Policy, Reseurch, and External Affairs 1
WORKING PAPERS                                      ' ,-
Public Economics
Country Economics Department
The World Bank
August 1990
WPS 490
The Coordinated Reform
of Tariffs and Domestic
Indirect Taxes
Pradeep Mitra
Tariff reform for trade liberalization must be seen as part of a
broader program of tax reforn. Customs duties on imports
should be geared chiefly to protection. Reductions in such duties
to promote an outward-oriented development strategy should be
offset by increases in sales/value-added taxes applied equally to
imports and domestic production. That would maintain public
revenues and avoid exacerbating macrceconomic difficulties
The Policy, Research, and External Affaus Complex distobutes PRI' Working Papers to disseminate the finduings of work in progress and
to encourage the exchange of ideas among Bank suff and aU others interested in development issues. Tese papers carry the names of
the authors, renect only) their vicws, and should he used and cited accordingly. Te findungs, interpretations, and conclusions are the
authors' own 1hey should not bc atLnbuted to thc World llank, its Board of Directors, its managmesnt, or any of its member countnes.



; Policy, Research, and-External Affairs
Public Economics
WPS 490
This paper- a product of the Public Economics Division, Country Jconomics Department -is part of an ongoing
program in the Public Economics Division to explore the relationship between trade liberalization and the public
finances in revenue-constrained economics. The paper was prepared for the World Bank Confercnce on Tax Policy
in Developing Countries, held in March 1990. Copies are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW,
Washington DC 20433. Please contact Ann BhalHa, room N10-059, extension 37699 (47 pages).
Tariff reduction designed to move toward an outward-     * Zero rating of exports under the VAT.
oriented development strategy will work only if          * Taxes on selected exports either where world
alternative revenue sources can be found to offset     demand for the country's exports is expected to
revenue losses that often accompany reduced protec-    remain inelastic or where the country is subject to
tion. The reason is that such losses can exacerbate    export quotas.
macroeconomic difficulties, lead to delays or reversals
in trade liberali7ation programs, and make policy          It is important to view the foregoing elements as
change less credible.                                  part of an interrelatcd package: for example, attempts
to unify customs duties at levels higher than the
Tariffs on imports do two things: protect          recommend&d range would create administrative
domestic producers and raise public revenues. Even     problems in implementing duty exemptions on inputs
the poorest countries have essentially two instruments  entering domestic production.
for fulfilling those two objectives: (i) customs duties
and (ii) sales taxes and value-added taxes (VATs) on       Coordinated reform of an existing distoned
imports. Since the customs duty raises the price       structure of tariffs and domestic taxes would include
facing domestic produccrs of an imported good above    the following:
the world price, it is a subsidy to domestic producers.
Since the sales tax/value-added tax, together with the   e Matching the sales and value-added tax rates on
customs duty, raises the price facing users of the     domestic production and imports, to transfer the
impon above the world price, they tax domestic users.    function of protection to customs duties.
The customs duty can then serve protection objec-        * Bringing customs duties on items for which there
tives, while the two together can be designed to meet  is no domestic production and which are therefore
revenue requirements.                                  purely revenue-raising under the rubric of the sales
tax/ value-added tax.
Opportunities for radical redesign of the incentive  * Offsetting any reduction in customs duties with
structure are rare. TIhe following integrated structure  an equivalent increase in the sales tax/value-added tax
of taxes cum tariffs provides a point of reference     structure - which, since that tax applies to domestic
toward which less comprehensive reforms may be         production as well as imports, would increase
directed:                                              revenues. A smaller-than-equivalent upward adjust-
ment in the sales value-added structure would
* A uniform basic customs duty of no more than      therefore suffice if the change were required to be
10-15 percent and an exemption from duty for           revenue-neutal.
imported inputs entering export production.
* A basic uniform VAT (preferably on consump-            More realistically, the rate structure might have
tion) - the rate determined by revenue requirements    to be raised beyond the point of revenue-neutrality to
- on both domestic production and imports with         allow for assistance to sectors hurt by the tariff
agriculture exempted, particularly nonmarketed food    reduction. Such assistance, if extended through the
consumed by the poor.                                  budget process, would have the advantage vis-a-vis
* A luxury or excise tax applied at a common rate    protective tariffs of being explicit and thus subject to
to both domestic production and imports of selected    periodic scrutiny.
items.
Thc PRE Working Paper Scries disseminates the findings of Work under way in the Bank's Policy, Research, and Extemal
AffairsComplcx. An objective ofthc scrics is to gct thcse findings out quickly, even if prescntations are lcss than fully polished.
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions in these papers do not necessarily represent official Bank policy.
Produced by the PRE Dissemination Center



The Coordinated Reform of Tariffs and Domestic Indirect Taxes
by
Pradeep Mitra
Table of Contents
I.    Introduction                                                  5
The Setting                                                   5
Plan of the Paper                                             6
II.   World Bank Advice                                             6
Tariff Reform                                                 6
Tax Reform                                                    7
III.   Tax and Tariff Instruments                                   8
IV.   The Design of Taxes-cum-Tariffs                              16
Producer Prices and World Prices                             17
Structure of Protection                                      18
Level of Protection                                          19
Summary of Tariff Recommendations                           20
The Treatment of Intermediate Inputs                         20
Consumer Prices and World Prices                            24
Structure of Consumption Taxes                              25
Summary of Tax Recommnendations                             29
Exports                                                     30
Optimal Policis versus Rules of Thumb                       32
V.    The Reform of Taxes-cum-Tariffs                              35
Nontariff Import Restrictions                               35
Tariff Reduction                                             36
Matching Sales Tax/VAT                                      36
Adjusting Taxes for Revenue                                  37
Revenue and Protection Constraints on Reform                39
Towards Explicit Assistance                                  41
VI.   Conclusions                                                  42
References                                                         46
*     This paper has been prepared for the World Bank Conference on Tax Policy in
Developing Countries. March 28 to 30, 1990.



THE COORDINATED REFORM OF TARIFFS AND
DOMESTIC INDIRECT TAXES
Pradeep Mitra
Tariffs on imports protect domestic producers and raise public revenue.
Thus the World Development Report 1987 finds that effective rates of protection
to manufacturing in developing countries typically exceed 40 percent while the
World Development Report 1988 estimates that the importance of import taxes in
tax revenue is over 20 percent in Asia, sub-Saharan Africa and in the Middle East
and North Africa compared to 2 percent in the industrial countries.   These
figures make clear that tariff reform which is intended to reduce anti-export
bias and promote an outward-oriented development strategy can be viable only if
alternative and administratively collectible sources of revenue can be found to
offset potential revenue losses. The tradeoff between liberalization and fiscal
imperatives is thus frequently central to tariff reform.
This paper argues that tariff reform must be seen as part of a broader
program of tax reform. The need to adopt such a public finance perspective is
argued with reference to selective reviews of country experience with trade
liberalization and tax reform, protection and revenue objectives in developing
countries and the instruments available to further those policy goals. The main
points emerging from the analysis are as follows.
1.   Since it is generally accepted that lack of supportive macroeconomic
policies has led to delays or reversal in trade liberalization programs, it is
important that potential losses in public revenue arising from tariff reductions
be offset so as not to exacerbate macroeconomic difficulties.   The common
practice of pursuing tariff and tax studies independently carries the risk that
the revenue implications of tariff reform and the implications for protection



2-
and efficiency of tax reform may not be properly integrated, with negative
consequences for the credibility of policy change.
2.   The adoption of a more comprehensive public finance perspective on
policy reform is made possible by the fact that even the poorest countries have
essentially two sets of instruments for the taxation of imports: (a) customs
duties and (b) sales taxes/value added taxes, that: are usually levied on the
customs duty-inclusive value of imports and that apply to domestic transactions
as well. Since the customs duty raises the price facing producers of an import
above the world price, it is a subsidy to domestic producers. Since the sales
tax/value added tax, together with the customs duty, raises the price facing
users of the import above the world price, they constitute a tax on domestic
users.  The customs duty can then serve protection objectives, while the two
together can be designed to meet revenue requirements.  These tax and subsidy
margins play a useful role in the discussion on tariff reform under point 5
below.
3.   While the opportunities for radical redesign of the incentive structure
are rare, the following integrated structure of taxes cum tariffs provides a
point of reference towards which less comprehensive reforms may be directed.
This comprises (a) a basic customs duty at a uniform rate of no more than 10 to
15 percent, (b) a basic value added tax, preferably of the consumption type,
applying at a uniform rate, depending on revenue requirements, to domestic
production and imports, and exempting agriculture, in particular nonmarketed food
consumed by the poorest, (c) a luxury rate or excises applying at a common rate
to domestic production and imports of selected items, (d) zero rating of exports
under the value added tax, (e) exemption of imported inputs entering export
production from customs duty, and (f) taxes on selected exports either where



world demand for the country's exports is expected to remain inelastic or where
the country is subject to export quotas. The paper argues that it is important
to view the above elements as part of an interrelated package so that, for
example, attempts to unify customs duties at levels higher than the recommended
range [as in (a)) would create administrative problems in implementing duty
exemptions on inputs entering export production [point (e)].
4.   The above prescriptions must be regarded as rules of thumb that can
generate broadly acceptable outcomes in terms of efficiency, equity and
protection and that should be flexibly applied in the light of country
circumstances and administrative capability. They are not properties of optimal
tariff and tax structures. Thus the value to policy advisors of analytically-
oriented studies of taxes and tariffs would be enhanced if the latter were to
identify circumstances where the pursuit of such rules is likely to be
inappropriate, rather than construct empirically implausible special cases where
they hold exactly.
5.   The coordinated reform of an existing distorted structure of tariffs
and domestic taxes in accordance with the above principles will include the
following components. The sales tax/VAT rates on domestic production and imports
should be matched, so as to transfer the function of protection to customs
duties. Customs duties on items for which there is no domestic production and
which are therefore purely revenue-raising should be brought under the rubric
of the sales tax/VAT.  A lowering of customs duties to reduce the excess of
producer prices over world prices (the element of protection), if unaccompinied
by other measures, would also reduce the excess of user prices over world prices
(the customs duty-cum-sales tax on users) and thus erode public revenue. Hence
reduction of protection per se, interpreted as a narrowing of the wedge between



