WF5 tibl POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1967 Agriculture and the This paper surveys the literature on the interaction Macroeconomy between agriculture and the macroeconomy in both industrial and developing Maurice Schiff Alberto Valdeis countnes, identifying what the authors believe to represent its most significant contributions and shortcomings. The World Bank Development Research Group Trade and Rural Development Department U August 1998 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1967 Summary findings Based on an economywide perspective, this paper begins Dutch Disease phenomenon and agriculture. The paper wvith a discussion of the bias against exports and next examines the influence of interest rates on agriculture that characterized the economic literature and incentives in agriculture, arguing that, surprisingly, this the development strategies in many developing countries has been a neglected area in the literature. after World War II. This is followed by an analysis of The paper explores the effects on agriculture of how the macroeconomic environment affects agricultural structural adjustment programs implemented since the price incentives. Specifically, the paper discusses how early 1980s in developing countries. The final section policies concerning industrial protection, exchange rates, surveys the literature on agriculture and the and interest rates and other fiscal policies can strongly macroeconomy in industrial countries, focusing on the influence the economic incentives for agriculture impact of the exchange rate on export competitiveness in compared with other sectors, identifying the most the United States, the cost of agricultural protection for relevant literature and alternative approaches used on the overall economy in Europe and Japan, and the this issue. It then proceeds to examine how the real increased importance of fluctuations in money markets exchange rate can be affected by exogenous shocks, such for the farm sector and the additional instability they as the foreign terms of trade, with emphases on the generate. This paper - a joint product of Trade, Development Research Group, and the Rural Development Department- will be published in B. Gardner and G. Rausser, eds., Handbook of Agricultural Economics, North Holland Publishers. Copies of this paper are available free frorm the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Alberto Vald6s, room S8-015, telephone 202-473-5491, fax 202-522-3307, Internet address avaldesCa?worldbank.org. Maurice Schiff may be contacted at mschiff Aworldbank.org. August 1998. (37 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective ofthe series is to get the findings oat quickly, eveni ifthe presentations are less than fnuly polished. The papers carry the names o/the authors and should be cited accordin,,ly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this I paper are entirely those of the authors. They do 7not necessarily represent the viewv of the World Bank, its Execudtive Directors, or the coontries they represenlt. Produced bv the Policy Research Dissemination Center Elsevier Science Handbook of Agricultural Economics Ed. by B. Gardner and G. Rausser Agriculture and the Macroeconomy Maurice Schiff and Alberto Valdes World Bank Introduction Until the mid-1980s, most analysts of agricultural policies were preoccupied with the direct effects of sectoral pricing and trade policies on output, resource use, and income distribution. Since that time, however, a number of analyses have suggested that the indirect effects of economy-wide policies on agricultural incentives have been greater than the impact of policies directed specifically toward agriculture. Conversely, in some cases, agricultural policies have had significant effects on macroeconomic variables. This chapter surveys literature on the relationship and interaction between agriculture and the macroeconomy, in both developing and industrialized countries. It presents an organized discussion of this literature, identifying what the authors believe to represent the most significant contributions and shortcomings of the existing scholarship on agricultural economics. We begin with a discussion of the bias against exports and agriculture that characterized development economics following the Second World War and the decolonization of many developing countries. During this time, export pessimism drove the shift from agriculture toward industry, and the substitution of imported industrial products with domestically produced goods. This substitution occurred irrespective of comparative advantage or disadvantage. The effects of import-substituting policies on agricultural incentives and economic growth were profound. A reorientation towards more open economies followed, beginning in South America in the mid-1970s, and becoming more profound in the mid-1980s. The changes were influenced by trade and development economists who began to investigate the potential contribution that opening the trade regime could make to overall economic growth. In an analysis of agricultural incentives from an economy-wide perspective, it was found that the "indirect" effects of