SWP344 Januarv 1985 Intemational Technology Transfer: M!>-;B,RY Issues and Policy Options ,a r 3C w- Frances Stewart WORLD BANK STAFF WORKING PAPERS Number 344 2 f Pry h WORLD BANK STAFF WORKING PAPERS Number 344 International Technology Transfer: .Issues and Policy Options Frances Stewart The World Bank Washington, D.C., U.S.A. Copyright (i1979 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/THE WORLD BANK 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States of America First printing July 1979 Second printing January 1985 This is a working document published informally by the World Bank. To present the results of research with the least possible delay, the typescript has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formal printed texts, and the World Bank accepts no responsilbility for errors. The publication is supplied at a token charge to defray part of the cost of manufacture and distribution. The World Bank does not accept responsibility for the views expressed herein, which are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank or to its affiliated organizations. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions are the results of research supported by the Bank; they do not necessarily represent official policy of the Bank. The designations employed, the presentation of material, and any maps used in this document are solely for the convenience of the reader and do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the World Bank or its affiliates concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city, area, or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its boundaries, or national affiliation. The full range of World Bank publications, both free and for sale, is described in the Catalog of Publications; the continuing research program is outlined in Abstracts of Current Studies. Both booklets are updated annually; the most recent edition of each is available without charge from the Publications Sales Unit, Department T, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, N.W, Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A., or from the European Office of the Bank, 66 avenue d'I&ia, 75116 Paris, France. When this paper was first published Frances Stewart was a member of the Development Economics Department of the World Bank. ISBN 0-8213-9219-0 ABSTRACT This paper surveys the issues raised by technology transfer to developing countries. Technology is a vital part of the development process, a necessary input into all activity. Because of the historical domination of research and development by developed countries, a very large part of the technology used is transferred from developed countries. The transfer raises four major issues: those of the costs of the transfer, the appropriateness of products and techniques which are transferred, the effects of the transfer on learning and technological development in LDCs, and the effects on independence. The paper considers the consequence of the transfer and the range of policies that might be adopted, nationally and internationally, in relation to each of these issues. It is argued that the appropriate policies will vary according to the stage of development of each country, its technological capacity and its own objectives. However, in general it is concluded that an active technology policy is called for if the costs associated with technology transfer are to be reduced and the benefits increased. While it is easy to design suitable policies on paper, it is much more difficult to ensure that they are effective in practice. TABLE OF CONFENTS SUMMARY vii I. Why Technology is Transferred 2 II. Transfer Mechanisms 11 III. Significant Dimensions of Technology Transfer 20 IV. Costs of Techrnology Transfer 23 Technology Transfer and Independence 37 Learning Effects of Technology Transfer 39 V. Policies Towards the Import -f Technology 46 Economic Strategy and Technology Policy 48 Policies Towiards The Terms of Transfer 52 Promotion of Technological Accumulation 61 Administration 73 Aspects of Political Economy 75 VI. Thc Characteristics of Technology 78 Policies to Secure More Appropriate Technology 86 Infonnation 94 The Devel.opment of Appropriate Technology 97 VII. Some Conclusions 101 LIST OF REFERENCES 109 - vii - SUMJARY Technology is knowledge of how to do all those things associated with economic activity. Thus, the acquisition of technology is as important to the development process and as essential an aspect of the process of investment as the accumulation of financial resources. Moreover, because technology is continuously changing, with new products and processes being developed year-by-year, the need to acquire technology is also a continuous one, and one that expands with expansion in economic activity. Two basic facts underlie the process of international technology transfer. First, the origin of the vast majority of technological develop- ments is concentrated in a few developed countries. Although some developing countries are beginning to promote local technological development, they remain dependent on tlhe developed countries for most of their technology. Secondly, a large part of the market for technology has been commercialized with proprietary rights acquired in the technology. Since technology has many of the characteristics of a public good, such that the marginal cost of communicating it to others is very low com- ared with the initial costs of development, the commercialization of the technology market has involved imposing restrictions - legal and other - on the free communication of know- ledge. The result is that the technology market is highly imperfect, the price charged for technology tends to be oligopolistic, and consequently there is considerable scope for abuse,and potential for bargaining on the part of buyers. The transfer of technology consists, in part, in the transfer of the required knowledge; in part, in the transfer of various marketing rights associated withl the knowledge. These include the right to use trademarks, access to specified markets, and so on. In many cases, the two are inextricably connected, so that if a buyer wishes to purchase the knowledge he also has to purchase the m.arket rights, and vice-versa. - viii - Teclhnology is transferred in a number of different forms, ranging from formal (technology contracts) to informal (meetings, people changing jobs). The process is often differentiated according to the degree of packaging involved in the transfer with the most packaged transfers consist.r.g of the bundle of services associated with direct foreign investment, and the least packaged in the direct purchase of machinery and other inputs. There are various intermediate forms including joint ventures and contracts involving associated management services *and knowhow. In any particular case, the mechanism of transfer depends on the willingness of the supplier to supply the technology in different forms and the desire and ability of the buyer to buy it in a particular form. There is considerable variation in the way different countries acquire technology reflecting differences in national policies, in national capacities and in the industrial composition of the technology transferred. In some countries, e.g., historically Jartn and currently the Andean Pact countries, the most packaged forms of technology transfer, notably direct foreign investmene, are severely restricted. The degree of development influences the extent of packaging because less developed countries may lack the capacity to put the package together for themselves. In general, more sophisticated (technologically) industries show a greater degree of packaging than less sophisticated. Despite recent support by some LDCs for less packaging, no definite worldt-ide trends towards depackaging can be discerned empirically. Developing countries' objectives towards technology transfer have evolved. Immediately following independence, most countries were keen to industralize quickly, and to maximize the technology inflow. Hence, they introduced a host of tax incentives to encourage teclnology inflow. As time - ix - proceeded, it emerged that the indiscriminate import of technology nad involved high costs, had led to dualistic patterns of development, had accentuated dependency and had inhibited learring effects. Consequently, new objectives evolved: in particular, many developing countries wished to regulate the inflow of technology to reduce the costs of transfer, to increase the in- dependence of decision making and to promote local technological innovation. In addition, in response to employment and other problems, some countries recognized a need for more appropriate technology. Costs of Technology Transfer The nominal declared costs of technology transfer need bear little relationship to actual costs because companies which supply more than one service may choose the form in which they receive payment. For example, payments for technology may appear as royalty payments or as profits or as overinvoiced import prices. The problems of disguised nayments arise in most acute form for the most packaged forms of transfer, but are also present to some extent in other forms, such as joint ventures. The high proportion of intra-firm trade and of intra-firm technology flows gives rise to the possibility of disguised payments. There is considerable evidence of overinvoicing of imports and underinvoicing of oxports. Wlile the evidence suggests that this occurs to the greatest extent in pharmaceuticals, there is strong evidence of similar practices in many other industries. Evidence of such practices has been collected in a number of Latin American countries, and in India and Greece. The industries covered include pharmaceuticals, clhemicals, metal products, minerals and rubber products. It is difficult to know how much of the disguised payments should be attributed to technology transfer and how much to other facLors. The need for technology transfer normally gives rise to th!c po;sIbility of such paymuent:s, but their extent is influenced by recipient - x governments' economic policies as well as by lack of compet;tion in the world industry. The process of technology transfer imposes additional costs as the result of restrictive clauses associated with it. In the case of direct overseas investment, the restrictions are implicit. For technology con- tracts between independent parties, they are an explicit part of the contract. There is evidence of widespread restrictions embodied in technology contracts. The restrictive clauses include limitations (or total bans) on exports, tied purchase of inputs, machinery and parts, limitations on competing supplies, and constraints which limit the dynamic effects of transfer by req iring excessive use of expatriate personnel and discouraging local r. and d. UNCTAD estimated the overt costs of technology transfer to be 5% of non-petroleum exports of developing countries in 1968, and estimated that this proportion would rise steadily over the subsequent 10 years. Miile other evidence suggests that the UNCTAD estimates (particularly in relation to the rate of increase after 1968) may be overestimates, adding some .stimate of .he implicit and indirect costs would substantially increase the costs. for example, to add 10 of the costs of imported capital equipment and chemicals and one-fifth of the declared profits on foreign investment to the UNCTAD estimates would more than double them. The high costs do not necessarily mean, of course, that the price is not worth payirg. But they do suggest that there may be considerable gains to be made from bargaining, especially in view of the non-competitiveness of muchi of the market. Independence Technology transfer limits the indepenidence of decision making. This is most obvious in the case of direct inx'tstment, but occurs to a considerablc extent witlh respect to transfers between independent parties where technology - xi - contracts include very heavy restrictions on freedom of decision making. It has been claimed that technology transfer has come to replace ownership as a mechanism of control. Learning The ability to make independent technological choices, to adapt and improve upon chosen techniques and products, and eventually to generate new technology are essential aspects of the development process. Relatively little is known about the process of accumulation of technological capacity. Broadly, three stages may be identified: in the first, the ability to make independent technol'rical choices is developed; in the second, minor innovations occur locally; and in the third, the capacity to create new technology is developed. In general, the stages occur sequentially. There is a complex relationship between the import of technology and the development of local technological capacity, and one that encompasses both complementarities and conflicts. Some import of technology is required as a basis for learning. But highly packaged imports tend to limit the development of the ability to make independent choices. Minor technological change may occur on the basis of imported technology - this seems to respond to a mixture of technological capacity and competitive and other pressures. The third stage - local de- velopment of technology - may be inhibited by indiscriminate imports - partly because of restrictive clauses involved in technology contracts which limit the dynamic effects; partly because the foreign technology associated with foreign trademarks tends to have a strong market advantage over local teclhnology; hence, loca technology, even when developed, is often not used, and thus the incentive to develop it Is much reduced. The most successful examples of technological development have combined selective import of foreign technology with positive measures to promote local technology. Thus the local developments are provided with the foreign knowhow they need and the protection and promotion necessary. Promotional measures include provision of infrastrtucture, tcchnology plans, - xii - subsidies and incentives to r. and d. and government procurem2nt practices that favour local technology. Japan's technological development is a very success- ful case of this sort of policy: technology was imported, then adapted do- mestically and promoted in both public and private sectors. Other successful examples, involving a similar comlbination of policies, have been observed in a few cases in Mexico and India. Policies Towards Technology Imoorts Relevant policies vary according to objectives, although there is considerable overlap with some po:Licies serving more than one objective, and the objectives themselves being mutually reinforcing. For example, policies which eliminate restrictive practices will also increase independence, reduce costs and may contribute to the learning effects of the technology. The set of relevant policies varies with the stage of develcpment, and particularly the technological and administrative capacity of the country con- cerned. Policies aimed at improving the terms of technology transfer are rele- vant