producer prices and world prices, is achieved by combining the lowering of
customs duties with an equal upward adjustment to the sales tax/VAT structure
to restore the tax wedge between user prices and world prices prevailing before
the tariff reduction.  This, however, would be revenue-enhancing because the
sales tax/VAT applies to imports as well as domestic consumption, so that the
higher rate structure, while exactly offsetting the revenue loss from customs
duties on imports, would bring in more revenue from domestic consumption. If
the objective is simply to offset the revenue losses from tariff reductions, a
smaller adjustment to the sales tax/VAT structure than the one described above
will suffice. More realistically, the rate structure would need to be raised
somewhat beyond the point of revenue neutrality so as to allow the government
to meet such demands for adjustment assistance as may arise from sectors
adversely affected by tariff reductions. Such assistance, if extended via the
budgetary process, would have the advantage vis-a-vis protective tariffs of being
explicit and thus subject to periodic scrutiny.



-5-
I. INTRODUCTION
The Setting
1.       The value of adopting an outward-oriented development strategy has found
increasing acceptance among economists.' The move towards outward orientation
requires, inter afia, that countries reduce the bias against exports caused by
the extensive use of tariffs and quantitative restrictions on imports. Thus,
for example, the World Development Report, 1987 found that effective rates of
protection to manufacturing in the late 1970s were as high as 44% in the
Philippines, 5'. in Colombia and 82% in Nigeria and, with the exception of Korea
and Singapore, that effective rates of protection were lower for exports vis-
a-vis domestic sales.
2.       It is now generally accepted that trade liberalization can be delayed
or aborted in the absence of complementary macroeconomic policies, in particular
appropriate fiscal policies.2  With public sector deficits averaging 7% of GDP
in developing countries,3 it is particularly imports ' that revenue losses
arising from tariff reductions be offset by identifying alternative and
administratively collectible sources of revenue so as not to exacerbate
macroeconomic difficulties. That these could be potentially significant emerges
from the World Development Report 1988 which estimated that the contribution of
import taxes to tax revenue in 1985 was 14% in Latin America, 21% in Asia, 22%
in the Middle East and North Africa and 26% in sub-Saharan Africa, as compared
to 2% in industrial countries.   The tradeoff between moves towards outward
orientation and fiscal imperatives is thus frequently central to policy reform.
'For an authoritative account, see Balassa (1989a).
2The relevant literature is cited in Halevi (1988).
3Based on a sample of 33 countries in 1986, as reported in Chhibber and K.
Shirazi (1988).



-6-
Plan of the Paper
3.       This paper argues that tariff reform must be seen as part of a broader
program of tax reform. Section II outlines advice that is typically given on
tariff and tax reform and points to instances where the two have been
insufficiently coordinated.   Section III looks at the instruments used by
d_veloping countries to further protection and revenue objectives. Section IV
lays out the contours of tax and tariff design in the light of efficiency and
equity objectives and constraints on administrative capacity in developing
countries. Section V eximines how those ides may be used to guide the reform
of tax and tariff structures. Section VI brings together the main points of the
paper.
II. WORLD BANK ADVICE
Tariff Reform
4.       Trade policy reform has been an important component of the World Bank's
dialogue with countries and has accounted for 30% of the conditions in adjustment
lending. [World Bank (1989b)] While details vary from country to country, the
core set of Bank recommendations on the reform of import policy consists in (a)
converting quantitative restrictions and other forms of nontariff licensing into
tariffs; (b) reducing the level and dispersion of tariffs.4  It is recognized
that such a system necessarily discriminates against exports: the bias is offset
in part through a variety of schemes that exempt from tariffs imported inputs
entering into export production.
4A recent review [World Bank (1989b)] describes "a practical first-phase
goal for reforms...is to...reduce tariffs to reasonably low levels, say to a
range of 15 to 30 percent over the medium term."  Another review of policy
recommendations regarding tariff reform in eleven countries [Rajaram (1989)]
noted that "a few reports appeared to favor a long term uniform/maximum effective
rate of protection of about 20%".



-7-
5.       A recent review of Bank recommendations on tariff reform [Rajaram
(1989)) found however that the revenue implications were not addressed
systematically.     Thus,  to give a few examples,  a 1984 recommendation to
eliminate the Special Import Tax in Morocco miscalculated the revenue impact
which, together with the poor initial performance of the value added tax, led
to a subsequent tariff increase. A similar situation obtained in Thailand in
1981 because proposals for alternative sources of revenue focussed oil one-time
increases rather than elasticity-enhancing tax reform. The revenue effect also
appeared to have been underestimated in the Philippines. The government then
introduced an across-the-board import tax and a domestic turnover tax to raise
revenue, but this is ascribed more to the deterioration of the economy in 1983-
86 than to tariff reform. The program of import liberalization was, however,
stalled by those developments.
Tax Reform
6.       The Bank had not till recently been active in offering tax policy advice
based on a detailed assessment of tax instruments and options. Data for 1987-
89 indicates, however, a more active involvement compared say to the period 1980-
86. In Malawi, the Bank recommended that t.riffs be reduced on competing imports
and intermediate goods and eliminated aitogether on noncompeting imports.   The
r venue losses were to be made up by raising the surtax which, with the
introduction of crediting mechanisms, could be turned into a manufacturer/import
level consumption tax. In Bangladesh, it was estimated that the revenue impact
of tariff reduction in selected key industrial sectors would amount to roughly
1.5 percent of tax revenue. The Bank proposed a wide-ranging package of refozm
designed (i) to raise revenue in the short run and (ii) to enhance the elasticity
of the tax system in the medium-to-long term via structural tax reform.   More



-8-
generally, the recommended reform of indirect taxation proposed in various
countries usually consists in moving towards a value added tax or a single-
stage sales tax, with symmetric treatment of domesti! production and imporcs.
7.       A selective review of Bank involvement with tariff and tax reform
studies [Rajaram (1989)] suggests that the two sets ot exercises are tc a large
extent conducted separately. It has already been noted that tariff studies have
generally not addressed revenue issues systematically. Nor has enough attention
always been paid to the protective role of domestic tax-subsidy instruments that,
in addition to tariffs, extend favorable treatment to local producers. In turn,
tax studies, while recommending symmetric treatment of domestically produced and
imported goods, have left analysis of the structure and level of protective
customs duties to tariff studies.   This separation has an obvious practical
advantage from the point of view of the management of tasks. It also has the
apparent virtue of not straining absorptive capacity of policy makers in
countries where such resources are often scarce, although the policy reversals
that have occurred in the examples noted above as a result of not addressing
budgetary concerns potentially compromised the credibility of reform. It will
be argued in this paper that a coordinated trade-cum-public finance perspective
on these issues is much to be desired.5
III. TAX AND TARIFF IN .AUMENTS
I.       The taxation of imports usually consists of (i) a customs duty that
applies to the c.i.f. price and (ii) a sales tax/VAT that is levied on the
5The need to integrate trade taxes with domestic taxes in a common framework
has also been argued in Shalizi and Squire (1989) and Linn and Wetzel (1989).



-9-
customs duty-inclusive price. Tables 1 through 5 report the use of those (and
other) instruments in Bangladesh, Malawi, Nepal, Tanzania and Uganda which, with
per capita incomes of $160, $160, $160, $180 and $260 respectively in 1987, are
among the poorest low income countries.6 It may be seen that the sales tax on
imports is a significant revenue source even in the three sub-Saharan African
countries where import taxes do not loom as large as in the two South Asian
countries.
9.       The tables allow the following important points to be made.  First, even
the poorest countries use (at least) two different policy instruments to tax
imports,  a feature that has considerable sigr ficance.   This point may be
illustrated using a simple example. Suppose that the c.i.f. price of an imported
good in local currency is 100. The customs duty is 20% and the sales tax which
is levied on the customs duty-inclusive price as well as on domestic production
c.f the good is 10%.  Assuming the absence of nontariff import licensing, the
price that domestic producers can charge for the good is the c.i.f. price
plus customs duty, or 120. In this example, the customs duty is a measure of
the subsidy extended by the incentive system to producers.  Thp customs duty
also raises the price of the good to the user above its international price
(from 100 to 120), providing the basis for the standard observation that a tariff
is a subsidy to a domestic producer financed by a tax on the user. Since the
tax component of the customs duty raises the price to users of domestic
production as well as imports, while its subsidy component applies only to
domestic production, the tax revenue from users exceeds the outlay on the subsidy
to producers; for this reason, the tariff is revenue-raising. The customs duty,
however, is not the only tax on users of the good. That is given by the customs
6World Bank (1989a).



- 10 -
Table 1. Composition if Indirect Tax Revenue in Bangladesh, 1987/88 a/
Tax Base             Imported           Domestic
Tax Type                          Goods                Goods             Total
Customs Duty               37.8                                  37.8
Sales Tax                  12.4                -                 12.4
Excise Duty                 -                 26.8               26.8
Total                      50.2               26.8               77.0
a/  Figures are percent of total tax revenue.
Notes:
1.  The customs duty is levied on the c.i.f. value of imports.  The sales
tax, which applies only to imports, is levied on the customs duty-
inclusive value.
2.  The excise duty is levied on the ex-factory price of domestically
produced goods.