macroeconomic and industrial policies were no less important to agriculture than the "direct" sector-specific agricultural policies. Two key relationships were central in this analysis: the relative price of agricultural to non- agricultural products, and the price of tradable to non-tradable (or "home") goods, i.e. the real exchange rate. We examined the factors that determine the equilibrium real rate of exchange, and that shift actual exchange rates toward equilibrium. These factors include both policy-induced domestic forces (such as changes in technology and productivity), and exogenous international forces (like changes in a country's foreign terms of trade). Exogenous factors include the relative prices of a country's imports and exports (its terms of trade) and the variables that go into determining them. One of the determinants is an export commodity boom (in some cases resulting in "Dutch disease" phenomenon), whose effect on other tradables has proven to be profound. Foreign capital flows are also significant in determining exchange rates, the price of inputs, and the cost of borrowing money. We discuss below the importance of interest rates to these capital flows, as well as their effects on agricultural investment itself. We then explore the effects of structural adjustment programs. These began during the 1 970s, and gained currency throughout the developing world during the 1 980s, as countries sought to correct their macroeconomic imbalances, especially overvalued exchange rates, that resulted from years of industrial protection and budget deficits. In the final section, we compare and contrast the experience of the industrialized "North," where agriculture accounts for a far lower proportion of national incomes and economic growth, to that of the developing "South", where substantially greater levels of exchange rate misalignment and industrial protection have imposed severe indirect taxation on agriculture. In stark contrast to the Southern experience, Northern agriculture enjoyed substantial protection even while industrial protection declined over time. We explore the macroeconomic implications of agricultural protection in the North for international prices and agricultural competitiveness, giving special attention to US agricultural tradables and the European Community's experience under the Common Agricultural Policy. Development Strategies in the South After World War II: A Historical Perspective The historical setting in which countries conceived and implemented development strategies in the decades following World War II is an appropriate place to start. The central issue of the time was finding and then cultivating a developing economy's "lead" sector, the sector capable of serving as its "engine of growth". This "engine" would presumably provide the income necessary to nourish and sustain economic development, while fostering a self-reliance that would prevent a society from depending upon international market forces that were outside a small country's capacity to affect. Economists recalled the collapse of primary commodity markets during the Depression, and of the disruptions in these markets during the Second World War. Their fear of such dependency led many development economists to ally themselves with what became known in economics as the "structuralist school" and "dependency theory." The sector which seemed capable of providing the "engine", particularly in the aftermath of the colonial experience, was industry. Agriculture was viewed, by many, as the station of the colony, the provider of primary products demanded by industrial countries. Persisting in this peripheral role would be tantamount to a defacto perpetuation of colonialism, hence the term neo-colonialism. But the nationalistic impulse among developing countries, many of which were newly independent, was not alone in leading many in the developing world to spurn agriculture and to discount its potential contribution to economic growth. Agrarian society by its very nature was regarded as socially and economically backward, governed by tradition, impervious to market signals, and devoid of links to other sectors that could bring the benefits of progress in agricultural production to the economy as a whole.' Another concern was the perceived secular decline in real agricultural prices which was blamed on an inelastic demand for agricultural products. The assumption was that the shift in the supply of agricultural products over time associated with technical progress was larger than the shift in demand. On the other hand, Martin and Warr (1993) and Gelhar et al. (1994) have argued that Rybczynski effects associated with the accumulation of capital in the process of growth result in a shift of resources away from the labor-intensive sector (agriculture) to the capital-intensive one (industry), which should dampen the negative effects on relative agricultural prices. 