to most countries. Although they involve administrative costs, the potential gains are lar-e, as shown by the experience of countries which have followed them. Iowever, policies of selectivity towards imported technology require a greater degree of technological sophistication and administrative judgment. These policies are only worth pursuing where there exists fairly considerable local technoJogical capacity; they may best be introduced on an industry-by-industry basis. The general economic strategy of the country is of relevance to the effectiveness and outcome of technology policies. The terms of technology tranisfer are likely to be more competitive, the more competitive the general environment is, and the less government policies (e.g. of protection) give rise to quasi-rents. But non-competitivc elements in the world industrial structure me.nn that s;pecial technology policies are required in addition t,o general - xiii - competitive policies. As far as local technological development is concerned, the relationship between general economic policies and local technological developments is less clear. While it is often argued that heavy protection and "distorted" factor prices remove incentives for local adaption, there are a number of examples of local technological'innovation occurring in a generally protected environment. Thus, India and Argentina have developed technology locally,in a few cases sufficiently to export the technology to neighbouring countries. The sort of pressures which lead to local technological innovation are of many kinds, e.g., absence of particular raw materials, and not confined to cost pressures associated with pri.e and exchange rate policies. A number of countries have tried to reduce the packaging element in imported technology. A major reason is to secure greater independence of decision making: this is desired in itself, and also as an essential part of the learning process so that countries may develop the capacity first o make independent technological choices, and subsequently to develop their own technology. The policy is also related to the question of costs, since it appears that costs tend to be higher the more packaged the form of transfer. The policies may be mandatory - e.g., forbidding majority foreign owner- ship in some or all industries - or rely on incentives. An essential complement to policies towards depackaging is the introduction of some sort of regulation over technology transfer between independent parties; otlherwise, as indicalted by empirical evidence, many of the problems associated with direct investment re-emerge via technology contracts. A number of countries have introduced National Registers of Technology, permitting registra- tion only if the cbntracts fulfill various criteria with respect to terms and restrictive clauses. In general, restrictive clauses (e.g., with respect to export bans and Lying inputOi) are outlawed. Investigations of the results of thesO policics in two countries - Col.ombia and Mexico - have slhown very - xiv - substantial foreign exchange gains, and the outlawing of a large number of restrictive clauses at relativelyl low administrative Cost. But it has not yet been thoroughly establislhed how far such policies have had de facto as against de jure success, as many of the explicit and formal restrictions may have been replaced by informal implicit ones. Changes in the tax system may be designed to improve the terms of technology transfer. In particular, if corporate taxation is made independent of the degree of underinvoicing or overinvoicing (either by formula apportion- ment or by a uniformity of rates approach), the foreign exchange and revenue loss cause by these practices will be r,much reduced. The removal of tax incentives towards overseas investment, which have been shown to be ineffective, would also improve the terms of technology transfer. Policies to protect and promote local technological developments involve the selective import of foreign techno'ogy as well as promotional measures towards domestic developments. Industries in which there is substantial local potential, and some likelihood of long run comparative advantage in technological develop- ment, should be selected; in these industries technology imports should be permitted where they are compiementary with and conducive to local technological development and restricted where they are competitive with local developments. Teclhnological development is an infant industry, with strong externalities, wlhich accordingly requires protection. There are numerous - and fairly well known - promotional measures, including government subsidies, training and education and so on. None of them have proved to be particularly effective on 1/ their own, but at both macro and micro levels a combination of protection and promotion does seemn to have been effective. Tuie system of patents and trademarks in effect gives stronig protection to foreign technology as against local technolngy. By so doing, it also tends I/ See the I.R.D.C. study into Science and Techniiology Policy IlistrumentLs in 10 Countrie-i (Sagasti, 1978). - xv - to raise the cost of the foreign technology. Five-sixths of patents are held by foreigners in LDCs, and of these, over 90% are unexploitec. International discussion and negotlation about the reform of the system is currently under- way. Trademarks act as a powerful protective device to foreign technology because of the marketing power they bestow. LDC trademarks are relatively undeveloped; they formed half of new registrations in 1974, but this was substantially less than some ten years before. Various reforms are possible, including complete outlawing of trademarks, outlawing foreign trademarks onlv, requiring joint foreign and local trademarks, and imposing a heavy tax on trademarks. The main problem is to combine consumer protection with a r.duction of the role of trademarks. Trademarks tend to be heavily concentrated in a few industries (notably pharmaceuticals) and action could be restricted to one or two sectors, initially. Any restrictive policies need to be accompanied by consumer education and pro- motion of alternative methods of guaranteeing quality, e.g. by developing government standards. Local technological capacity in tiird world countries is of critical importance: it is a vital part of the development process, it is necessary for independence , to improve bargaining power in relation to the import of technology, and to generate appropriate technical change. While there appears to be a certain amount of technological choice today, the continued concentration of technical change on advanced country technology is likely to result in increasingly inappropriate techniques. Unless developing countries undertake r. and d. in alternative directions, the choice of technology available in the future will be increasingly circumscribed and irrelevant to the needs of the world's poorest, The development of a continuous process of technological change - new techniques and products - in an appropriate direction in the developing countries is essential if the choice is to be widened. - xvi - Appropriate Technology Technology recently developed in advanced countries tends to be in- appropriate, in many respects, for many LDCs. This is because it is designed to meet the needs of the advanced countries; it tends for example to be in- creasingly capital intensive. Its use in poor countries involves a concentration of investment resources in the modern sector, exacerbating differentials and contributing to the problems of unemployment and underemployment. Products designed for advanced country consumers are ill suited to meet the basic needs of poor people. However, the high productivity of much modern technology and the efficiency and economies of scale a- sociated with advanced country products may make the technology the best choice, given the absence of efficient alterna- tives. Appropriate technology consists of technology more in line with develop- ing country needs and resouices; it consists of more labour intensive processes in the modern sector, and the development of new and improved techniques and products for the traditional sector. The promotion of more appropriate tech- nology includes the selection of more approp--iate technology among known tech- nologies (including "old" techniques from ad\anced countries and secondhand machinery) and the development of new appropriate technologies. The development strategy a country adopts strongly influences its technological options. If a country's consumption patterns are similar to those of developed countries, and if its main trading orientation is with developed countries, then the main body of technology it uses in the modern sector will need to be that of the developed countries. Consumption patterns are likely to be similar to those of developed countries among countries with an unequal income distribution, an "open" policy towards technological imports, and lack of indigenous cultural factors which inhibit the demonstration effect. Some - xvii - modification of technology is clearly possible - and indeed hbppens - even in this sort of situation, but modifications are likely to be largely a matter of time lags in adopting the latest advanced country technology, more labour intensive ancilliary activities, and modifications rendered necessary by differences in the size of the market. With more equal income distribution and with obstacles (cultural, economic or legal) preventing the domination of advanced country products, the potential for appropriate and self-generated technology will be greater. Trade in manufactured products with advanced countries has generally involved the import of technology from advanced countries, at least in the initial stage. Trade between developing countries is more likely to be consistent with the use of locally generated appropriate technology. Appropriate technology consists both in modification in "modern" sector products and techniques and in up- grading "traditional" sector technology. Even in countries with advanced country oriented modern sectors, there is potential for appropriate technology in the traditional sector to help raise productivitv and incomes and meet basic needs. Policies to promote appropriate technology consist in policies determining the demand for (or selection of) different products and techniques, and policies determining the supply of technologies. On the demand side, the policies concerned are chiefly national; they include determinants of income distribution and consumption patterns, tradint strategy, policies determining control over investible resources by different types of decision makers, and relative factor prices. On the supply side, they include the collection of information about different technologies and its diffusion, and research and development and the creation of new technologies. Potentially, there could be an important role for international institutions on the supply side assisting in informatiJon collection and diffusion, and in fundinig appropriate research. - xviii - Technology transfer belLween developing countries could have an important role to play in increasing developing countries technological independence and bargaining power and in promoting appropriate technology. There are some indications that such trade is expanding; third world MNCs are developing as is third worlcl consultancy and trade in capital goods. As with similar developments, there is a danger that new imbalances and dependencies within the third world will arise as a result. There is a complex system of relationships between past policy towards technology, policy makers and policy making. Countries which have been heavily dependent on foreign technology, particularly in the form of foreign investment, find it more difficult to regulate it than those which have relied on it to a lesser extent and have maintained an arm's length relationship with foreign suppliers. Similarly, patterns of production and consumption which are broadly inappropriate set in force strong forces making for similar inappropriate choices in the future. The extent of current free- dom of decision making depends in large part on past policies. Today's policies, then, will partly determine future opions. tn this context, radical delinking might be a tactica]. and temporary move to strengthen a country's position in future linked relationships. International Technology Transfer: Issues and Policy Options l/ Technology is knowledge - knowledge of how to do and make useful things.2/ At the heart of any form of economic activity from the least to the most sophis- ticated lies the technology or knowledge of how the activity is carried out. Be- fore initiating any economic activity then the first prerequisite is the acqui- sition of this knowledge. But technology is not randomly and freely distributed throughout the world, as would appear from some economists' models. Rather, as part of the process of historical development, the development of technology has been heavily concentrated in certain parts of the world, notably the developed countries. Moreover, much of this technology has been commercialized with pro- prietary rights acquired in it so that it is not freely transferred but is sold commercially. The international transfer - in many cases involving the international sale - of technology is thus an essential precondition for economic development. Since technology changes continuously, with new or improved products, new mater- ials or new uses of old materials, and new techniques of production, the need to acquire technology is not once for all, but a continuing one. Thus the question of technology transfer - how it is transferred, the terms of transfer and the effects of the transfer - is at least as critical to economic development, as the ques- tion of transfer of cap4tal resources. In recent years this fact has been widely recognized, as shown by the many international conferences, resolutions etc. on the subject. This paper attempts to summarize sume of the main issues that arise in connection with the international transfer of technology to developing countries 3/ 1/ I am grateful for comments on an earlier draft to a number of people in the World Bank: I would especially like to mention Howard Pack and Larry Westphal. / Merrill defines it as 'skills, knowledge and procedures for making, using and doing useful things.' 