- 11 -
Table 2. Composition of Indirect Tax Revenue in Malawi, 1988 a/
Tax Base             Imported           Domestic
Tax Type                          Goods               Goods             Total
Import Duties             17.8                 -                 17.8
Surtax                    13.7               20.2                33.9
Excise Duty                -                   3.5                3.5
Total                     31.5               23.7                55.2
a/  Figures are percent of total tax revenue.
Notes:
1. The import duty is levied on the c.i.f. value of imports.
2. The excise duty is levied on the ex-factory price of domestically
produced goods.
3. The surtax is levied on the import duty-inclusive price of imports and the
excise duty-inclusive ex-factory price of domestically produced goods.



- 12 -
Table 3. Composition of Indirect Tax Revenue in Nepal, 1988/89 a/
Tax Base              Imported           Domestic
Tax Type                           Goods              Goods             Total
Import Duty                35.7                 -                 35.7
Excise Tax                  0.7               13.6                14.3
Sales Tax                  11.0               11.8                22.8
Total                      47.4                25.4               72.8
/  Figures are percent of total tax revenue.
Notes:
1.  The import duty is levied on the c.i.f. value of imports.  There is a two-
tiered structure with only the first slab applying to imports from India and
both the first and second slabs applying to imports from other countries.
2.  The excise duty is levied on the ex-factory price for domestic goods.
It applies to imports and domestic goods at the same rate.
3.  The sales tax is levied on the excise and import duty inclusive  c.i.f.
value for imports and the excise tax-inclusive ex-factory price for
domestic goods.   It applies to import and domestic goods at the same
rate.
4.  Sales tax revenue collected from imported inputs is reported as revenue
from domestic goods, so that the 11 percent share reported above is an
underestimate of sales tax collected from imports.



- 13 -
Table 4. Composition of Indirect Tax Revenue in Tanzania, 1988/89 a/
Tax Base             Imported           Domestic
Tax Type                           Goods              Goods             Total
Import Duty                18.6                 -                 18.67
Excise Tax
Sales Tax                  17.2                55.6               72.8
Total                      35.8                25.4               91.4
a/  Figures ax- percent of total tax revenue.
Notes:
1.  The import duty is levied on the c.i.f. value of imports.
2.  The sales tax is levied on the import-duty inclusive value of imports and
the ex-factory price of domestically produced goods. It treats imports and
domestically produced goods in a symmetric way.
3.  An excise tax that  applied to both domestic and imported goods was
introduced in 1989/90. Revenue figures are not as yet available for that
year.



- 14 -
Table 5. Composition of Indirect Tax Revenue in Uganda, 1988/89 a/
Tax Base             Imported           Domestic
Tax Type                           Goods              Goods             Total
Import Duty                17.7                 -                 17.7
Excise Duty                  -                 10.9               10.9
Sales Tax k/               12.0               27.9                39.9
Total                      29.7                38.8               68.5
a/ Figures are percent cf tax revenue.
k/ Imports were subject to a higher rate of sales tax.
Notes:
1.  The import duty is levied on the c.i.f. value of imports.
2.  The excise duty is levied on the ex-factory price of domestic goods.
3.  The sales tax is levied on the import-duty inclusive c.i.f. value of imports
and the excise-duty inclusive ex-factory price of domestic goods.  There
were a number of items for which the sales tax rate on imports exceeded tnat
on the corresponding domestic product.   It is understood however that a
recent change has led to symmetric treatment of domestically produced and
imported goods.



- 15 -
duty plus the sales tax, which together raise the price from 100 to 132, (the
latter figure being arrived at by adding 10% to the customs duty-inclusive
price). Hence, the tax orn the user of the good is 32.
10.      The example suggests that the two instruments could be used to further
the two objectives of providing protection and raising revenue. Provided, as
in the example and in fact in Nepal and Tanzania (see Tables 3 and 4), that the
sales tax/VAT applies at an equal rate to imports and domestic production, the
customs duty may be seen as playing a priniarily protective role, with revenuic
objectives being met by the customs duty togetner with the sales tax/VAT. Thus,
the level and structure of customs duties should be set with reference to
whatever protection objectives are deemed by tile analyst to be supportable. The
sales tax/VAT can then be set at a level that, together with the customs duty,
satisfies the government's revenue requirements.
11.       Second,  although  the  excise  tax  features  separately  in  all  the
countries, it may be thought of as being a combination of both the customs duty
as well as the sales tax. This is because it has revenue raising and protective
aspects as well. The first is oovious. In Nepal (see Table 3), for example,
it has a purely revenue-raising function.   The second may be seen from its
operation in Malawi and Uganda, (see Tables 2 and 5) where the excise duty, by
applying to domestic production only, subtracts from the protection afforded by
import duties. This effect could be reproduced by adjusting import duties and
by offsetting the revenue impact by adjusting the surtax/sales tax.
12.      Third, faced with an array of duties and surcharges on imports, it is
sometimes tempting to recommend that they be consolidated into a single levy for
administrative  simplicity.   The above analysis  shows that this would be a
mistake. Thus, customs duties that apply to imports alone fulfil a different



- 16 -
role from sales taxes that apply to imports as well as domestic production. As
mentioned earlier, the two instruments are aimed at two objectives, viz.,
protection and revenue-raising.   Since both instruments are in use in the
poorect countries and, a fortiori, elsewhere, consolidation would result in
giving up one instrument and reduce the possibility of treating tariffs and
taxes in a consistent way.
IV. THE DESIGN OF TAXES-CUM-TARIFFS
13.      The simple example of Section III showed that
*   the difference between the producer price and the world price
of a good is the subsidy to producers, while
*   the difference between the consumer price and the world price
of a good is the tax on consumers.
This allows us to identify the customs duty with the producer subsidy and the
customs duty-plus-sales tax with the consumer tax.7
14.      This section develops some basic principles of coordinated tax ard
tariff design with a view to clarifying ideas as well as providing a point of
reference towards which reforms may be directed. We first consider the wedge
between producer prices and world prices introduced by customs duties and then
7It will be recalled that the shadow price, or social opportunity cost, of
a traded good for a small economy is the world price, adjusted for trade and
transport margins.   Hence the above statement has the appealing property of
measuring the producer and consumer distortions introduced by the tax-cum-tariff
system vis-a-vis social opportunity costs. While traded goods are the primary
focus of tariff reform analysis, it is clear that changes in taxes and tariffs
consequent on policy reform will affect nontraded goods as well.   It may
therefore be noted, paralleling the description for traded goods, that the wedge
introduced between producer prices and shadow prices of nontraded goods
corresponds to a subsidy, while that between consumer prices and shadow prices
of nontraded goods corresponds to a tax.



- 17 -
turn to the wedge between consumer prices and world rrices caused by the
combined operation of customs duties and sales taxes/VAT.
Producer Prices and World Prices
15.      A classical argument in favor of wedges between producer prices and
world prices is provided by the infant industry argument.8   A variant of this
runs as follows. It is argued that the volume of gross output confers "learning
by doing" type benefits. These eventually lower costs of production and allow
the industry to become competitive in the future.  The argument is therefore
intertemporal: the economy incurs the costs of industrial promotion today in
return for benefits in terms of higher productivity tomorrow.  However, this
does not necessarily translate into an argument for government intervention.
Thus, if private firms can invest in high cost production in the early years and
appropriate the benefits of higher productivity in later years, no intervention
is necessary. Institutional restrictions on appropriability and capital market
imperfections may however preclude such arrangements from being made. Economic
theory would then argue for intervention in labor and capital markets to correct
those distortions, without restricting trade in any way.9    However,  the
administrative capacity to identify and extend subsidies in factor markets may
be lacking in developing countries.   While this might suggest a welfare-
inferior policy of production subsidies extending to all production whether for
domestic sales or exports, it is in practice the case that developing countries
find it easier to assist their producers via an even worse policy.  This of
course is tariff protection which encourages only domestic production and
8For a detailed account, see Corden (1974).
9For a careful statement of the appropriate qualifications, see Baldwin
(1969).



- 18 -
discriminates against exports. Its widespread use may be explained with respect
to its revenue-raising feature as well as the advantage of extending assistance
to favored *;onstituencies in a relatively inconspicuous way.10
16.      The infant industry argument has also been seen to encounter certain
difficulties in practice. A recent Bank report on trade policy reform observed
that "experience with protection policies and their general outcome in the
majority of developing countries suggests that infant industry arguments are
generally used as a rationale by politically powerful protection-seeking
industries, without any serious consideration of whether and under what
conditions the economic benefits of the protection will exceed its economic
costs. Thus the policies seldom recognize that if the initial economic costs
are to be offset, the learning-by-doing benefits (weighted for risks and
discounted for the opportunity cost of the capital invested) must appear in a
period of, say, five to seven years."'1 The report goes on to state that for
these and associated reasons, "the World Bank has usually recommended that
protection not be given to support irndustries".
Structure of Protection
17.      In practice, advisors on tariff design will typically be faced with
import tariffs that are "justified" via a combination of learning-by-doing
arguments unaddressed by other, more targeted policies, effective lobbying by
special interest groups with no particular claim to "infancy" and political
imperatives to keep subsidies hidden (as is the case with tariffs) rather than
'Olt is recognized that the adi.iinistrative capacity to extend domestic
subsidies   as part of an industrial promotion policy as opposed to export-
discouraging tariff policies will vary across countries.
llSee World Bank (1989).