2 The academic acceptance of these presumptions without proper empirical evidence, and the overwhelming pre-eminence that scholars afforded industrial policy as a result, represented a monumental failure on the part of development economists. The illogic of this course was characterized succinctly by Theodore W. Schultz at the beginning of Transforming Traditional Agriculture (1964), when he wrote that "economists who have been studying growth have, with few exceptions, put agriculture aside in order to concentrate on industry, despite the fact that every country has an agriculture sector and in low-income countries it is generally the largest sector." Schultz' work set into motion an academic reexamination of the anti-export, anti-agricultural prejudice of dependency doctrine that would ultimately provide many of the theoretical underpinnings of the policy realignments of the 1980s. The preoccupation with the limits of traditional and subsistence agriculture that was so characteristic of structuralists and dependency literature led to a neglect of agriculture in general. The fear of depending on agricultural exports led to a neglect of the potential contributions export revenues might deliver to growing, capital-starved economies. And yet, one of the outstanding attributes shared by nearly all developing countries was that their exports were overwhelmingly agricultural. Another attribute shared by most developing countries was that their imports were, in large measure, industrial products. The unfortunate alternative to pursuing productivity gains in exportables was to replace imports with products made domestically. The prescription of import-substituting industrialization followed from the structural and dependency doctrines' assumptions about agriculture. The reasoning was that if industry lacked competitive advantage, it must be fostered artificially. The industry must be shielded from powerful foreign competitors by import barriers until it became capable of competing, regardless of whether or not this was a realistic expectation. Whatever costs had to be incurred by other sectors, including agriculture, to pay for this protection were justified on these grounds. The costs of this protection were felt widely across entire economies, with disastrous effects on growth. One theory that had a significant impact on economic policy was that of "balanced growth," articulated by Rosenstein-Rodan (1943) and Ragner Nurkse (1952). They predicted that rapid growth in developing economies would not be achieved through increased exports of primary commodities, and argued that development strategies should place greater emphasis on industrialization. Recognizing the limits imposed by the small size of domestic markets, balanced growth theory prescribed the simultaneous promotion of a variety of different industries in a way that would foster complementary demand among those industries for one another's products. A central premise in Rosenstein-Rodan and Nurkse's work (as well as that of Ranis-Fei, A. Lewis, and others), was the assumption that a large surplus of labor was employed at zero marginal product in rural areas. This surplus would prevent labor bottlenecks from occurring that might otherwise constrain balanced growth. Underlying the concept of a balanced growth path was the perception that resources for investment were severely limited. This, coupled with the 3 belief that a certain minimum level of investment was required to capture the external economies of sectoral growth and move a country to a higher growth path, was the "big push" advocated by Rosenstein-Rodan (1943, 1957). And it was here that the debate over where resources should be concentrated came to a choice between agriculture and industry. The "structuralist school," embodied in the works of Prebisch (1950), Singer (1950), and Myrdal (1957), drew similar conclusions, strongly emphasizing the forces which limited demand for primary products. The structuralist view, prevalent at the time, was that agriculture in general, and the traditional agriculture that was characteristic of developing economies in particular, was slow and weak in its response to market signals, owing to such constraints as imperfect factor mobility.2 Pessimism about the potential of agricultural exports to "lead" economic development was based on a number of factors (Valdes, 1991). Agricultural exports tended to consist of a small number of commodities, more reliant on natural resources as inputs than other commodities. For this reason, the agricultural sector was perceived as having few or weak linkages with the rest of the economy, and thus unable to serve as an "engine of growth." Demand for many of these primary commodities was presumed to be inelastic, both with respect to their prices and to income. It was argued that dependence on a few export commodities implied that import capacity would be determined by the prices of these commodities on the international market, making income subject to boom-bust cycles which governments could do little or nothing about. There were those who felt that the lack of control over foreign exchange earnings made outward-oriented development strategies seem irresponsible. Given that many countries were indeed experiencing declining demand for their primary agricultural products (Meier, 1989), it is perhaps not surprising that these ideas camne to profoundly influence the formulation of development strategies in many developing