3 There are many problems that arise in connection with internal technology transfer-i.e. the transfer of technology or its diffusion within a nation, but these are not considered in this paper. - 2- I. Why Technology is Transferred The international transfer of technology takes place when knowledge in one country - which may have been developed there or acquired from somewhere else - is communicated to people in another country, for use there. The communication may occur freely outside the market, or may be a commercial transaction. Effective communication of knowledge for economic activity is not normally just a matter of communication of design sheets and formulae, but also involves an essential soft- ware element, the communication of how to use the information, which may require the transfer of skills, managerial knowhow and so on.l/ The sale of technology occurs when some essential part of the package which constitutes the technology is in the commercial possession of some agent, who will only part with it for a price. This 'possession' may take the form of monopolization of the desired knowledge, which may occur naturally when it is first developed, and before others have caught up with the technological developments, or may be the result of legal restrictions protecting the owners of the technology, allowing them to sell it, and preventing imitators, as with the patent laws and those related to trademarks. In either case a monopolistic element enters the market enabling the owners of the technology to earn some monopolistic rents - i.e. to charge a price in excess of the 2/ actual costs of communication.- The monopolistic element may pervade a much wider area than that specifically covered by legal protection, because of the bundled as- pect of much technology, so that some element of the bundle which is apparently free- ly available without legal restriction is in practice protected by restrictions af- fecting some other element in the bundle. The actual costs of communication are 1/ "Technology, used in this study, refers to the package of product designs, pro- duction and processing techniques and managerial systems that are used to manu- facture particular industrial products." (Baranson, p. 13). This paper adopts this definition, but does not confine attention to industrial products. 2/ The justification for commercialization of the market for technology is that it provides the necessary appropriability to induce private R. and D. Part of the excessive price (over and above costs of communication) constitute normal returns to R. and D. and should not, therefore, necessarily be classified as monopoly profits. 3- by no means negl±giblef, Technology transfer may command a Drice to cover these costs in the absence of any monopolistic elements in the market for technology. Technology was defined above as knowledge of how to do and make useful things. But in practice examination of the market for technology suggests that in the process of commercialization of this market, the content of technology transfer has become more complex than this. A major element in technology trans- fer is the acquisition of the right to use certain trademarks and/or access to certain markets and inputs. For shorthand we may describe the acquisition of trademarks, and privileged access gained to markets and/or to inputs (which may include an assurance that the firm will be kept up to date with later technical developments) as marketing rights. These may be highly valuable to individual firms in helping gain markets or inputs. While they are often associated with the communication of useful knowledge, and form a significant part of technology con- '2/ tracts,- they are not themselves accurately described as consisting in-the communi- cation of useful knowledge. Nonetheless, in the context of discussion of inter- 1/ Teece (1976) estimates the costs involved in transmitting and absorh- ing all the relevant unembodied knowledge, and finds that these costs range from 2 to 59% of total project costs. 2/ Trademarks were an aspect of 48% of technology contracts examined in Mlexico and 58% in Argentina. But the estimates are very sensitive to the methodology used. In a study of Brazil where each contract was divided into as many agree- ments as there were contractual elements, trademarks formed 13.2% of the total. But in Brazil trademark licenses are not allowed between parent and subsi- diary company. See UNCT.D (1977b) (paras. 1Z6 and 127) national technology transfer, the acquisition of marketing rights forms an im- portant element of costs and is aLso a significant aspect of motivation. Dis- cussion of the international transfer of technology thus covers both the communi- cation (or sale) of knowledge and the sale of marketing rights. The internationnl transfer of technology takes place when three ccnditions occur. First, decision makers in one country wish to use a certain technology; secondly, that technology is not available locally; thirdly, they believe it is cheaper for them to transfer the technology than to reproduce it locally. These three conditions explain the quite substantia. amount of technology transfer be- tween developed countries.-/ But they are present to a much greater extent ir. relation to investment decisions in developing countries, such that a very la-.ge proportion of investment in developing countries involves international technology transfer chiefly from developed countries. The three conditions apply to a definition of technology which encompasses the marketing element just described. Condition one: investors wish to use a certain technology. For some observers it appears almost axiomatic that countries should wish to, and would benefit from, use of the latest technological developments: "Whatever the source, the increase in the stock of useful knowledge and the extension of its application are of the essence of modern economic growth....No matter where these teclinological and social 1/ See the analysis of eg. Posner (1961 and 1970) describing the 'technology gap' conditions which give rise first to trade, and subsequently to technology transfer between developed countries. A full explanation of international technology transfer should go further than the above, first explaining why a decision is made to produce a particular product in a particular country, as against importing it. Technology gap, product cycle, and import substi- tution cum jumping tariff barrier hypotheses provide explanations of the initial decision to produce. See eg. Posner op. cit., Hufbauer (1966) Vernon (1966) and Elirsch (1967), and (1§76) SPRU (1972) - 5 - innovations emerge - and they are largely the product of the developed countries - the economic growth of any nation delpends upon their adoption." (Kuznets, 1966)- From the point of view of the soc4al. interest and long run development prospects of developing countries, there are three reasons why one might questicn or at least qualify this view. First there are biases in the development of technology: the characteristics of any technology are heavily influenced by the economic and social conditions in the economy in which it is developed.-/ Thus technology developed for advanced societies often has characteristics which are ill suited to much poorer economies: for example, technological advances in rich societies tend to be increasingly capital-intensive, of increasing scale of production and. designed. to produce products intended for high income consumers. As we shall discuss more belcw, if imported unadapted into poor societies, these characteristics have various undesirable effects. The Kuznets view of the un- questionable superiority of the latest technology would cnly be invariably cor- rect if this bias did not exist and technical advance were neutral with respect to factor use and product design, raising the productivity of all types of tech- niques equally, and enhancing the efficiezcy of all types of products equally. aonetheless, recent technological advances do involve great gains in productivity in resource use and this fact mar compensata for biases in characteristics, but it does not do so Invariably. Secondly, there are sigaificant learning effects. 3I The Japanese case- 4ilustrates the way in which restricted import of cechnology may permit the local development of technological capacity. Again learning as- pects vill be discussed =ore below. Thirdly, as already stated the technology that Is transferred involves more than the mot recent technological advances; it l1 See also Gerschenkuxof (1962) and Spencer (1970). 2 Tht point is discussed at much greater length iX Stewart (1977) Chapters l. and 3. 3/ Sew O:awa (1966) 'and UNCTAD (1978a), - 6 - also involves the transfer of marketing rights. While the knowledge itself may be worth acquiring from a national point of view, marketing rights may not be. These qualifications are made from the point of view of the national in- terest of developing countries. They do not apply directly at the level of the individual firm, where most technology decisions are made. It is not their concern that amalgamatirg all the micro-decisions, the free import of advanced country technology may cause biases in development patterns; individual firms respond to this sort of consideration indirectly if differences in conditions affect factor prices and consumer tastes. Long run learning effects are externalities not allowed for in individual decision making while considerations related to marketing rights enhance the individual decision maker's assessment of the value of the technology in question rather than the reverse. For the most part then, individual decision makers wish to acquire recent technology - not necessarily the latest, the exact vintage depending upon technological alternatives and the factor price/market situation in the country in question. At a national level too, governments, keen to industrialize, wish to have the 'best' technology, which is often identified with the latest. Condition 2: the technology is not available locally. During the past two hun- dred years technological innovations have been dominated by a handful of countries. A study by O.E.C.D. (1970) identified 110 significant innovations in the twentieth century. All emanated from developed countries with the U.S. responsible for 60%, the-U.K. 14% and German firms 11%. As'these figures indicate innovations are not evenly spread among developed countries, but largely concentrated on a very few countries. Only the U.S. and the U.K. are net creditors in terms nf rnyp1ty paywents. Th U.S. accounted for nearly two thirds of the gross receipts of royalty payments among the major recipientsl/ in 1977; the main European countries accounted 1/ From the data fund of the I.M.F. Countries included are the U.S., Japan U.K., Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Sweden, Australia, S. Africa, New Zealand, Nonay, Finland and Spain. As a group) these countries are in credit Mo the rest of the world, in terms of royalty payments, to the tune of 1,065 million SDRs. The U.S.' own net credit Is far greater than this - 3,662 milliosn SRDs. for nearly 30%, and Japan for 3%. "hese figures reflect the past history of technological domination by a few developed countries. But much of this domi- nation remains. The developed countries are responsible for 97% of world re- search and development expenditure-,. 6 nations-/ employ nearly 70% of the world's research and development manpower and spend nearly 85% of R and D funds; only 6% of an estimated 3 1/2 million patents issued in 1972 were granted by developing countries, and less than one sixth of those issued by developing countries were owned by developing country nationals. -/ With the exception of Brazil and India, developing countries import a high proportion of their 4/ capital goods- ; over 90% of LDC plant and machinery imports come from developed countries. In recent years there has been some increase in the technological capacity of developing countries - an increase which, as is to be expected, has been unevenly spread among developing counitries. This is indicated by rising expenditure on research and development and, by some evidence of incipient ex- 5/ ports of technology by some developing countries; and by increases in the export 6/ of capital goods by some developing countries.- But while these developments are potentially significant, particularl, in relation to policy, they are of relative insignificance in the general picture. The developed countries retain a massive preponderance in technological innovation which is a fundamental fact which must underly any discussion of technology transfer: it is this pre- ponderance that is sonetimes described as technological dependence.-/ 1- Annerstadt (1978). Expenditure figures are a bit misleading because of dif- ferences in salary levels: developing countries account for 13% of world scientists and engineers involved in research and development. 2/ USA, USSR, Japan, Federal Republic of German, France and the UK. 3/ UNCTAD, (1975b). 4/ See Maizels (1963) and Stewart (1977), Table 5.2. 5/ Described by Wells (1977), Diaz-Alejandro (3977) and Lall (1978). 6/ rt<; of machinery and transport equipnent were 37% of developintg market economy cxpor1t; in .1976. 7/ See UNCTAD, (1976) - 8 - Despite the fact that most innovations occur in the developed countries, there are - to an increasing extent - local LDC sources of technology. In the first place, although small in relative extent, R. and D. in the third world is in- creasing, and third world innovat:ion (which extends, as in all economies, well beyond formal R. and D.) and adaptation is rising.-/Secondly, when a certain technology has been transferred once, internal transfer - from the initial re- cipient to other users - could, in theory replace international transfer. How- ever, in practice both these potential sources of internal technology tend to be underutilized in many countries. Much LDC R. and D. tends to be misdirected, from the point of view of generating usable technologies.- /A considerable por- tion of it is basic research, which nlay be necessary to build up a scientific capacity, but which many observers believe has been overemphasized. Moreover, there are weak links between R. and D. and local productive activities, with a notoriously small proportion of total R. and D. being conducted by firms.- /It is noteworthy that of five countries which have developed Technology Plans, four specified explicitly that a significant weakness of existing efforts was weak links with the productive sector.-4 Evei. where local research efforts do gen- erate viable technologies, there is a strong/ tendency for these technologies to be rejected in favour of foreign sources. This rejection is largely due to 1/ The five countries which have Technology Plans are all planning to raise the proportion of GNTP devoted to R. and D; significantly, to around 1%. Most re- cent figures collected by Annerstadt show a significant increase in R. and D. expenditure in LDCs in 1973 as compared with earlier figures, Adaption and innovntion have been identified in Korea and Taiwan (see Ranis 1972 and 1973), and in Argentina(see Katz (1978) and Maxwell (1978)). See also other sources cited in Lall (1978). While a certain amount of LDC innovation has by now been established its quantitative significance is not clear. 2/ This was the view of the USAID Report (1970); Cooper (1972), Ilerrera (1972) and Reddy in Bhalla (cd) (1979). 3/ See eg. Subrahmanian (1972), Carlsen (1975). 4/ UNC1AD (3978 b). The countries were India, Mlexico, Pakistan and Venezuela. 