- 19 -
transparent.'?  Since evidence on learning-by-doing and related externalities
across sectors is notoriously elusive, governments experience considerable
difficulty in identifying potentially successful sectors and products for
special encouragement. Economists have then recommended that assistance be made
uniform, on the grounds either that, in the absence of compelling evidence to
the contrary, learning effects might as well be assumed to be roughly the same
across sectors, or that a uniform structure of assistance is less vulnerable to
special pleading. 13   Higher timebound assistance may be provided for a few
selected sectors where there are demonstrable learning externalities.
Level of Protection
18.      It will be recognized that the above arguments on the structure of
protection would be relevant in arriving at a judgment, not only on the
structure of assistance as discussed above, but on its level as well.   One
argument, due to Little, Scitovsky and Scott, sees the need for special
assistance to manufacturii as deriving from the excess of the market wage over
the real cost of labor due to labor market distortions and savings constraints
on the economy. 14 Thus, if wage costs as a proportion of gross value added were
on average 15 percent and the real cost of labor 50 percent of the market wage
(which is likely to be a generous allowance), the extent to which value added
should be assisted is of the order of 5 to 10 percent.   The authors further
argue that in the least developed countries, if the wages of unskilled labor
12We ignore here the departures from free trade that may be justified by the
"new" trade theory.   Their relevance for developing cotntries remains to be
established. See, for example, Srinivasan (1989).
13For a derivation of the relationship between learning-by-doing and
production subsidies, see Mitra (1989). The relationship between structures of
incentives and lobbying however remains to be demonstrated.
14See Little, Scitovsky and Scott (1970).



- 20 -
were as high as 40 percent of value added, the justifiable level of assistance
to value added could be 20%.  While these estimates should be regarded as no
more  than  illustrative,   given  the  considerable  variation  in  country
circumstances governing the relationship between market wages and the real cost
of labor, they provide a rough range within which the average level of
protective tariffs might lie. It may be noted that while this range overlaps
that reported as being characteristic of Bank recommendations (see footnote 4),
the latter is somewhat higher.
Summary of Tariff Recommendations
19.      The  discussion  on  protective  tariffs  may  be  summarized  in  the
observation that a uniform tariff at a level not exceeding 10 to 15 percent
could be adopted as an acceptable rule of thumb in countries where
administrative and revenue constraints preclude extensive use of better targeted
instruments.   While  such a structure of incentives  discriminates against
exports, the 10 to 15% range is thought by practitioners to be low enough so as
to limit the extent of discrimination. The discrimination may be partly offset
by granting exporters duty free access to intermediate inputs. Both common sense
and experience suggest that practical schemes that give effect to such proposals
with regard to imported inputs (duty drawbacks, exemptions, bonded warehouses,
duty free zones, etc.) are easier to administer when tariffs are set at low
levels. This has two significant implications.
The Treatment of Intermediate Inputs
20.      First, access to duty free imported inputs on the part of exporters
implies that domestic producers of such inputs would not be able to compete if
they were to charge duty-inclusive prices.   Thus, for, example,  if garment
exporters can import fabrics free of customs duties, they would have no



-21-
incentive to purchase locally-produced fabrics at duty-inclusive prices. Hence
countries have attempted to allow an "indirect" exporter such as the local
producer of fabrics to import part of his input requirements free of customs
duty. This would offer no protection to domestic producers of fabrics on that
portion of their sales going to garment exporters. If successful, however, the
policy could develop backward linkages and deepen the benefits flowing from
outward orientation.
21.      Second, the difficulty of granting duty free access at high tariff
levels implies that attempts to unify tariffs at levels higher than the 10 to
15 percent range cannot be part of the recommended design. This has generated
the following problem to which some recent work has been addressed. Consider
a situation where tariffs on final goods are 30%, possibly (although this is not
necessary to the argument)  as a result of previous  reform.    Tariffs on
intermediate goods entering into the production of such final goods are low and,
for purposes of this argument, may be taken to be zero. Effective protection
to import-substituting final goods is therefore much higher than may be
"justified" on learning-by-doing or other grounds.   It is assumed that, for
reasons not usually specified, that the tariff may not be reduced any further.
Attention must therefore be directed to indirect ways in which protection may
be reduced. Broadly speaking, two kinds of solutions have been offered. The
first, due to Harberger (1988), observes that an increase in the tariff on
intermediate goods would be one solution.15 In fact, if an intermediate good
accounts for x percent of the value of the final good under free trade, a tariff
on the intermediate good at a level (100/x) times 30% would drive the effective
"5The selective review by Rajaram (1989) suggests that tariff increases on
intermediate goods have been recommended in certain countries.



- 22 -
protection on final goods to zero. Since x < 100, this level of tariff on the
intermediate good would be higher than that on the final good. Harborger does
not in fact recommend that intermediate good tariffs be set at that level.
Instead, it is suggested that a uniform tariff on intermediate and final good
imports is likely to be a satisfactory compromise. The second, due to Shalizi
and Squire (1989), is to impose an additional domestic tax on the production of
final goods without raising the tariff on intermediate goods.
22.      It may be observed that both solutions are revenue-raising and do not
therefore have adverse budgetary consequences. In fact, although this is not
mentioned in either paper, the extra revenue could be used if necessary to meet
demands for adjustment assistance to final good producers adversely affected by
the reduction of protection. We return to this point in Section V. The first
solution, by unifying the tariff structure at the "unalterable" level of 30
percent, runs the considerable risk of making it difficult for developing
country administrators to implement schemes allowing exporters duty free access
to intermediate inputs: the inducemencs to "leakage" from bonded warehouses and
the likelihood of fraudulent claims for duty drawback are too great. It also
offers considerable protection to domestic production of intermediate goods.
In contrast, the second solution, by not raising intermediate good tariffs, does
not complicate duty exemption procedures for exports.  However, it offers no
protection to intermediate goods and does not unify tariffs at a common level.
Under this scheme, there are two sets of tariffs:  a higher uniform rate for
final goods and a lower uniform rate (possibly zero) for intermediate goods,
complemented by an additional levy on domestic production of final goods.16
16It may be noted that this would be an excise tax with negative
consequences for protection of final goods. See paragraph 11 in Section III.



- 23 -
23.      It is a feature of both solutions that the protection of intermediate
goods does not seemn to be an issue. Harberger sees the tariff on intermediates
principally as an instrument to adjust the effective protectiorn to final goods,
while it is implicit in Shalizi and Squire that the need to protect
intermediates is not seen as important in the sub-Saharan African countries
under discussion. If therefore there are no particular grounds for protecting
intermediate  goods,  and  the  only  constraint  is  the  presence  of minimum
"unalterable" tariffs on final goods, hcw is tariff design to be modified? It
has been pointed out that the uniformity argument is based on the absence of
compelling empirical evidence on sectorally differentiated learning-by-doing or
externality arguments. If protection of intermediates is then not relevant, it
is preferable to have low protection for final goods and no protection for
intermediates. If this cannot be achieved by lowering final goods tariffs (but
see paragraph 24), then, faced with the real possibility of injury to exporters
and a consequent threat to outward orientation, it would be desirable to have
an additional domestic tax to offset the high effective protection to final
goods that would otherwise result.   On the other hand, if intermediates are
deserving of protection, their tariff rates should be increased to 10-15% levels
and an excise tax imposed if necessary on domestic production of final goods as
well. The answer to whether intermediate tariffs should be raised from zero to
10-15% therefore turns on whether intermediates are to be protected in their own
right.
24.      It may also be noted that both Harberger and Shalizi-Squire assume
without further discussion that while the reduction of final good tariffs is
ruled out, it is possible to increase intermediate good tariffs or to levy
additional domestic taxes on final goods respectively. Before endorsing those



- 24 -
solutions,  it  is  worth  enquiring  what  exactly  is  the  basis  for  the
unalterability of the final good tariff. If, for example, it may not be reduced
because domestic producers of final goods wish to maintain a minimum level of
protection, then those producers may be equally successful in blocking either
of the above proposals which adopt "indirect" methods to reduction of that level
of protection. In that case, it may be no more difficult to press directly for
the reduction of nominal tariff rates on final goods.
Consumer Prices and World Prices
25.      We turn next to the wedge between consumer prices and world prices,
given by the customs duty-plus-sales tax. The motivation for this wedge in the
absence of the lump-sum taxes of classical economic analysis  is to raise
revenue. This has the consequence that the government's revenue needs determine
the average level of this wedge, while standard considerations of efficiency and
equity guide its structure.
26.      In a one-consumer economy with an assumed absence of lump-sum tax
instruments it is desirable to raise revenue by taxing more (less) heavily goods
that are relatively complementary (substitutable) with leisure, where leisure
is understood to represent an untaxed time endowuent.17 Thus, if all goods were
equally substitutable for leisure, a uniform tax structure would be desirable.
In the more realistic many-consumer economy, the determinants of the desired
structure of taxation depends on two factors: (i) substitution possibilities
with leisure as before, and (ii) variations in consumption patterns among
different consumers and income groups.   This second consideration introduces
17The result follows from a desire to tax the consumer's endowment. It is
common to choose leisure as the endowment good. It could equally be interpreted
as nonmarket time. For a more careful statement of these conditions, see Stern
(1987).