countries. In the 1 950s, these countries began pursuing higher economic growth through policies of import-substituting industrialization. High import tariffs and concessional credit lines favored industry, while low import tariffs and relatively high export taxes on agricultural products revealed the extent to which the prevailing export pessimism was embraced by Third World policy-makers. Resources had to be purposefully channeled to the non-farm sectors which were thought capable of contributing to and sustaining faster growth within the overall economy. Agriculture in this view was there to serve simply as a resource base. 2 The belief that agricultural output was not responsive to changes in price was also propounded in industrialized countries. This arose from the experiences of the US during the Depression (1919-22 and 1929-33), as articulated by Galbraith (1938). However, D.G. Johnson (1950) disputed the validity of this hypothesis as applied to the Depression, and also disputed its applicability during times of full employment. 4 As understandable as the popularity of the structuralist school was, their emphasis on factors that would limit the demand for primary products led them to discount the possible benefits that opening new markets for new primary products might have. Moreover, the assumption that agriculture had few and weak linkages to the rest of the economy caused structuralists to disregard these linkages in their strategy. In fact, little empirical evidence was produced regarding the strength or extent of the interrelationship between agriculture and the larger economy (Valdes, 1991). Beginning in the early 1960s, the structuralist and dependency-theory schools faced increasing criticism. Schultz's Transforming Traditional Agriculture, and pioneering cross-country studies on trade policy and development by Little, Scitovsky, and Scott (1970), Anne Krueger and Jagdish Bhagwati (1978), and Bela Balassa (1982), argued that in terms of both growth performance and employment generation, export- oriented development strategies had performed better than import-substituting ones during the post-World War II period. By the mid- 1 980s, developing countries had grown increasingly disillusioned with import-substituting strategies, and a major reorientation has been taking place ever since. The new approach involves a more open economy, and recognizes the active role that agriculture can play as a major tradable sector in most developing countries. The Macroeconomic Environment and Agricultural Price Incentives Governments affect agriculture directly through sector-specific measures including tariffs, input and credit subsidies, price controls, quantitative restrictions (QRs), and government expenditures and taxes. Indirectly, government policies often have unintended effects on agriculture. Policies concerning industrial protection, exchange rates and interest rates, and other fiscal and monetary policies can strongly influence the incentives for agriculture vis-a-vis other sectors. For example, border protection has often been used to protect domestic manufacturing, and restrictive trade policies, accompanied by fiscal deficits, often result in exchange rate misalignment. Agriculture is also affected indirectly by exogenous changes in the world prices of non-agricultural commodities, such as oil and minerals, and by foreign capital flows. Because sectoral growth is affected by resource flows between sectors, and because these flows adjust to the relative opportunities offered by different sectors over time, an economy-wide view of returns is necessary for understanding the dynamics of agricultural growth and employment. Traditionally, agricultural economics has defined the effect of economic policies on incentives in terms of the nominal tariff, or sometimes the tariff equivalent (incltiding QRs), faced by agriculture, or what we referred to above as "direct" price interventions. Alternatively, in a general equilibrium framework, agricultural incentives could be defined in terms of the relative price of agricultural to non-agricultural products. The difference between the two concepts lies in the definition and the measurement of price 5 interventions. Most studies have taken the price of the non-agricultural sector as given, and have restricted their analysis to the effects of sectoral or direct policie, on agricultural prices. Some studies did adjust for exchange rate misalignment, generally employing nominal exchange rates (we will argue below that the real exchange rate is more appropriate). For examples of the nominal exchange rate adjustment approach, see Valdes (1973). Taylor and Phillips (1991), Byerlee and Sain (1986), and Lattimore and Schuh, (1979). Agriculture's ability to compete for resources domestically and globally is directly affected by economy-wide policies. These policies have important effects on relative agricultural prices through the real exchange rate and the price of non-agricultural tradable activities. We proceed below with a discussion of nominal and real exchange rates, followed by a description of the evolution of our understanding of how macroeconomic policies affect agricultural