5/ See Kidron, (1965) Subrahmanlian (1972), Sercovich (1975), Lall (1975). Aurorni ~.nd Morehouse (1974). the market power bestowed by foreign trademarks, which is in turn engendered by consumer belief that foreign 's best, and bv some bad experiences with local technclogies. Foreign technologies mav elso involve a greater marketability on world markets, and in some case access to markets which have been cartelized by foreign sources. The second potential source of internal technology is the internal transfer of techniques which have been initially imported. Both Japan and China have pursued this as a conscious policy. In the inter-war period, Japanese technology policy was summarized by the slogan: "The first machine by import, the second by domestic production". In China, Baranson reports that a UL.S. "process team was shown an ex.ct duplicate of its own - albeit, an eight- year old model - catalytic cracker and platforming refinery of a 3,000-barrel- a-day capacity apparently copied from one that UOP had previously sold to Cuba". (p. 118). But Japan and China are exceptions. Until recently many countries haVe followed a laisser-faire policy towards the import of techn-logy permitting the duplicative import of technology. Restrictions in technology contracts limit the possibility of internal transfer, while it is often in the interests of the individual firm to acquire a foreign technology from the original foreign source, despite the fact (or indeed because of it) that some other local firm has already acquired it. Thus empirical investigations find that very similar technologies are sold to the same country a number of times, and sometimes that the identical 2/ technology is sold a number of times. A study of DanislTforeign investment in India found that every single technique transferred was already in use somewhere .1 UNCTAD (1978a) I/ See Neers9 (1975) - 10 - in India. The potential internal sources of technology a-e thus underused and the extent of international transfer exaggerated, as a result of a laisser-faire policy towards the transfer of technology, and the market power bestowed by foreign technology. Condition 3: decision makers believe it is cheaper to import the technology rather than reproduce it locally. Despite the real costs involved in technology transfer, costs of local reproduction - particularly at the level of the in- dividual firm - are likely to be greater. This is in part due to the lower levels of technical sophistication and of R. and D. capacity in LDCs as com- pared with DCs, and in large part to economies of scale associated with R. and D., and particularly with its use. Thus it is not surprising that once a parcicu- lar technology has been developed, the reduplication of the development process should be. more expensive than acquiring it. Moreover, given that many inves- tors wish to acquire the marketing rights as well as the knowledge, and that lo- cal R. and D. cannot generate this, foreign technology may be bought even when local reproduction would be as cheap. The three conditions necessary for the international transfer of.tech- nology are thus very often present in investment decisions in third world countries This is particularly the case when the market situation is such that foreign trademarks enhance profitability, and governments pursue a passive policy towards technology imports. II. Transfer Mechanisms Defining technology I/ very broadly to include all knowledge related to econorm2ic activity naturally means that it encompasses a very wide range of types of knowledge, and that there are, correspondingly, very many mechanisms of transfer associated with it. In content, technology includes knowledge about infrastructure and services, agriculture as well as industry; it includes speci- fication of what is produced as well as how it is produced. The how of pro- duction is not merely a matter of technical specifications but also includes managerial techniques, forms of organization and so on. Much technology is transferred informally - through reading books, journals, sales literature, through personal contacts in meetings and conferences and so on and through th2 movement of trained people from one job to another. Within more formal categories of transfer, a distinction has been made2/ between direct and indirect mechanisms: direct mechanisms are those used when the recipient enterprises are in direct cont&ct with the suppliers of technology; indirect transfer occurs when a company in an advanced country plays an intermediary role packaging the technology for the developed country. In practice, this distidction is too firm: there are a large variety of types of transfer involving varying degrees of packaging. 1/ The literature abounds with definitional discussions of exactly what is involved in the process of technology transfer, and of the various elements in- volved, e.g., the distinction into "general technology," "system-specific" technology, "firms-specific-technology" and so on (Quinn 1969). See the dis- cussion in Cooper and Sercovich (1971). Here we avoid this type of discussion. 2/ Cooper and Sercovich. - 12 - Direct forms of transfer include direct contracting of individual experts and consultant companies, engaging engineering design and plant construction enterprises, training nationals for specific production prolects, technical information activities and transfer of the process technology embodied in capital goods bv importation of equipment purchased directly from machine manufacturers.-/ Indirect mechanisms range from the completely packaged in the form of dire( investment overseas in a wholly-owned subsidiary, through joint ventures, turnkey arrangements and license and management contracts between independent parties. License agreements encompass a considerable range of contracts which vary in what they cover, in the restrictive provisions involved, and in the form and rate of payment. Some license agrer.-nents contain provisicns fcr some equity participation; some include management contracts, or the right of the licensor to appoint managers and/directors; licensors may sometimes appoint quality control experts, and occasionally control marketing throubh wholly-owned subsidiaries. License agreements often contain restrictive clauses in relation to the rights of the licensee to export, to conduct and/or use independent research, and tie-in clauses, whereby the licensee has to purrhase inputs from the licensor, and so on.-l The determination of the mechaniism of transfer in a particular case is the outcome of the willingness of the supplier of technology to supply the technology in a particular form and the desire and ability of the recipient to acquire it in a particular form. Generally, indirect mechanisms tend to be adopted where a country lacks the capacity'to undertake direct purchase, where proprietary technology is involved which *ill not be released, or where (for marketing or other reasons) the recipient wishes to acquire trade marks.-3 But, 1/ Cooper and Scrcovich. 2/ Cooper and Scrcovich provide a comprehensive discussion. A considerable mnuount of researclh has been done examining the nature of transfer mechanisms in par- ticular countries - see e.g., UNCTADI(3975a), Asian Productivity Organization (1976), S.P.R.U. (1972)., IJNCrAD (1974), Mtarga Institute (1975), Sercovich (1974), Vaitsos (1974). 3/ S.P.R.U. (197'), pp. 19-20. - !.3 - as just suggested, there remains considerable choice as zo the nature of the indirect mechanism. W4here the interests of the rec4pient country differ from those of an individual recip-ent enterprise, the outcome may depend on who is responsible for the negotiations - government or enterprise - and how far enterprise freedom is restricted by government regulations. The quantitative signilficance of different mechanisms varies as between countries, as between industries, and over time. Country variation, illustrated in the Table below for 1970, is partly a matter of national policy towards technology transfer and private overseas investment, and partly of the degree of development, and in particular the technological and managerial sophistication of the country concerned. The less developed - in terms of this type of sophistica- tion rather than per-capita income - the more packaged the transfer is likely to be. because the country may lack the capacity to put the package together itself, and because it may lack the bargaining power to insist on so doing.-/ But independently of stage of development, the question of aLational technology strategy is of critical importance: some countries, such as Japan and many of the socialist countries, only permitted license agreements or direct transfers; many others have encouraged 1/ But, taking the ratio of intra-firm tQ total technology payments to U. S. companies as a guide to the degree of packaging, in 1976 developed countries' packaging (with the exception of Japan) was not dissimilar to that of the developing countries (see footnote, p. 18). This may in part be due to the non-regulatory/interventionist policies of most developed market economies permitting packaged transfers. It also may be due to the fact that as countries become more developed, the technology they need to acquire from overseas becomes more sophisticated, and the tendency for packaging in sophisticated industries to be greater than in less sophisticated outweighs the effects of greater technological sophistication in reducing packaging. - 14 - direct foreign investment; I/ while a few follow an intermediate policy (e.g., India).21 The content of licensing agreements also varies between countries: as is to be expected, countries with little independent managerial capacity are likely to have agreements which include management contracts. This was illustrated in a study of technology transfer to Ethiopia,-/ which found that the majority of agreements contained management contracts. The nature of the transfer mechanism adopted varies with the industry. The more technologically sophisticated, the more difficult it is for countries to rely on direct transfer. The extent and nature of property rights over technology vary with the industry, as does the significance of trademarks. UNCTAD (1975a) classified industries into "modern" (requiring heavy research and develop- ment and with a recent record of tetchnological innovation), "traditional" and "other" - both of which use well-established technologies. They found that for 13 countries, 57% of the contractual arrangements were in the "modern" classifica- tion in manufacturing, but there was a wide dispersion between countries. Relatively sophisticated countries, like South Korea, had as much as 80% of contractual arrangemeents in the modern industries, presumably indicating that direct transfer occurs in mature industries with well-established technologies; but in Dahcmey, 80% of contracts were outside the research intensive sectors. A comparative study of pharmaceuticals, chemicals and electrical engineering in Latin America 4/ found significant differences in preferences of supplying firms for different mechanisms of transfer. Broadly, these differences in preference were reflected in the actual arrangements. In the pharmaceutical industry, there was a strong preference for transfer via wholly-owned subsidiaries, and also for patent 1/ As shown by the massive tax incentives provided. 2/ See S.P.R.U. (1972) Ozawa (1966). Subralmanian (1972), Neers6 (1975), UNCTAD (1978), Mytelka (1977), UNID0 (1978). 3/ UNCTAD (1974). 4/ S.P.R.U. (1972) - 15 - iable 1 OWNERSHIP CHARACTERISTTCd OF TIE CONTRACTING ENTERPRISES IN THE TECHNOLOGY JIZECEIVING COUNTRY, EITD 1970 % of Contracts in Enterprises with Majority Foreign Minority Foreign Wholly Nationally Country Ownership Ownership Owned Cyprus 48 44 8 Colombia 45 12 43 Brazil 36 64# Sri Lanka 29 42 29 Peru 28 19 55 Rep. Korea 13 87# Pakistan 12 8 79* India 3 12 85 Yugoslavia - 5 95 Source: UNCTAD (1975) TD/B/AC.ll/OjRev. 2, Table 3. # Minority foreign ownership treated as wholly national. * Specifier, as "100% government controlled." protection of the technology transferred. In chemlcr.ls, the majority of firms preferred joint ventures or pure licensing arrangements - the preference being greater the smaller the size of the supplying firm. In electrical machinery - which on the whole is a mature technology which has been widely dispersed - by far the largest nuamber of preferences was for licensing agreements. In a study of metal working and chemical firms in three Andear Pact countries, Mytelka (1978) distinguis-:. between technology transfer via licensing and direct acquisition through experience of personnel, non-negotiable means (e.g., copying), the purchase of machinery and processes, journals end professional meetings. "Ownership structure, product - 16 - sector and firm size...correlated highly with the decision to license." Foreign firms clustered in industrrEs with complex and volatile technologies; they together with mixed firms overwhelmingly licensed their technology, even wilere the technologies were simple and mature. Nationally-owned firms were domninant in simpler (technologically) industries: 61% of nationally-owned firms acquired technology through direct means, as compared with 17.6% of foreign firms, 12.5%J of State firms and 25% of mixed fi-ms. The firms were asked why they decided to license: 51% gave braLvd name acquisition as a reason; 47% the complexity of the technology, 30% prior L elationship to the technology supplier, 26% cheapness, and 17% 'other' which in(ludes advanLageous bargaining conditions, reduced costs, few restrictions. Returning to the earlier distinction between that part of technology transfer which eonsists in the communication of useful knowledge, and marketing rights aspects, it appears that for this sample,of the total reasons given, one-third v!.-e of the knowledge communication typ' (complexity and cheapness), while twe- th:, i, were other reasons, much of which could be classified as marketing rights. Iziis does not mean, of course, that licenses obtained for e.g., brand name reasons, did not bring with them useful knowledge and quality guarantees which it would have been costly to obtain in other ways. A study of sources of technology in S. Korea -/ found that formal mechanisms of transfer - licenses and te.hnical agreements with foreign technology suppliers - accounted for ornly a small proportion of tne total. Form,al mechamisms from foreign suppliers were of greatest significance in the modern sector - accounting for 21% of all important technology sources. This is a smaller proportion than other sources of foreign technology, which included tech- nology embodied in Korean labour anad rNanagement (18.6%), foreign suppliers of capital equtipment or raw materials (8.2°') and foreign buyers (6.6Z). In 1/ Pursell and Rhee (1978). - 17 - the traditional and resource based sectors formal mechanisms played a sig- nificantly smaller role. While there may be special factors in S. Korea accounting for some of the importance of informal mechanisms - for example, buyers can only play a significant role in an export-oriented economy - the study suggests we may often o"leremphasize the role of formal mechansims in technology transfer. In recent years, there have been various forces making for less packaged forms of transfer - both in recipient and supplying countries. Growing industrial sophistication among recipients has increased their capacity to provide elements of the package for themselves; but they have also moved into more sophisticated (technologically) industries, where packaging is more dominant. Increasing political and economic sophistication, combined with the accumulation and spread of knowledge about the technology transfer process, has increased countries' intervention in technology transfer, sometimes involving a search for unpackaged alternatives. -/ In some of the supplying countries, government regulations curtailing investment overseas, and fears of the riskiness of overseas investment in the light of moves among recipients to reduce equity participation, have contributed to more arms length forms of technology transfer. 