- 25 -
distributional considerations into the analysis in an essential way.   Thus,
uniform taxation would be desirable if all goods were equally substitutable for
leisure and if there were no variation in consumption patterns across different
households.   These conditions are implausibly stringent.   But they can be
relaxed if other instruments are available to the government. Thus, if there
is a well-functioning income support scheme and income taxation that can
appropriately target the basis of differences among households, it may be shown
that uniform taxation may under certain circumstances continue to be desirable
even in a many-consumer economy.
27.      Literally interpreted, these prescriptions would call for a complicated
structure of tax rates that could not be administered effectively.   However,
analysis comparing optimal and uniform tax structures18 and country experience
suggest that broadly acceptable outcomes may be obtained by implementing the
following set of recommendations.
Structure of ConsUmDtion Taxes
28.      First, it would be desirable to tax consumption over as large a part
of the economy as administrative constraints permit and to do so at a uniform
rate.    This  does  not  discriminate  on  the basis  of complementarity  and
substitutability relationships with leisure endowments but since such
information is extremely difficult to obtain, it is not uncommon to assume that
all goods are equally substitutable with leisure.  The situation is somewhat
analogous to the earlier one where, in the absence of evidence on differentiated
learning effects across infant industries, it was assumed that they are equally
strong. However, given the limited reach of taxation in developing countries,
18See, for example, the calculations reported in Ebrahimi and Heady (1988)
and Mitra (1990).



- 26 -
the uniform tax will not in practice apply to all sectors at the same rate.
Agriculture will be exempt from taxation except for its purchase of taxed inputs
as will be enterprises in the informal sector and many services. Once again,
the situation varies across developing countries. The middle income countries
of Latin America generally administer a value added tax on consumption that
extends through the retail  level to the point of final consumption.   In
contrast, the Asian countries with the exception of Korea and the Philippines,
and the low income countries of sub-Saharan Africa administer a VAT that extends
only to tne manufacturers' level.
29.      Second, given the absence of well functioning income support mechanisms
and the undeveloped nature of the income tax, especially in the lower income
countries, it is necessary to allow exemptions and some differentiation in the
rate structure of indirect taxes in order to accommodate distributional goals.
Thus, the exemption of nonmarketed food in particular ensures that the tax
system has distributionally acceptable consequences. However, the requirement
that the indirect tax system not be expected to serve too many objectives,
together with administrative considerations, dictate that a proliferation of
rates be avoided.
30.      Reference has already been made above to the desirability of taxing
consumption. This is done under the VAT by allowing firms credit for taxes paid
not only on raw materials but on capital goods as well.19 This form of tax also
19VAT systems which disallow credit for taxes paid on capital goods--the so-
called "income type" VATs are generally not used.   Exceptions among LDCs are
Argentina and Peru and, to some extent, Turkey. Income type VATs by definition
credit taxes paid on capital goods purchases only when the latter depreciate:
their implementation therefore requires maintaining depreciation accounts. In
practice, however, the depreciation provisions used in Argentina and Peru are
very generous. In contrast, VATs of the "gioss product" type, as practiced in
Finland and Morocco, do not allow tax credit on depreciation.



- 27 -
allows exporters refunds on taxes paid on capital goods, thereby enhancing
competitiveness and allowing the benefits of outward orientation to be more
fully reaped.
31.      The ensuing discussion makes a distinction between exemption and zero-
rating and requires a brief explanation. Exempted sectors, by not being part
of a VAT, do not pay taxes on their output.  By the same token, they cannot
claim credit for taxes paid on their inputs. Hence exempted sectors are taxed
on their inputs rather than on their outputs, whereas sectors under the VAT are
taxed on their output rather than on their inputs. Zero-rated sectors, on the
other hand, are exempted from taxation on both their inputs as well as on their
outputs. Zero-rating therefore offers a precise way of according relief from
taxation.
32.      The VAT used by most countries either has a zero rate or an exemption
applying to necessities, a standard rate for the majority of sectors and a
higher rate applicable to luxury items and those goods whose consumption the
authorities wish to discourage. Table 6 provides some examples. It shows the
main rates of VAT and additional rates applying to a subset of goods in the EEC
countries (which have the longest experience of using VAT), other European
countries, selected Latin American countries, and in New Zealand, Taiwan
(China), Indonesia, and Korea. The rates shown are those that apply to domestic
sales; virtually all of the countries zero-rate exports. The largest number of
different rates is seven (in Belgium), but two or three rates are more common.
In Asia, Indonesia has a single rate while Korea and Taiwan, China which began
with single rates now have three rates.
33.      All  the countries  listed  in the  table have  additional  taxes on
particular commodities. These are separate from the VAT and are therefore not



- 28 -
Table 6. The Rate Structure of VAT in Selected Countries
Main               Other                      Number of
Rate              VAT Rates                    Rates
Argentina                   18            9                                  2
Austria                     20            10, 32                             3
Belgium                     19            1, 6, 17, 25, 33, 0                7
Denmark                     22            0                                  2
France                    18.6            2.1, 4.5, 5.7, 33.3                5
Germany                     14            7, 2                               3
Greece                      18            3, 6, 36                           4
Hungary                     25            15                                 2
Indonesia                   10            -                                  1
Ireland                     25            2.2, 10, 0                         4
Israel                      15            6.5                                2
Italy                       18           2, 9, 38, 0                         5
Korea                       10            2, 3.5                             3
Luxembourg                  12            3, 6                               3
Netherlands                 20            6, 0                               3
New Zealand                 10            -                                  1
Norway                      20            11.11                              2
Portugal                    16            8, 30                              4
Spain                       12           6, 33, 0                            3
Sweden                  23.46             3.95, 12.87, 0                     4
Taiwan, China                5            15, 25                             3
United Kingdom              15            0                                  2
Source:   A. A. Tait, Value added tax:   International Practice and
Problems, (International Monetary Fund: Washington, D.C.
(1988).



- 29 -
subject to refund. In the European Community these additional taxes are mainly
in the form of excise taxes on tobacco, alcohol, gasoline and diesel oil. The
rates vary widely from one country to another, but are often higher than the
VAT levied at either 10 percent of 20 percent on goods that are regarded as
luxuries.   In Korea, there is a Special Excise Tax that is levied at rates
between 5 percent and 100 percent on selected goods.
34.       Thus, distributional objectives may be accommodated through a second
or "luxury" rate within the value added tax or by imposing excises on luxuries
entering final consumption, together with items such as cigarettes, alcohol and
petroleum products.20  Once again, the extent of differentiation in the rate
structure must be chosen in the light of internationa'l experience and the
country's administrative capabilities. However, it is important to ensure that
the standard and luxury rates apply symmetrically to domestic production and to
imports, thus ensuring that the task of protection is left to customs duties.
Summary of Tax Recommendations
35.       The discussion on the wedge between consumer prices and world prices,
may lie summarized in the observation that this should be set (i) at a single
rate for all transactions that the tax administration is able to reach, with
exemptions for items such as nonmarketed food that are consumed by the poorest
and (ii) at higher rates for luxuries and other goods whose consumption the
government wishes to discourage, with the extent of differentiation being
dictated by administrative capacity.
20International opinion is somewhat divided as to what framework is
appropriate for the tax treatment of luxuries and other goods whose consumption
the government wishes to discourage. One option is the incorporation of luxury
rates on income-elastic g.-'ods within the VAT, with additional sumptuary excises
on selected items.   A second option is the use of a single rate VAT with
sumptuary excises outside the VAT.



- 30 -
36.       It has already been mentioned that the wedge between consumer prices
and world prices to which the above discussion refers is brought about through
the operation of the customs duty plus the sales tax/VAT.  Recall the earlier
example of paragraph 9 where the c.i.f. pri..  of an import in local currency is
100, the customs duty is 20% and the sales tax 10%.  Since the latter tax is
levied on the customs duty-inclusive price (120) rather than the world price,
consumer prices could be raised by a uniform proportion over world prices
essentially only through a uniform rate of customs duty (which raises producer
prices by an equal proportion over world prices) and a uniform rate of sales
tax/VAT (which raises consumer prices by an equal proportion over world prices).
That proportion would be given in this example by (1.2 x 1.1) - 1 - 0. 32.
Luxury rates or sumptuary excises would apply on top of this for selected
commodities.  This consideration further underlines the importance of adopting
an integrated perspective in determining a desiralble structure of customs duty
and sales tax/VAT.
Exports
37.       The summaries in paragraphs 19 and 35 did not pay detailed attention
to the tax treatment of exports, except to suggest that inputs entering export
production not be liable for customs duty or value added tax.   There are
circumstances, outlined below, when the taxation of exports is justified.
However, to the extent that exports are already implicitly taxed via import
tariffs, these arguments should be used with considerable care.
38.       First, a classical argument is provided by inelasticity in world
demand for a country's exports. As the above formulation makes clear, however,
the relevant elasticity is not that of world demand as a whole, but the demand
for the country's exports. Competition among countries ensures that the lat-ter



- 31 -
will usually be considerably more elastic than the former, weakening the
argument for significant export taxation. It is also necessary to remember that
long  run  demand  elasticities   substantially  exceed  short  run  demand
elasticities. 21
39.       A second argument for export taxation is provided by the existence of
a quota on a country's exports or because of "voluntary" export restraints. Its
purpose is to tax quota profits and it should be set at a level that makes
exports equal the quota in question. Examples are provided by the Multifiber
Arrangement and various commodity agreements.
40.       A third argument for export taxation arises from restrictions on
domestic tax possibilities. Thus, constraints on the possibilities of taxing
agricultural land or income can justify the taxation of agricultural exports.22
These can either be explicit or be implemented via agricultural marketing boards
that set prices received by farmers below international prices.
41.       It is noted in the World Development Report 1988 that export taxes
were used in at least fifty three of the seventy four countries singled out for
a study of such taxes. The evidence also suggests that they are set at levels
considerably in excess of those justified on grounds of demand inelasticity or
the need to substitute for unavailable land or agricultural income taxes.
21These observations are confirmed by Imran and Duncan (1988) who present
the relevant information for cocoa, tea, coffee and natural rubber.
22For a review of the comparison between export taxes and land taxes, see
Skinner (1990).