incentives. The remainder of the section discusses, in turn, exogenous effects (in particular export-commodity booms), interest rates, and structural adjustment programs. The Real Exchange Rate There are two major concepts of the exchange rate, namely the nominal and the real rates. The nominal rate is an undeflated conversion factor between one currency and another. It corresponds to the exchange rate a government can announce or fix. The nominal equilibrium rate is the rate at which the demand and supply of foreign exchange (to finance both current account and autonomous capital account transactions) are equal for a given set of trade taxes. The purchasing power parity (PPP) relates the purchasing power of one currency to that of another, by adjusting the nominal rate for relative inflation. Neither the PPP nor the nominal equilibrium rate necessarily imply an optimum exchange rate, nor do they correspond to the shadow price of foreign exchange used in social project evaluation. The PPP is considered to be misaligned when its value differs from the base period value. The concept of effective exchange rate, a commodity-specific rate that expresses the price of foreign exchange including all import or export taxes, is useful in analyzing individual activities. In contrast, the real exchange rate (RER) is a relative price that reflects the competitiveness of the tradable sector (import substitutes and exportables). The RER varies according to the definition used (e.g., with respect to the deflator). Following Salter (1959), Swan (1960), Dornbusch (1974), and others, the RER introduces the concept of a home goods (or non-tradable) sector. A key factor on which the distinction between tradables and non-tradables is based is their price-formation mechanism. Both prices and quantities of home goods are determined by domestic supply and demand. In contrast, for small open economies, the domestic prices of tradables are determined by world markets together with the nominal exchange rate, trade taxes, and subsidies. 6 The various definitions of the RER that are used in agricultural economics literature have resulted in some confusion.3 One version is the purchasing power parity index mentioned above. Most early studies that attempted to measure the impact of the RER on agricultural incentives used the PPP approach (for example, Valdes, 1973; Binswanger and Scandizzo, 1983, and more recently Byerlee and Sain, 1986). There are at least three problems with the PPP concept of the RER. The first is the possibility that the base period RER may be misaligned as a result of macroeconomic disequilibrium. Secondly, even if the RER is in equilibrium in the base period, there is no reason to assume that this equilibrium will remain unchanged over time, owing to such factors as changes in the terms of trade and international interest rates. Thirdly, the base period PPP is obtained under given trade policy distortion, while we are interested in the equilibrium RER that would prevail in the absence of trade policy distortions. This requires a model of RER determination not found in the PPP adjustment. A now widely accepted definition of the real exchange rate is the ratio of the price of tradables to non-tradables: (1) RER = P7 PNY in which PT is the price of tradables and PNT is the price of non-tradables. The RER can serve as a proxy for a country's international competitiveness (Edwards, 1988). An increase in the RER (a depreciation) represents an improvement in the country's international competitiveness given relative prices in the rest of the world. Conversely, a decrease in the RER (an appreciation) indicates a decline in the country's international competitiveness. Changes in the RER can occur as a result of policy-induced effects that reflect a misalignment in the RER, and as a result of exogenous factors that reflect a change in the equilibrium value of the RER. In empirical estimation, the RER is often proxied as (2) RER = E where Eo is the nominal exchange rate, expressed as local currency per unit of foreign currency, P* is the foreign price index for tradables (often approximated by the wholesale price index), and P is the domestic price index, presumably heavily weighted by the home goods sector (as with the consumer price index). It is important to clarify the concept of equilibrium RER (ERER). Several conceptual and empirical definitions of the ERER are used in the literature, including the PPP. Edwards (1988) defined the ERER as that level of RER at which the economy is 3 See Hinkle and Nsengumiva (1995) for a detailed discussion on the various definitions of the real exchange rate. 7 accumulating or decumulating foreign assets at the "desired rate," and at which the demand for domestic goods equals supply. This definition can be refined to consider an ERER for a given trade policy regime, such as the ERER that would prevail under free trade. An important feature of this definition is its treatment of the ERER as a general equilibrium concept. Edwards' calculation was based on the idea of "macroeconomic fundamentals", and provides a useful framework for the discussion at hand. The "macroeconomic fundamentals" that determine the RER can