2/ The evidence, however, is rather mixed. Baranson claims that "the most dramatic of the new strategies has been the adoption by some U. S. firms of an explicit policy to shift from equity investment and managerial control of overseas facilities to the sale of technology and management services as a direct means to earn returns on corporate assets." 3/ He cites examples in five major research-intensive industries. In the parts of the world where policies have been most explicitly directed against packaged forms of technology inflow, 1/ See UNIDO (1978) and Mytelka (1977). 2/ Baranson (1978) discusses the reasons, particularly from the point of view of the supplying countries, at greater length. 3/ Baranson, op. cit., p.5. - 18 - e.g. India and the Andean Pact Countries, there is evidence of a move towards less packaged forms. 1/ But as Table 2 shows for the world as a whole, and for developing countries other than Latin America, there has been a significa-nt 2/ increase in the proportion of U. S. technology receipts which are intra-firm. Tlih U. S. accounLed for 7:?2 of gross receipts for technology among the U. S., Japan and Europe in 1969; the proportion has declined to 68% in 1977. 3/ It appears that U. S. technology supplies are more often intra-firm than supp:ies from other countries. 4/ No definite conclusions can be drawn on the basis of this evidence - which is not surprising, perhaps, given the many factors that contribute to the overall breakdown, including recipient country policy, industrial composition,-5/ 6/ country source of supplies, etc. But it does appear that there are a range or alternative mechanisms for technology transfer in many industries. l/ See Mytelka (1977). 2/ As disctussed in detail below, royalty payments are not necessarily an accurate guide to payments for technology transfer. Over time, changes in the envirron.:ent may leac' companies to change the form (proportionately) in which they receive differel t forms of payment. This may be one explanation of the declining iatra- firm raLio for Latin America, whlere the Andean Pact prohibited the payment of royalties between subsidiary and parent companies. 3/ These figures are for receipts from technology transfer to all countries. Evidence for payments by particular developing countries also suggests the declining role of the U. S.: for example, in South Korea, the U. S. accounted for 40% of technology imports for the years 1962-66, and 217 in 1973-77; 'apj7 accounted for 33% in 1962-66 and 53% in 1973-77. In Peru, the U. S. and Canaca accounted for 60% of the royalty payments in 1971 and 35% in 1974. A study of license agreements in the Philippines for agreements hefore 1970, showed that 67% were with U. S. firms, 8% with Japanese firms; for the period 1971-73, 34%' were with the U. S. 12% with Japan. (UNIDO, 1978). 4/ This is suggested by the fact that intra-firm payments for particular countries to all sources are substantial'ly lower than those shown for U. S. payments: e.g., for Brazil intra-fi-n payments aere 52% of total payments in manufacturing 1965-70; in Argentina they were 42% in 1972. (Chudnovsky 1978). 5/ See Chudnovsky (1978) ,Table 2 for variations in the ratio of inter-firm to intra-firm royalties according to industry in Argentina. 6/ Tlhe proportion of total. payments of royalties and management fees to U.-S. companies, w7hich were int-ra-firm, rose sharply over the period 1960 to 1976 in the de.veloped countries, as well as the 'other developing': In Japan, it rose from 13 to 50%, in the U.K., from 56 to 84%', in Western Europe, from 44 to 82%, Canada, 80 to 94%, in Australia, New Zealand and South Africa fromn 65 to 84Z. - 19 - Table 2 PROPORTION OF TOTAL U.S. RECEIPTS FROM ROYALTIES AND MANAGEMENT FEES WHICH ARE INTRA-FIRM World Latin America Other Developing 1956 64 88 n.a. 1960 62 83 72 1972 76 85 80 1976 82 82 90 Source: 1956 - Hymer (1976), Table 2.2. Rest - Chudnovsky (1978), Table 1. - 20 - III. Significant Dimensions of Technology Transfer Objectives of LDCs in relation to technology transfer have evo)vpt4 in response to experience in relation to technology transfer over the last 2c years. Initially, keen to industrialize rapidly and thereby, as they thought, acquire wealth and economic independence, most countries main aim was to maximize the quantity of technology transferred. Hence, they introduced a host of incenti:.es, such as tax incentives, duty drawbacks, protection, and the provision of infra- structure, designed to encourage the inflow of technology from overseas, main.l in the form of private overseas investment. -/ In other respects, a broadl-y laisser faire policy was followed with respect to technology transfers so that it was left to individual firms to decide the form and nature of the technology transferred. However, as the consequences of unrestricted inflow became apparent, new objectives evolved: the laissf,r-faire policy has therefore given way to a much more interventionist strategy at both national and international levels. First, the high and rising cost of technology transfer drew attention to the neet to introduce policies which would improve the terms of technology transfer. This was initiated by the Andean Pact group of countries, then UNC:A.D, a,: by now the need for policies in this area has gained very wide acceptance amo=g LDCs. Secondly, in many countries a dualistic pattern of development was associated with the unrestricted import of advanced country technology. The capital intensity of the investment, the heavy underemployment, and the elitist 1/ See Lent (1967), Reuber (1973) and U.N. (1972) for a description of the ir.- centives. - 21 - consumpcicn patterns :n many counttie3 led to emphasis on the need for appropriate technology: i.e., tecinology In line with the needs and reso'irces of poor countries. Although the need for appropriate technology was largely 4nit±aced in the advanced countries, it has achieved increasing support among LDCs. Thirdly, the dependency school of development suggested that neither political independence nor industrialization was sufficient to achieve economic independence, and that at the root of the dependency relationship exhibited between periphery and center lay technological dependence. A more modest approach. which does not rest on acceptance of the whole dependency analysis, shows that techno- logical dependence did indeed impose restrictions on the freedom of decision making that were scarcely compatible with economic independence. Hence, the creation of independent technological capacity became an aim. Fourthly, it was increasingly felt that unrestricted imrort of techno- logy inhibited the development of local technological capacity which in turn reduced long-run development prospects and engendered further technolcgicaL dependence. The new' objectives towards technology transfer, which have been accepted and pursued with varying degrees af enthusiasm, are in many ways in conflict with the initial objective of maximizing the inflow. / They each suggest a much more interventionist policy on the part of governments, and in general a more restrictive and selective policy towards technology transfer from abroad. They each support (from different points of view) the need to develop 1/ See the findings of the feasibility study into "A New International Mechanism for Appropriate Technology." (1978). 2/ There is a (non-coincidental) parallel between chpnpin. 0j'4NC 3 S tr%rards economic development and those towards technology transfar. Itc the dethronement of COP has gone, after a timelag, a corresponding detrocking of associated (instrumental) objectives such as maximizing technology transfer. - 22 - Third World technological capacitv. In other respects, the new objectives are sometimes in conflict, and often d±ffer 4n emphasis and policy,r conclusions. In the rest of chis paper, we examine the policy opcicns indicated by the new objectives. The paper takes four d±mensions of technology transfer: 1. the terms of the transfer, or the cost; II. the effects of che transfer on 'ndeoendence of d4ecision nak4ng; III. the effects of the transfer on local technological capacity, or the learning effects of the transfer; and IV. the characteristics of the transfer. Each of these corresponds with one of the 'new' objectives described. The paper considers past experience in relation to each of these dimensions, and policy options suggested (and in some cases adopted). The next sections consider the first three dimensions, which are grouped naturally together in terms of policy. The question of characteristics raises somewhat sep"rate issues and is dealt with in Section VI. 23 - IV. Costs of Technology Transfer (i) Actual costs: It is difficult to ascertain actual costs of transfer. Apart from the fact that data is weak and sparse, the packaged aspect of much technology transfer and the indirect costs imposed raise problems. Where there is any degree of packaging the supplying firm is, by definition, supplying more than one service. This means that the firm has some choice in how it receives its return for each element of the package - e.g., whether it receives payment for technology as royalties, as profits, or through the transfer pricing mechanism. Declared payments nominally attributed to any one item may therefore bear no relationship to the real charge levied. To get at the total charges levied is lifficult; but with rough and ready means, estimates have been made. But this does not solve the problem of how to allocate the items among the elements of the package. This is peculiarly difficult in connection with technology transfer because there is often some monopoly element involved, enabling the total charges levied to exceed the competitive charges. But the source of monopoly is not always the possession and sale of the technology; it may involve access to markets, or raw materials or so on. However, if we define the technology transfer to include marketing rights, as we have above, then it can be claimed that in large part monopolistic charges may be attributed to the technology transfer. But we should not include, as many seem to have done, competitive payments for other services which form part of the package, as costs of technology transfer. These problems, that arise from the packaged nature of technology transfer, are most acute for the most packaged torms of transfer - viz., that of the TNC to wholly owned subsidiaries. But joint ventures also have - 24 - considerable scope for manipulating payments. Wholly owned national companies often receive technology and inputs from the same source - again it is not possible to know to what extent particular forms of payment represent the payment for technology. A further problem is that restrictions on activIties form a normal part of many technology contracts. But these impose costs, which can be substantial. For example, tied sources of inputs is similar to tied aid in increasing costs, but worse because with aid tying normally takes the form of tying to a particular country whereas with technology transfer the tying is to a particular firm. Even for aid, the costs have been estimated to be as much as 30% of the cost of the equipment. - The costs are likely to be greater for private technoloRy transfers. Other forms of restriction also impose costs which are difficult to estimate, such as restrictions on exports and on local innovation. The extent of these restriction has been established by a number of studies, but not their costs. In view of these problems, it is perhaps not surprising that none of the (quite numerous) studies on technology transfer to developing countries have come up with satisfactory estimates of costs. The most systematic estimates of direct costs were mrade Dy UNCTAD (1975). For 1968, they estimated -that direct costs to LDCs of technology transfer were around $1,500 million for royalties and consultancy payments, which was equivalent to 5% of non-oil exports and around 0.5% of GDP. They 1/ Bhlagwati (1968). - 25 - estimated that thiese payments were likelv to grow et around 20% p.a. on the basis of questionnaires to recipient countries. However, the technology receiving countries expected a lower rate of increase. If we assume that in fact technology payments grew by 15-Zo p.a. from 1968-1977, they would amount to i5,Z75m. in l977.- Table 1 shows the UNrUfAD estimates togerner with technology related payments. As suggested above some element of these related payments are likely to be due to technology. In addition to these direct costs, overinvoicing of imports and underi.voicing of exports represents an additional cost. The very substantial proportion of international trade that occurs within the transnational corporation gives scope to these practices. 1/ The data are derived from questionnaires to recipient countries. More recent data collected by the IMF is too incomplete to provide much guidance. It excludes management/consultancy and the coverage is very incomplete. The estimates for royalties are far lower than those of UNCTAD (generally of the order of 1/2% to 1% of exports). It is likely that a good deal of intra-affiliate payments have been omitted in the IMF data. However, the Fund data suggest that the UNCTAD estimates overstate the costs. According to the Fund data, gross royalty receipts among the main technology suppliers from all countries grew by 99% p.a. between 1969 and 1977. Net receipts grew by 10.9% p.a. - 26 - TABLE 3 Direct costs ot transrer ot Iccltnology in comparison w ith ofiler relevant forcign cxchange fl,j%N s of devclopinig countirics, 1968a Proporti-bn of i,ect PVatte pay,,,lcra lop Irinilef (miltios of of tri,01j,l 'ry Flows do/Irls) (per e(nt) Outflovs 1. Direct paYji, nnts for transfer of techinology (palents, licensws, know-how, tradenmarks, and mana,:emcnt and othcr teclinical scrvices) 1,500 100 s. Tcchniology-rclatcd paymcrnits: (aJ imports (c.i.f.) of machincry and equiplicnt (excluding passcger vcihicles) and ol chemiicals 18.420 8 (bJ P'iofit on direct forcign investment (excluding oil-producinig countrics)b ................. 