- 32 -
Optimal Policies vs. Rules of Thumb23
42.       Before concluding this section,  it must be pointed out that the
prescriptions outlined here are be seen, not as characterizations of optimal
policies, but as rules of thumb for policy making that yield broadly acceptable
outcomes with regard to efficiency, equity and protection, while being
implementable with the administrative resources available to developing
countries.    In  contrast,  Harberger  (1988)  has  attempted  to justify  the
optimality of uniform tariffs. In what follows, we examine his basic argument.
43.       Harberger's argument in favor of uniform tariffs is based on the
notion that this guarantees efficiency. The reason this argument is somewhat
difficult to assess is that, notwithstanding references to "the protectionist
motive", the paper nowhere states in what form one should think about protection
either as an objective or as a constraint.
44.       The  argument  in favor of uniform  tariffs  is motivated by  the
observation that "the uniform tariff goes on to point out the absurdity (from
an economic point of view) of paying a domestic resource cost (DRC) of 22 pesos
per dollar in one place, of 16 pesos per dollar in another, and of 10 pesos per
dollar in a third place--all being cases of import substitution.. .A country
gains by moving towards equalization of the domestic resource costs of different
import substitute activities." Since the measure of the DRC used here, viz.,
factor use in each activity evaluated at market prices compared to value added
at international prices. is equal, in a standard trade model, to one plus the
effective rate of protection (ERP?), the above is equivalent to arguing that
23This subsection relates the present paper to some earlier literature and
is somewhat more demanding.   Readers prepared to accept the conclusions of
paragraph 47 might omit it without disadvantage.



- 33 -
unequal ERPs are undesirable, from which the optimality of uniform ERPs follows
directly.
45.       The difficulty with this argument is the following.  It has been shown
by Srinivasan and Bhagwati (1978), for example, that DRCs evaluated at market
prices of factors have no welfare significance in a distorted economy.  The
argument is straightforward. With distortions, the real opportunity cost to the
economy of employing or withdrawing a factor from a particular activity is given
by its marginal product in that activity evaluated, in the case of tradeables,
at their world prices and not their market prices.   To make statements on
welfare in such an economy it is therefore necessary to use the real opportunity
costs of factors in calculating the DRCs. Since only DRCs calculated using the
real opportunity costs of factors have any welfare significance, and since this
is not the case for DRCs calculated at market prices, which latter equal one
plus the ERP, Srinivasan and Bhagwati argue that "it is best therefore to drop
the terminology and concept of ERPs altogether from cost-benefit analysis."
46.       Harberger's claim on the superiority of uniform ERPs may however be
established using a different line of argument that makes the protection
constraint on economic policy making explicit.   If the objective is (i) to
extend special treatment to a subset of sectors in the economy (e.g.,
manufacturing) compared to the rest of the economy and (ii) to preserve
uniformity of treatment within that targeted subset, a form of protection
constraint due to Bertrand (1972), it is clear that policy interventions would
discriminate in favor of the subset compared to those outside but not within it.
If there were no economic cost to providing subsidies, i.e., if the latter could
be costlessly raised through lump sum taxation, the above objective would be
achieved by a uniform subsidy to producers within the targeted sector.



- 34 -
Furthermore, this uniformity would lead to effective rates of protection if the
aim were to encourage value added, i.e., gross output net of intermediate
inputs, in the targeted sectors. However, the argument refers not to
distortionary tariffs at all but to production subsidies financed by lump sum
taxation. In particular, as pointed out in Mitra (1987), if subsidies may not
be raised except via distortionary taxation, the economic costs of the latter
would have to be taken into account, undermining the uniformity argument. Since
revenue and administrative constraints preclude most developing countries from
assisting local production via subsidies and since most tax administrators do
not have access to lump sum instruments to finance those subsidies, it must be
concluded that this special case is of virtually no interest for policy. On the
other hand, as argued in the present paper, Harberger's recommendations on
uniform tariffs, together with uniform indirect taxes, if combined with
exemption of nonmarketed food and supplementary taxes on luxuries, though not
optimal, are likely to be reasonably good rules of thumb in a wider class of
situations. 24
47.       It is now generally known that uniformity is not optimal except in
very special cases. The above discussion implies that the value of analytical
tax-cum-tariff studies for policy making would be considerably enhanced if
attention were to be paid to identifying circumstances under which the pursuit
of uniformity of taxes-cum-tariffs, supplemented by higher taxes on domestically
produced and imported luxuries, would be seriously inappropriate.   Thus, for
example, the earlier discussion of this section focussed on weaknesses in income
support mechanisms and incoTne taxation as an important reason for introducing
24This is also the position taken in Balassa (1989b) in a paper that
synthesizes disparate literatures into a consistent package for policy makers.



- 35 -
distributionally-oriented  differentiation in the value added tax.   Recent
research suggests that uniform VAT structures may also be seriously
inappropriate in economies where the public sector, for example, is
characterized by extensive price controls.25 The pursuit of appropriate rules
of thumb has thus made more progress with respect to the design of tax
structures compared to that in the area of simultaneous tariff-cum-tax design.26
V. THE REFORM OF TAXES-CUM-TARIFFS
48.       Policy advisors are rarely in a position of being called upon to
design a cuuntry's tax-cum-tariff structure de novo.  The more typical situation
is one where the anti-export bias of the trade regime is high on account of
import tariffs and quantitative restrictions and must be reduced. At the same
time, revenue constraints are typically acute, so that accompanying fiscal
adjustments are necessary to preserve macroeconomic stability.27 '-low could the
ideas on desirable structures developed in Section IV above be used to guide the
reform?
Nontariff Import Restrictions
49.       The relaxation and ultimate removal of quantitative restrictions and
import licenses is a standard component of trade liberalization. Countries have
tried different schemes in this regard28; to th,. extent these involve the
25See Heady and Mitra (1990).
26An attempt in this direction is contained in Mitra (1990).
27The raising of tariffs that are currently lower than the 10-15% range but
are called for on grourds of protection will of course usually alleviate
conflicts with revenue goals.
28These are outlined in World Bank (1989b).



- 36 -
replacement of those restrictions by tariffs, this stage of reform is revenue-
enhancing.    Two points  deserve mention here.    First,  since  quantitative
restrictions axe protective in intent, their replacement by tariffs should be
reflected in the customs duty and not in the sales tax/VAT on imports. Second,
this change increases the dependence of public revenue on tariffs till such time
as the country reduces protection and switches from tariffs to less
discriminatory sources of revenue such as the sales tax/VAT.
Tariff Reduction
50.       Before analyzing the consequences of reduction of protective tariffs,
it may be observed that an easy stage of "reform" is provided by the lowering
of tariffs that are set so high that their lowering would raise revenue. This
would also raise protection for domestic import-competing producers while
reducing protection, in the case of intermediate goods, for domestic users of
the product.
Matching Sales Tax/VAT
51.       The integrated approach to tax-cum-tariff analysis suggests that
protection and revenue issues arising in subsequent tariff reduction be handled
as follows.   It is desirable to transfer the role of protection to customs
duties.  To that end, the sales tax/VAT on imports and domestic transactions
should be matched, so that both are taxed at the same rate.   Customs duties
which are levied on commodities for which there is no domestic production and
which are therefore purely revenue-raising should be brought under the sales
tax/VAT. 29
29Since there is no domestic production of these items, there will be no
revenue collected under those items from the domestic sales tax. However, this
does nc- affect the principle that the rate applying to these items under the
sales tax should be the same irrespective of wheth3r the source of supply is
imports or possible future domestic production.



- 37 -
52.       It is recognized that the matching of the sales tax/VAT with respect
to rates does not necessarily imply that the effective rate, defined as the
revenue collection divided by the base, will be the same for imports and
domestic production. This is because collection costs are usually higher for
domestic taxes compared to trade taxes.   The World Development Report 1988
reports that the administrative costs of trade and excise taxes range from 1 to
3 percent of revenue collected, whereas the corresponding figure for VATs can
be as high as 5 percent.30 What is relevant in switching from protec- e customs
duties to a VA', however, is not the average administrative cost reported above,
but rather the marginal administrative cost of collection; no evidence is
available on the extent to which these differ across taxes. Nevertheless, it
is in practice the case that satisfactory matching of the sales tax/VAT will
require a concomitant strengthening in domestic tax administration.
Adlustina Taxes for Revenue
53.       To illustrate the kinds of adjustments  that are necessitated by
revenue considerations, it proves convenient to return to the numerical example
of paragraph 9. Recall that the c.i.f. price of the imported good was 100, the
customs duty 20% and the sales tax 10%, so that the producer price was 120 and
the consumer price was 132.   A lowering of the customs duty by say, 50%,
reduces the producer price to 110. However, since sales taxes are levied on the
customs duty-inclusive price, this also reduces the consumer price to 121 [G
110(1 + 0.1)]. But protection refers to the wedge between the producer price
and the world price and should not involve reducing consumer prices as well.
Hence reduction of protection per se, interpreted as a narrowing of the wedge
3OThe corresponding figure for personal income taxes is reported to be 10%.



