in Appendix 2. Appendix 4: MYRAs and Write-Offs a In order to see how a multi-year rescheduling agreement associated with a write-off can help time-consistent lenders, let us restrict the analysis to the deterministic case when u = v. Assume that the lenders are trapped into the tim-consistent strategy by which they are expected to (and indeed do) levy Pt-b t each period. Assume that they reschedule the debt on - 30 - a long run basis so as to let each period's payment falling due equal: t with g being some exogenous growth rate. The country now must: (A-l) Max B u [Qt- J Pt] and one sees that the disincentive to growth is eliminated (inasmuch as the borrwer takes Pt as not contingent upon Qt). Clearly there exists a value of Po and g for which the equilibrium growth rate of the economy coincides with g and for which the borrower is exactly indifferent between servicing the debt and defaulting. For this equilibrium one finds that lenders raise the value of their claim above the time-consistent pay-off (to the extent that the disencentive to grow has been eliminated) but fall short of the first best strategy (to the extent that the incentive to grow has not been optimally designed). In order to require (A4.1), the lenders must therefore write off part of the debt below the "maximum repayment" value. - 31 - References Bulow, J. and K. Rogoff "A Constant Reconstracting Model of Sovereign Debt", forthcoming Journal of International Economics. Calvo, G. (1988) On the Time Consistences of Optimal Policy in a Monetary Economy," Econmetrica no. 6. Claeesens, S. (1988) "The Debt-Laffer Curve: Some Estimates" World Bank, mimeo. Cohen, D. (1988) "The Inefficiency of Private Lending to Sovereign States" forthcoming in a volume in honor of E. Malin+ajid edited by Crandmont, Laroque and Monfort. Cohen, D. and P. Michel (1988) "How Should Control Theory be used to Calculate a Time Consistent Policy" Review of Economic Studies, March. Cohen, D. and J. Sachs (1986) "Growth and External Debt Under Risk of Debt Repudiation," European Economic Review, vol 30, pp. 529-550. Corden, Max (1988) "Debt Relief and Adjustment Incentives: A Theoretical Exploration," Mimeo, IMF. Dooley, M. (1987) "Market Discounts and the Valuation of Alternative Structures for External Debt," IMP, Mimeo. Dornbusch, R. "Our LDC Debts," in The United States and the World EconomY edited by M. Feldstein Universy of Chicago Press. Eaton, J. and M. Cersovitz "Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical (1981) and Empirical Analysis" Review of Economic Studies, March. Cenotte, C., H. Kharas "A Valuation Model for Developing - Country Debt and S. Sadeq (1987) with Endogenous Rescheduling," World Bank Egonomic Review, January. Helpman, E. (1988) "Debt Relief: Incentives and Welfare," Mimeo. Kruguan, Paul (1987) "Financing vs Forgiving a Debt Overhang: Some Analytical Rates," Mimeo, MIT. Kydland, P. and E. Prescott "Rules rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency (1977) of Optimal Plans," Journal of Political Economy, no 3. - 32 - Portes, R. "Debt and the Market," Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Purcell, J. and D. Orlanki "Developing Countries Loans: A New Valuation Model (1968) for Secondary Market Trading," June. Corporate Bond Research, Solomon Brother Inc. SAchs, Jeffrey (1988) "The Debt Overhang of Developing Countries," in de Macedo and Findlay (ed.), Debt, Growth and Stabilization: Essays in Memory of Carlos Diaz Alejandro. Oxford, Blackwell, 1988. Sachs, J. and H. Huizinga (1987) "US Comercial Banks and the Developing - Country Debt Crisis," Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, no 2. PPR Working Paper Series Title Author Date Contact WPS114 Africa Region Population Projections 1988-89 edition My T. Vu October 1988 S. Ainsworth Eduard Bos 31091 Rodolfo A. Bulatao WPSIIS Asia Region Population Projections 1988-89 edition My T. Vu October 1988 S. Ainsworth Eduard Bos 31091 Rodolfo A. Bulatao WPS116 Latin America and the Caribbean Region Population Projections 1988-89 edition My T. Vu October 1988 S. Ainsworth Eduard Bos 31091 Rodolfo A. Bulatao WPS117 Europe, Middle East, and North Africa (EMN) Region Population Projections 1988-89 edition My T. Vu October 1988 S. Alnswqrth Eduard Boa 31091 Rodolfo A. Bulatao WPSI18 Contract-Plans and Public Enterprise Performance John Nellis October 1988 R. Malcolm 61707 WPS119 Recent Developments In Commodity Modeling: A World Bank Focus Walter C. Labys October 1988 A. Daruwala 33716 WPS120 Public Policy and Private Investment In Turkey Ajay Chhlbber October 1988 A. Bhalla Sweder van Wijnbergen 60359 WPS121 Commercial Bank Provisioning Against Claims on Developing Countries Graham Bird October 1988 1. Holloman-Willi 33729 WPS122 Import Demand In Developing Countries Riccardo Faini November 1988 K. Cabana Lant Pritchett 61539 Fernando Clavljo .PS123 Export Supply, Capacity and Relative Prices Riccardo Faini November 1988 K. Cabana 61539 PPR Working Paper Series Title Author Date Contact WPS124 International Macroeconomic Adjustment, 1987-1992: A World Model Approach Robert E. King November 1988 K. Adams Helena Tang 33738 WPS125 The Effects of Financial Liberaliza- tion on Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines Christophe Chamley October 1988 A. Bhalla Qalzar Hussain 60359 WPS126 Educating Managers for Business and Goverment: A Review of International Experience Samuel Paul November 1988 E. Madrona John C. Ickis 61711 Jacob Levitsky WPS127 Linking Development, Trade, and Debt Strategies In Highly Indebted Countries Ishac Diwan November 1988 1. Diwan 33910 WPS128 Public Finances in Adjustment Programs Ajay Chhibber J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi WPS129 Women In Development: Defining the Issues Paul Collier WPS130 Maternal Educatlon and the Vicious Circle of High Fertility and Mal- nutrition: An Analytic Survey Matthew Lockwood Paul Collier WPS131 Implementing Direct Consumption Taxes In Developing Countries George R. Zodrow Charles E. McLure, Jr. WPS132 Is the Discount on the Secondary Market A Case for LDC Debt Relief? Daniel Cohen November 1988 M. Luna 33729 WPS133 Lewis Through a Looking Glass: Public Sector Employment, Rent-Seaking and Economic Growth Alan Gelb November 1988 A. Hodges J.B. Knight 61268 R.H. Sabot