1.721 87 3. Service paymcnts ont cxternal public debt 4,022 37 Inflowr 4. Non-petrolcum cxports (f.o.b.) .29,350 5 5. Total oflicial flows. 6.710 22 6. Direct foreign investmencit (including rcinvested carninl2s) .2,700 56 Zou es: Line 1: 1 .ZCTAD secretariat estimates (sce text). Linc 2 (a): United Nations, .Mlonthly lBulletin of Statistic . vot. XXVI. No. 7 (July 1972). Line 2 (b): "'the outfloNv of financial resources fronm developing countries: note by the UNCTAD secrctariat" (TDIl I 8/Supp.S), loc. cit. tine 3: lBRD/IDA,.AtrnrialReport, 1972. Lincs 4, s anrd 6: UNCI'AD, Ilaindbook o,f Itiertiarrional Trade anid Decilopnmenr St,:trltic:. 1972 (Uniited Nations pubhication, Sales No. Lt/F.72.tt.D.3). D Data do not include Southern Europcan countries. b Including oil-producisng countries: $4,934 millIon. - 27 - It is estimated that roughly one-third of total US exports were on an intra-firm basis in 1970.1/ In manufacturing three industries accounted for 70% of that trade: transport, equipment, non-electrical machinery and chemicals. Fifty three percent of manufactured exports to developing countries was intra-firm, and for developing countries other than Latin America the proportion was 65%.2/ Intra-firm trade is here defined as trade between a parent and a majority-owned affiliate. If joint ventures were included the proportion would be higher. A detailed study of Brazil and Mexico showed that the intra-firm share of exports was high and growing: in 1960 it was 68% and 54% respectively; in 1972, 73% and 82%.-/ Imports from the parent company accounted for 50% (Brazil) and 58% (Mexico) of the affiliates' total material imports in 1972. Again, intra-firm trade was found to be particularly concentrated in technologically sophisticated industries. For the UK, a survey suggested that about one-quarter of all exports were intra-firm, and one-quarter of recurrent imports of affiliates in developing countries were supplied by other units within the corporation. Data for Norway and German firms also show a significant proportion of trade is intra-firm; generally speaking the proportions (of both imports and 2xports) are lower than for US firms.-/ 1/ Lall (1973) and UiCTAD (1977c) summarize the evidence. i/ Table 1 UNCTAD (1977c). 3/ Newfarmer and Mueller (1975) quoted i.n UNC'TAD (1977c). 4/ See la!CTAri (1077c). - 28 - The evidence thus shcws that a very significant proportion of trade is intra-firm, giving rise to the possibility of a quantitatively significant element of costs of technology transfer being disguised through the manipulation of transfer pricing. Intra-firm trade tends to be highest in the technologically sophisticated firns where the costs of technology transfer are likely to be greatest. Intra--firm trade appears to be of substantially greatest significance for US companies. However, the US is by far the largest source of technology transfer, although its predominance is declining.l/ The existence of a high proportion of intra-firm trade is necessary but not sufficient to indicate the existencL of transfer price manipulation as a sizeable source of income transfer between countries. There are obvious difficulties in getting hard evidence on the existence and extent of such practices. But a growing body of evidence has now acctimulated2! showing that in some industries, it forms a significant element in internaticial income flows. One approach has been tc, try t:' establish the extent of such practices indirectly by regression estimates. Kopits (1976b) found he was able to explain the breakdown of income transfers as between royalties and transfer payments, statistically, by the tax incentives for the different types of remittances. But he was primarily concerned with developed countries. An econometric analysis of export prices in Latin America suggested underpricing of exports of, on average, 40% of the value of exports.3/ Other indirect evidence has been less conclusive. _/ See page 18. 2/ Summaries are contained in Lall (1973), Knnits (3q76P) and 1TNCTAD (1077c) 3/ Morgenstern and Miller (1974). - 29 - Direct estimates have been obtained by comparing J.ntra-firm prices with -market prices. Detailed studies have been done for Colombia and Greece - when the government instituted machinsry to check on transfer pricing practices of international firms. In Colombia between 1967 and 1970, overpricing was great- est in pharmaceuticals - "the absolute amount of overpricing for the foreign firms studied amounted to a figure of six times their royalties and 24 times their declared profits':-/ overpricing was greatest for the pharmaceutical industry, (on average 155%) where the fereign exchange losses due to overpricing of inputs were estimated to be as great as the total industrial royalties paid by all industrial sectors for technology. In electrical goods overpricing was estimated to be 54%, in rubber goods 44%, and chemicals 25%. In Greece-/ two groups of products were studied. In metals, metal products and minerals a sample investigation showed overpricing of imports of between 5 and 88%, with a weighted average of 19.4%; for chemicals the range was between 12 1/2 and 229%, with a weighted average of 34.5%. In the first group of prod- ucts 95% of the underpricing was the responsibility of foreign owned firms; in the chemicals groups it was all in the foreign owned firms. For the mineral -product group the total foreign exchange cost was estimated to be about 2 1/2 times the size of declared profits. The Greek study also investigated three export products and found underpricing ranging from 8.3% to 16.9%. The extent of underpricing was equivalent to 35% of the preceding year's profits for a 90% foreign owned firm, 26% for a joint venture and 13% for a locally owned 1I 'aitsos (1971). I/ Roumeliotis and Golemif (1978). - 30 - firm with foreign connections. Evidence of substantial underpricing of imports in the pharmaceutical in- dustry has been obtained in India, Ecuador, Peru and Chile.-/ The evidence for extensive use of transfer pricing to secure international income flows has been long established in the petroleum industry. -2 The evidence collected so far indicates that transfer pricing forms a significant source of international income flows in intra-firm transactions - at least as great as declared royalities and often as great as declared profits. While the evidence, in terms of cotutry coverage and of magnitude, is grea,est for the pharmaceutical industry, the practices are not confined to this industry but extend (in lesser amount) to all irLdustries examined, such as rubber and mineral products, as cited above. In view of the strong incentives that firms face to 3/ price in these ways (which include the tax system and restrictions on remittances- the results are not surprising. It is difficult to assess with fairness and accuracy how far these prac- tices inflate the costs of technology transfer - partly because the evidence though growing is still very incomplete, and partly because, as alre..dy suggested, it is difficult to know how much of' the additional cost should be attributed to technology transfer and how much to other factors. However, without trying to form an accurate estimate certain conclusions follow: first, the declared royalty payments cannot be taken as a guide to the costs of technology transfer. Some element of the income transferred as overinvoiced imports/underinvoiced exports should also be attributed to technology transfer. In so far as it is technological dominance (including marketing rights aspects) which gives rise 1/ See 1UNCrAD (1977c) paras. 94 ro 98. 2/ Jenkins and Wright (1975). 3/ The various motives are summarized in Vaitsos (1974), Lall (1973) and Kopits (1976a). - 31 - to the market domination of a few firms and the possibility of transfer price manipulation, then it is correct to -attribute the inxcome so transferred in large part to the process of technology transfer. Secondly, the form or mechanism of the technology transfer influences the extent to which this sort of inter- national income transfer is possible. Manipulation of transfer prices can only occur, in fully fledged form,-where trade is intra-firm. But some possibilities exist in less packaged forms than the wholly owned subsidiary. Joint ventures, indeed, may have as great a possibility, and a greater (at least from the point of view of the foreign partner) reason for transferring income in this way. But the (limited) evidence suggests that joint ventures pay slightly less for inputs than wholly owned subsidiaries.- .ae possibilities are clearly less for locally owned firms, but even here where they have strong connections with overseas firms, or where purchases of inputs (and/or access to markets for output) are effectively tied to the foreign firm, part of the costs of technology transfer may appear as inflated prices of imported inputs. However, both a priori reasoning, and the limited empirical evidence on this, suggest that the more packaged the transfer mechanism, the greater the flow of interiational income that occurs via transfer pricing. Thirdly, irrespective of the total sums involved, the existence of sizeable international income flows associated with technology transfer, in the form of transfer price manipulations, suggests a number of directions for policy. These will be discussed below. Indirect costs as already indicated the process of technology transfer often imposes restrictions on the activities of recipient enterprises which impose real, albeit indirect, costs. In the case of wholly owned subsidiary these restric- tions are often implicit. But in transfers between less closely associated enterprises, they are explicit elements in technology contracts.-/ I/ Stopford and Wells (1972) p. 161 - 162 21 UNCTAD (1975a) found that in both India ana the knilippines provision for tied purchase of inputts was substantially greater in technology transfer between indcpendcnt enterprises (20Z in India, 58% in the Plillippines) than between associated enterprises (10% for botlh wlholly owned subsidiaries and minority equity in India; 9X for a wholly oxrned subsidiary and 25% minority equity in Llte Philippines); (Table 6). Vaitsos (1971) found similar differencea. - 32 - Table 4 provides a useful summary of the sort of restrictions to be found. TABLE 4 Patietri or tinit-violsm o)n ;acvvss tui icchniiigXy by dlevntillingi coultirics A' r;'p*s at I, wv rije, """" Ii"t': v J IIr ' .1 csfteid li,m,it,gltij Type of fit f,i*fhin Yes No 1. Tied pI iuhjscS or imapoitcd Argenirn;a. Cthile. C"yprus. Fcu.io Requblic of Kurca in put, *cetimpinvolI .a ad pairc dewf . G r;c *rI .\l Ml 1.1. Mc ic3. parts Njigrij. 1.'k;S uI, l'eru, Sri Lanka, Turkey 2. Rcstii0jun of ex iorts (totil Afgj nlin.a. Chile. Cyprru. Sinjn porc prolubilion. piarliIl lilill- I Wuldor. Greece. I r at. Ma II ta(Iml. gCoFrapI:cal . Mexico, Niw-rar. Vikiun, constraint) I'ctu, Sri Latika, Turkcy 3. Requirnem.nt orguirinaces Cylprus, Nigeria, Turkuy Grcccc, Iran, MIalta, .'lcxico, 3apinit clhmjtae% in taxes, SingJPorc tariffs nI\d c\chanec ratCs aiffectig prolits. royaltics and icinitt;anecs 4. Limitation of comepeting supplies by: Ja) rc!tuiction or Cyprmss. Grcccc. Mexico. Irani, Malta, Pakistan, Republic competinllg t:npor%. Ni;rCri3, Peru of Korea, Singapore, rurkCy (bJ preventitig com,-ctition Greece, %Ijita, Mexico Iran, Nigcria, P.akiNtan, for loctl rxsources Rcpublic of Korea, Singaporc (cj obtainirng ocni putenits Ecuador, Malta, Nigeria Greccc, Iran, Singapore to clinil:eC competitors 5. Constraints limifing thc clynaniic effects of the transfcr pJi CXCcSMiVC usc of Argcntina, Malta. MIexico Silngaipore expatriJte personnel Nigeria, Plcru, Turkey (b) discouragCement of thc Argentina, Ecuador, GrecCC, development ol Iocal Ntaltw, Mexico, Migeria, tcchni:jI and ruswarch Turkey and dcvAlopmcnt cap.ibtlities The first two items are of greatest relevance to the question of costs of technology transfer. Detailed studies of technology transfer have revealed that restrictions 1/ are widespread. The SPRU-study of Latin America found export restrictions 1/ SPRU (1972) - 33 - in 12 out of 19 firms in the pharmaceutical irdustry, 8 out of 10 companies in chemicals and the majority of firms in electronics. A study-/ of the Andean Pact countries experience showed that of contracts examined 77% in Bolivia, 77% in Colombia, 75% in Ecuador and 89% in Peru con- tained a complete export prohibition. For nationally owned firms the per- centage which prohibited exports was 92%.- No major differences were found be- tween sectors. The effect on countries' export potential varies with industrial strategy and the type of technology transfer as well as the strategy of the technology sup- plier. While these studies found significant export restrictions, technology transfer associated with multinational companies provides access to export mar- TABLE 5 Provisions for lied inputs in contracl'aal agreerients for thc transfer of itchnoIo&y ?rrcen,rage of ugircc,,ict,ts Ctountry containing sIIcI provisiolns Bolivia .83 Colombia ............... 77 Ecuador .67 Peru .62 Pilippines. .26 India: April 1961 - March 1964 .... IS April 1964 -- MaLreli 1969 . .-. - S Solt res: Colombia, p)cpartaniento N3cion3l de Plarncaci6n, 7rans. ferelncia de fcnolote1g(o (IBogoti. Junie 1970); C. V. Vaitsos, 7The PrOctsS of Co"lnlzercidlianri,, eof Technzologv in the A ndran Pact (OAS, %VWashingrorrl D.C., 1971); and Restrictive businzess practices: Jlyteriin rcport be [lie IINCTAD secretariat (United Nationis publi- cation, Sales No. 1.72.11.D.1 0). table 2. NOTE. For Blolivia, EcuaJor and Peru the perccntacs rcelale to tihc total numilber of agrecine,ts contarninin references to inpluts. For India. the perceilttge for 1961.1964 refcrs to the total number of effective arreenenits; U1e prccvit.-e fur 19o4.1969 refers to those agrecicilt5 obtailjiog ;Gover nment approvjl and eventually comiig inito force dtiring the period. 1/ Vaitsos (1971) 2/ In Japan, In 1962, 53% of technology contracts contained export restrictions, with lnuch a higher proportion in some industries (90% in metal products, 85% in non-tranrsport miaclinery, 80% in transport machinery and 65% in paper products): O.E.C.D. , (1967). - 34 - kets in other cases, as for exampLe with the processing technologies associated 1/ with export zones.- For this sort of technology transfer the wholly owned sub- 2/ sidiary is more likely to gain access to international market than joint ventures.- The Table, on the previous page, based on answers to an UNCTAD questionaire snows tne prupurr..oa us contracLb wnicn iuciuueu a cie-iL clause iur iilputs. The study of the Andean Pact group of papers showed that tie-in clauses were experienced in all sectors st:udied, but were greatest in the pharmaceutical industry. Adding up the costs: as already stated it is impossible to be accurate because of lack of data and conceptual and theoretical problems in estimating and attributing costs. However, it does seem clear that the overt charges for technology transfer - royalty paymer,s etc. - are way below the total costs of tie transfer. For axdwple, to au6 13% of thie cubts uf importetu capital equipment and chemicals and one fifth of declared profits on overseas investment to the LTFCTAD estirates of rechnology costs would more than double the costs in IT6° Fo 12 1/,r7 of non-petrolctTm exporits). Yet in .