- 38 -
between producer prices and world prices, would be achieved by combining the
lowering of customs duties with an equal upward adjustment of the sales tax/VAT
structure so as to restore the tax wedge between consumer prices and world
prices prevailing befoye the tariff reduction.   In that case,  it would be
necessary to simultaneously increase the rate of sales tax to 20%.  Since,
unlike the customs duty, the sales tax applies to imports as well as domestic
production, this combination of changes is revenue-enhancing.   Thus, if the
import and domestic tax bases were unchanged, an assumption made here for
expository convenience, the collection from customs duties and sales taxes on
imports taken together would be unchanged (with customs duty collections falling
by 50% and sales tax collections rising by roughly 83%),.  If the sales tax
applies equally to domestic production, the revenue from this source increases
by 83%. Lest this seem puzzling, recall that customs duties are a subsidy to
producers.   A reduction in those duties, when accompanied by a sales tax
adjustment to maintain the revenue-raising wedge between consumer prices and
world prices, must therefore increase revenue.   From this revenue estimate,
however, must be subtracted, if any, the increased cost that is incurred in
collecting the extra sales tax/VAT revenue, net of the cost saving arising on
the customs side. While unavailability of marginal collection costs precludes
these from being quantified, it is worth bearing in mind that successful reform
will require a reallocation of resources across the units entrusted with
administration of the different taxes.
54.       Readers will recognize that a somewhat extreme example is being
sketched here. The subsidy implicit in protective tariffs is being lowered and
the sales tax increased by the full amount of that reduction. But this serves
to bring out clearly the main point, which is that reduction of protection per



- 39 -
se necessarily requires a coordinated reform of tariffs and domestic indirect
taxes. If the sales tax/VAT is thus adjusted, it will be possible to generate
extra revenue, some of which could be used to extend adjustment assistance,
preferably through the budgetary process, to producers adversely affected by the
tariff reduction.
55.       It follows from the above argument that a smaller upward adjustment
in the sales tax/VAT structure will suffice to make the reform revenue-neutral.
Once again, for purposes of illustration, if the domestic sales tax base is 50%
higher than that for imports, it is easily seen that the sales tax rate would
have to increase from 10% to around 14%-or by 40%-to offset the revenue losses
from tariff reduction.31 A larger adjustment than the above would of course be
:equired to raise the revenue necessary to meet demands for adjustment
assistance and to take into account any differences in the marginal collection
costs of sales tax/VAT compared to protective customs duties. 32
Revenue and Protection Constraints on Reform
56.       The extent to which revenue as opposed to protection considerations
limit the reduction of protective tariffs depends ultimately on administrative
constraints to expansion of the domestic tax base. While this will necessarily
vary from country to country, the following general point may be made.  The
evidence cited earlier in the paper shows that the importance of trade taxes in
public  revenue  declines  with  per  capita  income.        This  implies  that
31If M is the import base and D the domestic sales tax base, pre-reform
revenue equals 1.32M + l.lD.   If x is the sales tax rate after the reform,
revenue equals (1 + x)(l.lM + D).  Since D - 1.5M, the two are equal and the
reform revenue-neutral when x - 0.142.
32Mexico offers an example where the introduction of a VAT three years
before the 1983 trade reform allowed revenue losses to be offset through
increases in domestic indirect taxes.



- 40 -
administrative constraints to identification of revenue sources alternative to
trade taxes can be expected to be most acute in the low income countries. This
might encourage the conclusion that a reduction of protective tariffs would
rapidly encounter revenue constraints in such countries. Against that, however,
must be set the observation that the low income countries do not have a
diversified manufacturing sector and therefore that many of their import taxes
will  be  mainly  revenue-raising  rather  than  protective.         Since  trade
liberalization should pertain to the reduction of protective rather than purely
revenue-raising tariffs, with the latter being absorbed within the sales
tax/vat, the extent of revenue loss arising from this reduction will be
considerably smaller, thus requiring a more modest offsetting adjustment in
domestic tax structures.
57.       The extent to which protection considerations themselves limit the
reduction of protective tariffs depends on the ability of import-competing
producers to preserve the tariff-induced implicit subsidy enjoyed by them as
well as the other instruments availabie to the government.   Since existing
tariff levels in many countries are well in excess of the recommended range of
10-15%, it is clear that a very significant reduction in protection is involved
in moving to an outward-oriented development strategy. Producers will require
considerable time to adjust to such changes; the magnitude of this adjustment
is essentially the same whether protection is reduced by cutting tariffs on
final goods, raising tariffs on intermediate goods or levying taxes on domestic
production of final goods. The desired changes could therefore be facilitated
by extending other forms of assistance to them; this theme is further developed
in paragraph 59.



- 41 -
58.       Finally, it may be noted that no reference has been made to two paths
to tariff reform that have been discussed in the trade literature.33 One is the
'"concertina' method which collapses the structure by reducing the top rate at
each step of the transition to the next highest level, while leaving other rates
the same. A second is the "radial" method whereby at each stage all tariffs are
reduced to a fraction of their previous levels. However, the conditions under
which  these  paths  to  reform  improve  matters  are  stringent.    Thus,  the
"concertina"   method,   to   be   welfare-improving,   essentially   requires
substitutability among commodities, a feature that is almost certainly false
when intermediates and capital goods are imported as well as final goods.  The
"radial" method, on the other hand, is welfare-improving (i) either if there are
no domestic taxes (ii) or, more generally, if those taxes are also reduced
radially, in either of which cases the country's revenue base would suffer
significant erosion. Furthermore, the methods require the government to be able
to offset the revenue gains and losses at each stage through lump sum taxes and
subsidies, a feature that greatly limits their relevance for policy. As against
that, it is not known whether these rules perform reasonably well as rules of
thumb in a class of situations wider than those where they can be shown to be
desirable. In practice, it would be preferable at the outset to preannounce the
desired tariff structure as well as a realistic timetable that allows producers
to adjust towards it.
Towards ExDlicit Assistance
59.       Reference has also been made above to revenue needs arising from
demands for adjustment assistance by producers adversely affected by tariff
reduction. Thus, it is sometimes the case that a tariff on a key intermediate
33For an extended discussion, see Corden (1974).



- 42 -
good such as steel is imposed to protect one or two large and visible high-cost
local producers, possibly but not necessarily in the public sector. Reduction
of the tariff on steel is recommended in order to make downstream producers, say
producers of light engineering goods, more competitive in export markets. While
the latter is an objective with which the government is in agreement, concern
is however expressed that the reform would make local producers of steel
uneconomic, threatening jobs and leading to other negative consequences.   In
such a situation, the affected producers are few and visible and almost
certainly registered with the domestic tax authorities. It would therefore be
administratively feasible to extend assistance to those producers via subsidies,
with the required revenue coming from the sales tax/VAT adjustment made in
combination with the reduction in protective customs duties. Such a policy, in
contrast with tariff protection, would have the advantage of being explicit and
therefore subject to periodic budgetary scrutiny.   There is therefore some
likelihood that such assistance would be more timebound and less "permanent"
than assistance via tariffs.   Hence this is a policy change that should be
suggested in such cases.34
VI. CONCLUSIONS
60.      The   main points emerging from the analysis may be summarized as
follows.
(1) Since it is generally accepted that lack of supportive
macroeconomic policies has led to delays or reversal in trade liberalization
programs, it is important that potential losses in public revenue arising from
34A recent review of the Bank's approach to subsidies, Myers and Brondolo
(1986) took the view that explicit subsidies are preferable to implicit subsidies
and that it is undesirable to finance subsidies through nonbudgetary instruments.



- 43 -
tariff reductions to be offset so as not to exacerbate macroeconomic
difficulties.    The  common  practice  of  pursuing  tariff  and  tax  studies
independently carries the risk that the revenue implications of tariff reform
and the implications for protection of tax reform may not be properly
integrated, with negative consequences for the credibility of policy change.
(2) The adoption of a more comprehensive public finance perspective
on policy reform is made possible by the fact that even the poorest countries
have essentially two sets of instruments for the taxation of imports:   (a)
customs duties and (b) sales taxes/value added taxes, that are usually levied
on the customs duty-inclusive value of imports and that apply to domestic
transactions as well. Since the customs duty raises the price facing producers
of an import above the world price, it is a subsidy to domestic producers.
Since the sales tax/value added tax, together with the customs duty, raises the
price facing users of the import above the world price, they constitute a tax
on domestic users. The customs duty can then serve protection objectives, while
the two together can be designed to meet revenue requirements.
(3) The following integrated structure of taxes cum tar'ffs provides
a point of reference towards which reforms may be directed. This comprises (a)
a basic customs duty at a uniform rate of no more than 10 to 15 percent, (b) a
basic value added tax, preferably of the consumption type, applying at a uniform
rate depending on revenue requirements, to domestic production and imports, and
exempting agriculture, La particular nonmarketed food consumed by the poorest,
(c) a luxury rate of excises applying at a common rate to domestic production
and imports of selected items, (d) zero rating of exports under the value added
tax, (e) exemption of imported inputs entering export production from customs
duty, and (f) taxe- on selected exports either where world demand for the



- 44 -
country's exports is expected to remain inelastic or where the country is
subject to export quotas or where there are significant constraints on land or
income taxes. The paper argues that it is important to view the above elements
as part of an interrelated package so that, for example, attempts to unify
customs duties at levels higher than the recommended range [as in (a)) would
create administrative problems in implementing duty exemptions on inputs
entering export production [point (e)].
(4) The above prescriptions must be regarded as rules of thumb that
can generate broadly acceptable outcomes in terms of efficiency, equity and
protection and that should be flexibly applied in the light of country
circumstances and administrative capability. They are not properties of optimal
tariff and tax structures. Thus the value to policy advisors of analytically-
oriented studies of taxes and tariffs would be enhanced if the latter were to
identify circumstances where the pursuit of such rules is likely to be
inappropriate, rather than construct empirically implausible special cases where
they hold exactly.
(5)   The coordinated reform of an existing distorted structure of
tariffs and domestic taxes in accordance with the above principles will include
the following components. The sales tax/VAT rates on domestic production and
imports should be matched, so as to transfer the function of protection to
customs duties.   Customs duties on items for which there is no domestic
production and which are therefore purely revenue-raising should be brought
under the rubric of the sales tax/VAT, i.e., apply at the same rate to imports
and possible future domestic production. A lowering of customs duties to reduce
the excess of producer prices over world prices (the element of protection), if
unaccompanied by other measures, would also reduce the excess of user prices