be divided into external and internal factors. The internal factors can be divided into those influenced by policy decisions, and those that are exogenous to policy. Domestic policy variables include import tariffs and export taxes, quantitative restrictions on imports and exports, exchange and capital controls, other taxes and subsidies, and the level and composition of government expenditure.4 Domestic effects that are exogenous to domestic policies include productivity changes and teclmological progress, among others. External factors include international prices, international transfers (such as private capital flows and foreign aid), and world real interest rates. Changes in any of the variables will have an impact on the level of the RER, and most will affect the level of the ERER. For example, an increase in the world price of importables relative to exportables (i.e. a deterioration of the terms of trade) reduces the quantity of importables demanded, and induces a change in the level of the ERER (the direction of the change is ambiguous due to the negative income effect). An increase in import tariffs will have a similar effect on the domestic relative price of importables, reducing the quantity of importables demanded, anid resulting in demand switching to non-tradables and exportables. This in turn exerts upward pressure on the price of non- tradables, causing the ERER to shift downwards (i.e. to appreciate), given the existing trade policy regime and other determinants. Sustainable, or permanent, increases in government expenditure can also cause the ERER to decrease, owing to the increase in aggregate demand. Even if increases in government spending are financed through taxes, the ERER may appreciate due to the public sector's higher propensity to spend on non- tradables (such as labor). The ERER is, therefore, not a constant, but follows a discernible trend, a fact of critical importance when considering the effects of policy decisions. Elbadawi (1994), for instance, found India's ERER from 1967 to 1981 not only close to the actual RER, but that the ERER depreciated along with the actual RER. This does not imply that the rupee 4 Williamson (1994) pointed out that the evidence for the relevance of the composition of government expenditure was weak. Both Edwards (1994) and Elbadawi (1994) included it as a variable in estimating ERERs. In Williamson's view, the size of government expenditure was the important factor, not its composition. 8 was not overvalued, but simply that the actual depreciation was just sufficient to offset the reduction in protection, leaving the margin of overvaluation almost unaffected. Conversely, changes in the RER do not necessarily reflect disequilibrium. For example, technological progress in the production of importables (which will result in an improvement in the foreign terms of trade), or increased capital inflows, will both result in an appreciation of the RER. Insofar as the changes in these factors are permanent, the ERER will also appreciate. While the ERER is determined by real variables, the actual RER responds to both real and monetary variables. Typically, the RER is misaligned when the monetary and fiscal policies in place are inconsistent with the chosen nominal exchange rate regime. When the nominal exchange rate is fixed, any increase in domestic credit that exceeds growth in the domestic demand for money (i.e. expansive monetary policy) will result in excess demand for both tradables and non-tradables. Excess demand for tradables translates into higher trade deficits, loss of international reserves, and/or higher net foreign borrowing, none of which affect domestic prices. Excess demand for non-tradables results in higher prices, and thus appreciation of the RER. If this appreciation is not the result of equilibrium changes in the macroeconomic variables, it implies a deviation of the actual RER from its equilibrium value. It is also possible to construct another estimate of misalignment by comparing the ERER under the conditions of free trade to the actual RER. This construction was used by Schiff and Valdes (1992) in computing the indirect effect of trade and macroeconomic policies on agricultural incentives. Policy-Induced Effects In order to examine the impact of policy on agricultural incentives, we examine the impact on the value added among agricultural goods relative to that among non- agricultural goods. Both types of goods can be divided into tradables and home goods, i.e. VA A /VAA, + (1 )VAA,, VANA a VA1,, + (1-a) VA,,, where VA A is value added in the agricultural sector, VA NA is valued added in the non- agricultural sector, and VA, is value added in the non-agricultural tradable (or industrial) sector. The subscripts T and H refer to tradable and home (non-tradable) goods; respectively. Since most agricultural goods are tradable, the value of D is usually taken to be very close to one. The expression simplifies to the following form, 9 (4) VAA VAA a VANA a VA1 + (I - a) VAH This can be re-written as: (5) VAA VAA/VAH a < 1. VANA a VAI / VAH + ( - a) Many studies use relative prices instead of value added, in which case the expression becomes: (6) PA PA/PH a