-rew of the evidence on intra-firms trade, transfer pricing practices, tied purchases of inputs, and *xport restrictions, these additions are extremely modest. For example, suppose we assume that tied purchase of capital goods adds 30% to cost:s of capital equipment, as might be sug- gested by the evidence on tied aid, then for countries with around three quarters of their inputs tied by technology contracts, the additional cost would be over twerty percent of the cost of capital equipment. It would be interesting and useful to have accurate estimates of total costs, but even without these, it is clear that the total cost is very significant, and LDCs could make important foreign exchange savings if they were able to reduce the cost of technology transfer. 1/ See eg. Helleiner (1973). / "One of the important differences between the two types of equity arrangement appears to lie in the different access to export markets. The foreign con- trolled subsidiary is more likely to be offered access to the global channels of distribution of the -foreign firm than is a joint venture" Chudson (1974). Some reasons and evidence is contained in Stopford and Wells (1972). - 35 - (ii) The Appropriate Irice: The market for technology is a peculiar one - even within developed countries; peculiarities aze greater in relation to technology transfer between developed and developing countries. The marginal cost of supplying information that has already been developed, are low: "once new knowledge has been created it has the character of a public good, in the sense that the use of such knowledge by one person does not preclude its use by another so that optimality requires that it be made available to all poten- tial users without charge" (Johnson) However, since the costs of the initial research and development may be substantial, marginal cost pricing would not provide enough incentive for its development by the private sector. To this dilemma, two solutions are possible: first, that the public sector should be responsible for, or subsidize, the pro- duction of knowledge. This raises problems in securing the necessary links with users (problems widely encountered in developing countries, where much research is publically financed); although experience with defence research suggests the problems are not insuperable. The second solution is to provide leg..l and other protection to the owners/developers of technology so that they may acquire some monopolistic control over their technology, and consequently sell it at a price above its marginal cost. This has been the system adopted for much technological development in developed countries. It is often justified as necessary to secure a continued flow of research and development. Essentially then with this system the price charged for technology is a monopolistic/oligopolistic one. The non- competitive pricing of technology can be viewed as a mechanism adopted by devel- oped country firms to generate returns to innovative activity in an area where competitive appropriability is low. Developing countries have control over how they wish to finance or pro- tect their own research, but in acquiring technology from abroad, they have to accept the system as they find it. In this context it makes little sense to - 36 - talk of the 'right', 'optimal' or 'appropriate' price. Two extreme positions have been put forward. On the one hand, it is sometimes suggested that the develop- ing countries are so marginal in relation to the technology sales of advanced countries, that they should make a minimum or zero contribution to the research and development costs of t.±e technology they acquire.-fOn the other hand, others have suggested that even a small inroaLd into the current price of technology, will re- duce the flow (the flow being variously interpreted as the flow of research and development and/or the flow of technology transfer).2/ Both common sense and evidence suggest that the latter position is Loo extreme. Developing countries, taken as a whole, do provide a considerable portion of the expenses of technological development, as evidenced by the costs summarized above. But they are normally quite a way down the line, as users of new technology, frequently acquiring it not from the first developers hut subsequent owners,-3 after a considerable time lag. Sales to developing countries, then, probably form only a small part of the moti- vation behind the development of most technologies. Another question is how far the transfer, as against the development of technology would be affected by a reduced price. Tne answer to tiis 3s unknown - -here can be no single answer covering all countries anu all industries, but the experience of countries which have tried to bargain toughly sVggests a low supply elasticity.4/ An essential feature of the market for technology then is that it is non- competitive; consequently there is considerable (extent unknown) area for bargain- ing, as the price may vary between an upper limit determined by costs of repro- ducing the technology and a lower limit determined by costs of imparting the in- formation. The important potential role of policy arises from this indeterminacy, 1J Vaitsos (1974) 2/ Carlsen and Hufbauer (1978) _| Vaitsos (1974) 4/ See evidence of Mytelka (1977); experience of Japan. - 37 - Technology Transfer and Independence Independence of decision making is valued in itself by some - hence the resentment of foreign ownership of a large proportion of a country's assets. But it is also necessary for the achievement of other aims. Restrictions on freedom of decision making tend to increase costs and reduce the firm's ability to be selective about technological choice, and to learn and to generate an independent technological capacity. Independence of decision making is obviously absent in the case of wholly owned subsidiaries of foreign companies. Nationalization of assets, joint ven- tures and restrictions on the shares of equity that foreign compi-lies may hold are policies that have been adopted in large part in order to preserve independence of decision making. But close scrutiny of technology contracts of joint ventures or national firms has revealed a very considerable degree of restriction on independence of decision making. A typology of restrictions was shown in Table 4. Vaitsos' research in the Andean Pact showed - in addition to iestrictions on exports and tie-in clauses already discussed - restrictions on prices, on volume of sales, on quality control and on the sale of technology.- A study-/ in Argen- tina showed that licensing agreements with wholly locally owned firms included clauses such as: source of inputs of machinery, materials, spare parts; prices and quantity of output; export outlets permitted; restraints on the dymamic effect of the transfer - e.g. non-transference of patents, restrictions on local R and D. Similar restrictions were found in a study of Indian firms.-/ For example, 23 percent of the agreements examined involved some restrictions on local sales (type, quantity, price) while over half involved restrictions on exports.4/ 1/ Vaitsos (1971) p. 20. 2/ Sercovicli (1972) 3/ Subralimanian (1972) 4/ See als.o M;aovelle (1974); Oxman and Sagnsto (1972). - 38- Changing the ownership structure is thus insufficient to secure independence of decision making. Indeed technology contracts have been described as "a mechanism of control of the recipient firms." -/ Direct purchase of technology, through, e.g., use of the experience of personnel, purchase of machinery, copying imported products, avoids this sort of re- striction. But for most countries, this is a possibility only for the simpler products and techniques. As noted earlier, even emong the simpler technologies, a tendency has been observed foi foreign owned and mixed firms to purchase technologies via technology contracts. A different approach - now followed by an increasing number of countries-/ - is to outlaw restrictive clauses. But outlawing cannot always ensure de facto elimination of the practices. 1/ Vaitsos (1971), p. 21. 2/ See UNIDO (1978): e.g. South Korea, the Andean Pact Countries, Brazil - see below. -- 39 Learning Effects of Technology Tra sfer The ability to make independent technological choices, to ada?t and improve upon chosen techniques and products, and eventually to generate new technology endogenously are essential aspects of the process of development. The process may be described as the accumulation of technological capacity; it is at least as important to economic development as the accumulation of capital. The accumulation of technological capacity is the outcome of a complex series of forces. One significant element is 'learning by doing'; another is an educational, infrastructural and institutional setting which both permits and encourages the learning process. Both aspects are crucial, although in the past policy has tended to overemphasize the institutional side, which is most obviously amenable to government policy, and underestimate the 'learning by doing' side. Weak links between an elaborate institutional structure and industrial and learning by doing activities have tended to 'marginalize' the 1/ activities of the scientific institutions.- The accumulation of technological capacity is not a simple, easily described activity. It cannot be measured in a straight forward way at either macro ur micro levels. At a macro-level, residual methods of measuring technical change, suggest the substantial significanice of increases in productivity which are not explained by increases in inputs. But these methods are highly dubious because of the probleins of attributing increases in output to increases in input. Moreover, in a developing country context they exaggerate the extent of indigenously generated technological change, since in part the technical 1/ See Hierrera (1973), Cooper (1973) and Sagasti (1978). - 40 - change identified is due to improved imported techniques; on the other hand, the measure in no way captures the development of independence of decision- making which is an important element in the accumulation of technological capacity. Micro-case studies throw more light on the process. Again, precise measurement is not possible, but rmicro-studies of technological change do pinpoint the significance of such change and also suggest the myriad causes. Maxwell's study of a steel plant :Ln Argentina, for example, showed that (endogencusly generated) technological change, was responsible for over half the increase in output capacity. The causes of the technological change he attributed to exogenously determined changes in demand (leading to the need to diversify output), exogenously determined changed in operating conditions (e.g., deterioration in the quality of available scrap), and endogenously generated changes arising from routine activities of engineers, etc. The exogenous causes were of the greatest significance. The form the technical change took varied - from major changes in process, to minor changes in procedure. The agents if the changes included people transfer from elsewlhere in Argentina, the employment of foreign consultants and the firms'own engineering department. There is a complex relationship between the import of technology and the development of local technological capacity - one that encompasses both conflicts and complementarities. The import of technology is a necessary, or at the very least helpful, part of the learning process in many countries and for many industries - either by providing an essential input into the learning process or by pennitting the country to bypass the slow process of reinventing the wheel. On the other hand, the unrestricted inflow of foreign technology may severely inhibit the learning process. - 41 - The development of local t.chnological capacity may be roughly class'fied as a three stage process. In the first stage, the capacity for independent -E;rch and choice is developed; in the second, minor technical changes (which may add up to major changes in terms of quantitative impact) are generated localvy- the third, new technology is developed indigenously. The third stage is unl'.:ely to occur unless the f'irst two are well established. Different types of capacity are necessary for each of the stages; in the first two entrepreneurial and engineering capacity are required rather than formal R. and D., while formal '. and D. may be necessary, in many cases, for the generation of new technology. Government policy which has concentrated on formal R. and D. in government financed research laboratories has tended to neglect the first two stages al:'.ough they are necessary precursors to the effective use of the results of the for-.al R. and D. The impact of foreign teLcnology inflow is likely to be different according to the stage reached, local scientific and technological capacity, the form w'iich the foreign technology iniflow takes, and the industry concerned. Unregulated technology inflow in packaged form may inhibit or delay each stage, but part..cularly stages 1 and 3. Yet, some import of technology is likely to be an essential input to each stage. In relation to stage 1 - the capacity for independent technological choice - use of foreign technology, in packaged form, tends to lidit independent choice. In the case of wholly-owned subsidiaries, decisions about choice of techniques remain those of the foreign company. Where technology is licensed, there is more freedom of choice but, as is to be expected, the parent company (of mixed firms), or the licensor determines the source of machinery to be used in mary - 42 - cases. -/ Limitations on decision making, which as already described form part of many technology contracts, limit the freedom to make a choice and consequently the possibility of learning how to do so. The effects are not confined to the immediate decision covered by the licence but tend to carry forward to the next set of decisions: thus, Mytelka found that firms that licensed their technology were overwhelmingly likely to expect that they would acquire future technology in the same form. In contrast, and not surprisingly, firms that acquired technology by direct means -/ generally were expected to be able to generate new technology in the siL-e way. The second stage of accumulation of technological capacity - minor changes and adaptations generated locally - is largely unrelated to the extent of foreign technology inflow. It oc:curs in response to local pressures for adaptatior and change. Imported tec:hnology may provide the basic technology subject to thls kind of technologicaLl change. Local changes are generated as a re- sult of the need to expand and diversify output, and in response to cost pressures. Bot] Kntz and MRxb.T11 show.r s1.9nificant changes of this type occurring in subsidia- ric!s of maultinational companies, 0.ere the basic technology was imported. The changes reqouired a certain initial engineering capacity, but in turn the learning process generated through the changes created additional technological capacity. We have much too little evidence on change of this type to know whether there is any systematic relationship with quantity or form of technology transfer, any systematic relationship with competitive environment (national l/ liytelka (19 Oh). Of thiose licensing, 67% did ilot choose their own machinery - these inclulded 91% of foreign firms, 100% of State firms and 44% of national firms. 