- 45 -
over world prices (the customs duty-cum-sales tax on users) and thus erode
public revenue.   Hence reduction of protection Rer se,  interpreted as a
narrowing of the wedge between producer prices and world prices, is achieved by
combining the lowering of customs duties with an equal upward adjustment to the
sales tax/VAT structure to restore the tax wedge between user prices and world
prices prevailing before the tariff reduction. Thus, however, would be revenue-
enhancing because the sales tax/VAT applies to imports as well as domestic
consumption, so that the higher rate structure, while exactly offsetting the
revenue loss f.im customs duties on imports, would bring in more revenue from
domestic consumption. If the objective is simply to offset the revenue losses
from tariff reductions, a smaller adjustment to the sales tax/VAT structure than
the one described above will suffice. More realistically, the rate structure
would need to be raised somewhat beyond the point of revenue-neutrality so as
to allow the government to meet such demands for adjustment assistance as may
arise from sectors adversely affected by tariff reductions. Such assistance,
if extended via the budgetary process, would have the advantage vis-a-vis
protective tariffs of being explicit and thus subject to periodic scrutiny.



- 46 -
References
Balassa, B. (1989a). "Outward Orientation" in Chenery, H. and T. N. Srinivasan,
Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. II, (North Holland: Amsterdam).
Balassa, B. (1989b). "Tariff Policy and Taxation in Developing Countries" PPR
Working Paper No. 281, The World Bank.
Baldwin, R. (1969). "The Case Against Infant Industry Protection", Journal of
Political Economy, 68, 295-305.
Bertrand, T. (1972). "Decision Rules for Effective Protection in Less-Developed
Economies", American Economic Review. 62. 743-746.
Chhibber, A. and J.K. Shirazi (1988). "Public Finance in Adjustment Programs",
PPR Working Paper No. 128, The World Bank.
Corden, M. (1974).   Trade Policy and Economic Welfare,  (Oxford,  Clarendon
Press).
Ebrahimi, A. and C. Heady (1988).   "Tax Design and 'Household Composition",
Economic Journal, supplement, 98, 83-96.
Halevi, N.  (1988).   "Trade Liberalization in Adjustment Lending",  (Country
Economics Department, World Bank, processed).
Harberger, A. C. (1988). "Reflections on Uniform Taxation", (paper presented
at the 44th Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance held
in Istanbul).
Heady, C. and P. Mitra (1990). "Commodity Taxation with Administered and Free
Market Prices: Theory and An Application to China", (paper presented at the
International Seminar in Public Economics, Delhi).
Imran, M., and R. Duncan (1988).   "Optimal Export Taxes for Exporters of
Perennial Crops", PPR Working Paper No. 10, The World Bank.
Linn, J. and D. Wetzel (1989). "Public Finance, Trade, and Development: What
Have We Learned?", PPR Working Paper No. 181, International Economics
Department, The World Bank.
Little, I. M. D., T. Scitovsky and M. Scott (1970). Industry and Trade in Some
DeveloRing Countries (Oxford University Press, London).
Mitra, P. (1987). "Protection and Revenue-Raising Trade Taxes: Theory and an
Application to India", Country Policy Department Discussion Paper No. 1987-
4, The World Bank.



- 47 -
Mitra, P. (1990). "Tariff Design and Reform in a Revenue-Constrained Economy:
Theory  and  an  Illustration  from  India",  (paper  presented  to  the
International Seminar in Public Economics, Delhi).
Myers, R. and J. Brondolo. (1986). The Bank's Approach to Subsidies (The World
Bank, Country Policy Department Discussion Paper No. 1986-44).
Rajaram,  A.  (1989).    "Tariff and Tax Reforms:    Do Bank Recommendations
Adequately Integrate Revenue and Protection Objectives?", (Country Economics
Department, The World Bank, processed).
Skinner, J. (1990).   "Prospects for Agricultural Land Taxation in Developing
Countries", (paper prepared for the World Bank Conference on Tax Policy in
Developing Countries).
Shalizi,  Z. and L. Squire  (1989).   "Tax Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa:   A
Framework for Analysis", PPR Policy and Research Series No. 2, The World
Bank.
Srinivasan, T.N. and J. Bhagwati, (1978). "Shadow Prices for Project Selection
in the Presence of Distortions: Effective Rates of Protection and Domestic
Resource Cost", Journal of Political Economy. 86. 97-116.
Srinivasan, T.N. (1989). Comment on "The Noncompetitive Theory of International
Trade and Trade Policy," by E. Helpman, Proceedings of the World Bank Annual
Conference on Development Economics, The World Bank.
Stern, N. (1987).  "The Theory of Optimal Commodity and Income Taxation:  An
Introduction" in D. Newbery and N. Stern, eds., The Theory of Taxation for
Developing Countries, (Oxford University Press for the World Bank).
A.A  Tait  (1988).  Value Added Tax:   International Practice and Problems,
(International Monetary Fund: Washington, D.C.).
World Bank (1989a). World Development Report, The World Bank.
World Bank (1989b). Strengthening Trade Policy Reform: (in 2 volumes) Country
Economics Department, Trade Policy Division, The World Bank.



PRE Working Paper Series
Contact
TJ16                             AutAho                                   fr paper
WPS469  Modeling Economic Behavior in     J. Barry Smith          August 1990      M. Abundo
Peru's Informal Urban Retail Sector  Morton Stelcner                      36820
WPS470  What Do Alternative Measures of    Alexander J. Yeats     August 1990      J. Epps
Comparative Advantage Reveal                                              33710
About the Composition of Developing
Countries' Exports?
WPS471  The Determinants of Farm          Gershon Feder           August 1990      C. Spooner
Investment and Residential      Lawrence J. Lau                          30464
Construction in Post-Reform China   Justin Lin
Xiaopeng Luo
WPS472  Gains in the Education of Peruvian   Elizabeth M. King    August 1990      C. Cristobal
Women, 1940 to 1980              Rosemary Bellew                          33640
WPS473  Adjustment, Investment, and the   Riccardo Faini          August 1990      R. Sugui
Real Exchange Rate in Developing   Jaime de Melo                         37951
Countries
WPS474  Methods for Measuring the Effect    Anne Maasland         August 1990      P. Dixon
of Adjustment Policies on Income                                          39175
Distribution
WPS475  Does Divestiture Matter? A        Ahmed Galal             August 1990      G. Orraca-Tetteh
Framework for Learning from Experience                                   37646
WPS476  Health Insurance in Sub-Saharan   Ronald J. Vogel         August 1990      K. Brown
Africa: A Survey and Analysis                                             35073
WPS477  Private Participation in the Delivery   Thelma A. Triche  August 1990      M. DhoKai
of Guinea's Water Supply Services                                         33970
WPS478  Interrelations Among Child Mortality, John Marcotte       August 1990      S. Cochrane
Breastfeeding, and Fertility in  John B. Casterline                      33222
Egypt, 1975-80
WPS479  Conversion Factors: A Discussion   Michael Hee            August 1990      E. Zamora
of Alternate Rates and Corresponding                                      33706
Weights
WPS480  An Evaluation of Neutral Trade Policy Jaime de Melo       August 1990      R. Sugui
Incentives Under Increasing Returns David Roland-Holst                   37951
to Scale
WPS481  The Effects of Trade Reforms on   James Tybout            August 1990      R. Sugui
Scale and Technical Efficiency:  Jaime de Melo                           37951
New Evidence from Chile          Vittorio Corbo
WPS482  Membership in the CFA Zone:       Shantayanan Devarajan    August 1990     R. Sugui
Odyssean Journey or Trojan Horse?  Jaime de Melo                          37951



PRE Working Paper Series
Contact
iiie                             Author                    DaQ             for paper
WPS483  An Evaluation of the Main Elements  Refik Erzan             August 1990      G. llogon
in the Leading Proposals to Phase    Paula Holmes                          33732
Out the Multi-Fibre Arrangement
WPS484  Stock Markets, Growth, and Policy   Ross Levine             August 1990      R. Levine
39175
WPS485  Do Labor Market Distortions Cauwe   Ram6n Lopez             August 1990      R. Luz
Overvaluation and Rigidity of the  Luis Riveros                             34303
Real Exchange Rate?
WPS486  A RMSM-X Model for Turkey          Luc Everaert             August 1990      S. Aggarwal
Fernando Garcia-Pinto                     39176
Jaume Ventura
WPS487  Industrial Organization Implications  Timothy Condon        August 1990      R. Sugui
of OR Trade Regimes: Evidence    Jaime de Melo                              37951
and Welfare Costs
WPS488  Prepaid Financing of Primary Health  Per Eklund             August 1990      K. Brown
Care in Guinea-Bissau: An        Knut Stavem                                35073
Assessment of 18 Village Health Posts
WPS489  Health Insurance in Zaire          Donald S. Shepard        August 1990      K. Brown
Taryn Vian                                35073
Eckhard F. Kleinau
WPS490  The Coordinated Reform of Tariffs    Pradeep Mitra          August 1990      A. Bhalla
and Domestic Indirect Taxes                                                 37699
WPS491  How Well Do India's Social Service    Nirmala Murthy        August 1990      E. Madrona
Programs Serve the Poor?         Indira Hirway                             37483
P. R. Panchmukhi
J. K. Satia