2/ Nine,-y-Seven percent of firms which licensed their technology said they would be unable to dcvelop tLheir uwn technology for new products; 73% of firms which nicquired technology ir; othe .ays, said they would be able to develop their own teclhnology for new products (defined as acquiring it other than through 3 ,:vtiI i&, . - 43 - I ot international, although a priori. reasoning leads one to expect some), I/ or with other variables. Nor can we say, at this point, how far the results are cumulative leading to acceleratir;g technical change of this type, to the 2/ next stage of technological development, or to technology exports.- The third stage - generation of new techniques - is likely to be inhibited by weaknesses in the earlier stages. One outcome of weakness in decision making capacity is inability to generate technology autonomously.3/ To some extent, development of local technological capacity is an infant industry, requiring protection from outdide competition it it is to be established. The free import of technology inhibits its development in a number of ways: it provides a reliable (and sometimes relatively cheap) source of technology as compared with the risks of own development. These risks are not just scientific ones, but include marketing risks. Techniques with a foreign trade-mark have . m0ic certain market compared with techniques developed indigenously. Formal restric-tions on local development of technology and/or the use of locally- develovpc:d techniques form part of some technology contracts.A4/ Most foreign- owned firms prefer to rely on their central research and development laboratories, and do not conduct R. and D. in the developing countries.5/ Recently, it has been the policy of some large U.S. companies to shift some of their R. and D. overseas, 6 but the shift has been almost exclusively to developed countries. 1/ Sercovich (1978) has suggested that the extent of such change will depend in part on the initial design (whether 'underdesigned' or 'overdesigned') which in turn depends on initial conditions. 2/ Katz and Ahblin (1978) suggest a sort of product cycle in technology: the import of technology leads to the development of local technology in respcnse to environmental pressures, and then to the export of technology to countries with similar environments. They illustrate with a few cases in Argentina. 3/ Again, the Mytelka study supports this showing a close connection between freedom of choice of machinery and a belief in the firms ability to generate its own technology in future. 4/ See UNCTAD, (1975), TD/B/AC.ll/l0/Rev. 2, paras. 83-89. 5/ The SPRU study showed that foreign firms did little or no R. and D. in Latin America. 6/ See Ronstadt (1977). - 44 - Sagasti reporting on the IDRC study of science and technology policy instruments which included research in ten less developed countries, concludes that "Although technology imports do not always hamper the growth of domestic science and technology capabilities, the wholesale importation of technology without efforts to screen, control and absorb it usually stunts the growth of domestic science and technology capabilities." (My underlining) While a selective approach to the import of technology may be necessary to protect and encourage local technological development, positive, promotional policies are also required. The most successful examples of technology promotion have combined selective imports of foreign technology with many positive promotional measures: at a macro-level Japan's policies provide a very good example. Micro examples include PEMEX in Mexico and fertilizer developments in India.l/ It is clear that the appropriate set of policies will vary according to the industry as well as local technological capacity. In some technologically complex industries, most LDCs will need to continue to rely on imported technology for some time, and at this stage are in a position only to learn to Lhoose and to adapt in minor ways. In less complex industries, many countries may be in a 2/ position to generate technology themselves.- ;- Giving special promotion (plus protection) to local technological developments may involve (as with other such promotional policies) short run costs, in terms of reduced eff'ciency. This is in part a question of the 1/ Roberts (1973) 2/ Cooper (1976) provides a classification of industries along these lines. - 45 - opportunity costs of the resources levoted to technological developments, and in part of any inferiority of the local technology as compared with the foreign alternative. Exclusive ise of promotional policies (with no restrictions on foreign technology) will avoid the second kind of loss, but, it seems likelv, at the cost of making local efforts more ineffective. There are three different types of reason why countries may consider these costs justified: first, because technological independence is an aim in itself. Secondly, because there are externalities of local technological developments which are not captured by the firm, but which benefit the economy (e.g., as a result of the learning experience, which individuals take to other firms). Thirdly, because short run losses are believed to be outweighed by long run gains-/- the infant industry argument. 11 It must also be assumed that government objectives differ from those of individual firras either because of externalities or because of attitude towards time. - 46 - V. Policies Towards the Import of Technology Relevant policies vary according to the objective, but there is considerable overlap: some instruments serve more than one objective, while the objectives themseJves are interrelated and mutually enforcing. For example, policies which increase independence also tend to improve bargain- ing strength. The effectiveness of different policies depends in part on the general economic strategy of the country; it also depends on other poli- cies towards technology. This is particularly true with respect to the promotion of local technological development, where policies towards foreign technology are only a small part of the total effort needed.-/Relevant and appropriate policies will vary according to the stage of development of the country, its administrative and technological capacity, and according to the industry. As seen above, the free and unselective import of foreign tech- nology has involved a high cost (clirectly and indirectly), has limited independence of decision making and, to _ome extent, the learning effects of the technology. Policies towards the import of technology are designed to reduce these effects.- Many of the policies considered below are primarily aimed at reducing the cost of imported technology:, this may be secured by changing the form of technology inflow towards less packaged alternatives, by 1/ See the many policies described in Sagasti (1978). 2/ "Although there is recognition of the country's dependence on foreign technology, an important objective of this legislation is to gain a degree of control over this major import, botli in terms of cost and of technological impact." (UJ4IDO, 1978, p. 3). This statement of the Mexican Governmlent is representative of the intentions of many govern- ments active in this area. - 47 - avoiding duplicated i,nports, by outlawing restrictive clauses of technology imports, and by reducing the value attributed to the marketing aspects of technology. To date, most concentration - at UNCTAD and in developing countries - has been devoted to the question of the direct cost of tech- nology transfer, although few countries have effective policies. The balance of the discussion below on specific policies reflects this, despite the fact that the question of accumulation of technological capacity is probably of greater long run significance than the costs of any particular transaction. However, many countrie- are not yet in a position to generate their own technology to a significant extent - nor do they have the administra- tive and technological capacity to pursue the kind of screening policies required. For these countries, the policies towards costs are the most relevant. While it may be argued that the administrative costs of such policies are high, the 'success' stories have shown that the cost savings are also high and in most cases easily outweigh administrative costs. However, more research is needed on the real effectiveness of regulatory policies, in the long run, including an investigation of the extent to which formal restrictions replace formal ones. Some of the policies aimed at reducing the costs of technology imports will also contribute to increasing technological capacity: for example, less packaged alternatives tend to involve less costs, and also more freedom of decision making. Outlawing of restrictive clauses normally also outlaws restrictions on learning and research. Policies reducing the significance of foreign trademarks will help protect local technology. But effective policies towards promoting technology capacity extend well beyond those related to cost reductions. Selectivity towards foreign technology imports designed to protect local developments requires an assessment of local potential - 48 - in each area, permitting technology imports where these are likely to induce local innovations but preventing them where they are likely to inhibit them. This clearly is a delicate task involving considerable judgment on the part of policy makers. Many countries lack the administrative capacity and technological awareness to pursue this type of policy across the board. However, screening policies can be adopted on an industry-by-industry basis, starting with the industries where there is most local potential. Policies to promote local technological developments must also contain a strong positive promotional element, pursued simultaneously with screening poli- cies towards foreign technology. Thus, as indicated by the varying ex- perience in this area, policies towards technology imports and promotion are not all-or-nothing, but rather can be pursued at a different level, according to the objectives of the country and its administrative and tech- nological capacity. Economic Strategy and Technology Policy The general economic strategy -f a country strongly influences technological developments.- This is most obvious - and most significant - in relation to the question of appropriate technology, where policies towards income distribution, trading strategy, factor prices and credit availability are critical in determining the choice of products and tech- niques. These relationships will be discussed more below. But the general economic strategy is also of significance in relation to the other dimensions. 1/ "Explicit science and technology instruments are those intended to affect directly the decisions having to do with the growth of local S and T capabilities; implicit ones are those that affect decision making indirectly through second-order effects. The great weight, both in number and influence, of the latter limits the potential impact of the former." (Sagasti). - 49 Thus, the potential for charging excessive prices for techrology is much greater in a non-competitive en'rironment. Hence the worst examnples of under-invoicing tend to occur in industries which are heavily protected, and in which, as a result there is considerable potential for making ex- cessive profits. Lack of competition is partly a national problem, partly an international one. Industries which are technologically sophisticated often lack effective competition on a world basis, and in such cases national policies alone cannot be effective Ji eliminating the source of non-competitiveness and, therefore, the excessive prices. An important source of non-competitiveness occurs via trademarks, advertising and product differentiation. In economies, in which this type of market structure is predominant, excessive costs of technology imports are likely. Technology policies may be designed to offset these effects (e.g. by regulating the prices paid, investigating invoicing and so on), but so long as the funda- mental causes remain, the policies may well prove to be only nominally effective. The general economic and technological environment is also of significance in determining the rate of accumulation of technological capacity. But simple generalizations about the relationship between trade and pricing policies and indigenous technlcal change are not possible at this stage. It is necessary first to distinguish between protection/ competition in the market for goods and that in the market for technology. As already suggested, some protection in the market for technology may be necessary to protect local technology, and this will extend to those goods - 50 - (notably capital goods) in which technology is embodied. But this is the reverse of the form which protection normally takes, where capital goods and technology are subject to very little or no protection, while consumer goods are subject to hcavy protection.-L It has been claimed that "in general, import substitution policy and full-scale protection of consumer goods industry have tended to promote a passive attitude to the utilization and development of indigenous R and D efforts during the early phase of indus- trial development ."-This claim seems to be borne out by case studies of Brazil and Ghana.-/ Yet micro-studies of technical change suggest that trading policies may not be of major significance. Examples of quite substantial indigenous technical change have been found in both open and closed economies.-/The success of countries such as Argentina and India - both heavily protected economies - in developing technology exports-/ challenge the view that an open trading strategy and undistorted factor prices are necessary for the generation of technical change. Technological developments are uiost likely where there already exists a certain amount of technological capacity, in the form of engineer- ing resources and an innovative attitude on the part of entrepreneurs, 1/ For example, in Indonesia the amalgamated tariff trade and sales tax on capital goods and basic industrial inputs is 5%, that on intermediate inputs 25% and on manufactured consumer goods,. 50-70%. (See World Bank, Indonesia, Basic Economic Report, 1979). 2/ Nam Kee Lee (1975) 3/ Beranek and Ranis (1978) 4/ See the work of Katz and others in the IDB/ECLA Research Programme in Science and Technology. 5/ See Katz and Ablin (1978) and Lall (1978). -- 51 managers and worl