The Political Economy of Protection in Belgium
SWP431
World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 431
October 1980
Prepared by: P.K.M. Tharakan (Consultant)
Economic Analysis and Projections Department
Copyright ( 1980
The World Bank
1818 H Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A.
The views and interpretations in this document are those of the authors F           C   cJF'y               ./1
and should not be attributed to the World Bank, to its affiliated
organizations, or to any individual acting in their behalf.






The views and interpretations in this document are those of the author
and should not be attributed to the World Bank, to its affiliated
organizations, or to any individual acting in their behalf.
WORLD BANK
Staff Working Paper No. 431
October 1980
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PROTECTION IN BELGIUM
This work in progress report is part of an inquiry being undertaken
by the World Bank in conjunction with scholars from twelve industrial countries
into the penetration of the markets of industrial countries by exports of
manufactures from developing countries. The project seeks to establish the
shares of industrial country markets held by the developing countries, changes
in such shares in the 19708, and why they vary among industry groups and countries
The aim is to assist developing and industrial countries to improve their policies
through a better understanding of trade patterns and protectionist pressures.
This paper reports the results of the analysis of the causes of
protection in Belgium. Tariffs were found to be correlated positively with the
total and non-wage value added per person, suggesting that the present structure
of the European Community's Common External Tariff supports industries
in which Belgium has a comparative advantage. However, industries using scarce
natural resources also receive some tariff protection, and non-tariff assistance
to industry appears to be skewed toward the more labor intensive products.
Government assistance to industry on the whole seems to be favoring sectors that
are vulnerable to competition from the developing countries.
The paper was written during the author's visit to the Institute for
International Economic Studies at the University of Stockholm where a first
version of the study was presented at a seminar. The author is thankful to the
participants of that seminar, particularly C. Hamilton, M.E. Kreinin, A. Lindbeck
and T.A. Oyejide for their helpful comments. R. Erzan of IIES and W. Nonneman
of the University of Antwerp (UFSIA) extended programming assistance and made
useful suggestions. The author takes the responsibility for any remaining errors.
Prepared by: P.K.M. Tharakan (Consultant)
Economic Analysis and Projections Department
Copyright Q1980
The World Bank
1818 H St.N.W.
Washington D.C. 20433, U.S.A.






TABLE OF CONTENTS
Page 
I.  THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PROTECTION                         1
II.  THE ANALYTICAL RATIONALE                                    4
III.  RESULTS                                                     8
IV.  CONCLUSIONS                                                17
STATISTICAL APPENDIX                                       18
REFERENCES                                                 21
LIST OF TABLES
RESULTS OF THE REGRESSIONS IN WHICH NOMINAL TARIFFS
(NT) WERE USED AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE                    9
RESULTS OF THE REGRESSIONS IN WHICH EFFECTIVE TARIFFS
(ET) WERE USED AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE                   11
RESULTS OF THE REGRESSIONS IN WHICH NON-TARIFF
BARRIERS (NTBs) WERE USED AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE        13
SPEARMAN RANK CORRELATIONS BETWEEN INDUSTRY
CHARACTERISTICS AND CONCENTRATION OF ASSISTANCE
TO INDUSTRY                                                15






I. THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF PROTECTION
The sharp rise in the protectionist tendencies in the indus-
trialised market economy countries which we are now witnessing is
leading to   resurgence of analytical intereIt in the political
economy of protection.  A number of authors.LI have recently attempted
to explain the structure of protection or governmental assistance to
industries in various high income countries by resorting to models of
political choice. Various offshoots of the fledgling theory no the
political economy of trade policy have been surveyed recentlyhJ and
hence will not be reviewed here in detail. Caves (1976) identifies an
"adding machine" model in which the trade policy is shaped by the number
of voters who are expected to favour or oppose it, an "interest-group"
model which stresses the way groups with common economic interests
organize lobbying pressure in order to influence public policy and
thirdly a "national policy" model where the emphasis is on integrating
the national preference for particular industrial structures in the
traditional realm of optimization analysis. The essence of the approach
is the use of exogenous variables reflecting the likely impact of
pressure groups on trade policy decisions to explain why some industries
succeed in receiving more protection or assistance than others. The
approach, if not the topic, is relatively new and is hence often
characterized by intuitive rather than formal models and sometimes
haphazard choice of variables. In the present exercise we shall first
attempt to suggest a conceptual framework within whicK� the pressures
for protection can be empirically analyzed, note some of the pitfalls
surrounding the approach and subsequently isolate and quantify the
variables which can be used for such an analysis.
It may be recalled that the essence of the neo-classical
argument is that the commodity composition of trade between countries
will be determined mainly by the concordance of the pattern of factor-
endowment of the trading countries with the factor intensities of the
production processes of the commodities traded. The 'positive' element
of this proposition consists of the fact that subject to a set of highly
restrictive assumptions, it will be able to 'explain' or predict the
actual pattern of trade and production. It is also normative in the
sense that the predicted pattern of trade and production would be the
optimal mix in the inter-industry allocation of resources between
countries, as it will not only lead to a better distribution of income
between countries, but also to a tendency towards the equalization of
the returns to labour and capital within the trading countries.
1/ See for example, Anderson (1978a, 1978b), Caves (1976),
Helleiner (1977) and Pincus (1975).
2/ See Caves (1976) and Baldwin (1978).



-2-
Part of the post-Leontief paradox literature in this field
has stressed that the non-free-good nature of knowledge pertinent both
to the production and the demand side could substantially distort the
optimal inter-industry mix predicted in a Hecksher-Ohlin world. In
the context of the present exercise, the analysis from the production
(supply) side which takes into account the 'imperfect' nature of
technology markets is less relevant than the analysis from the demand
side which stresses the imperfect competition resulting from product
differentiation. The essence of the latter argument is that the price
of a given product in a given market, at a given point of time, is
determined by the slope of the tangent of the production possibilities
curve to the highest possible indifference curve and hence the preference
of the consumers or the price they are willing to pay for a given variety
of a product has to be explained in terms of factors which determine such
preferences and not simply accepted as 'given' (Tharakan et al 1978).
The process by which a consumer is persuaded to pay a higher price
for a particular brand of a labour-intensive product for its presumed
qualitative difference compared to the same product imported from a
developing country is not very different from that by which governments
are persuaded to protect structurally weak industries for 'national'
reasons and consumers to pay a higher price for 'domestic' products.
In this instance, the brunt of the persuasion campaigns will be directed
at the policy makers so that they may erect or maintain protective
barriers. But the success of such efforts hinges substantially on
keeping the majority of the citizens of a country persuaded that the
effects of protection are beneficial to them or for the country as a
whole. For, after all, if the majority of the people were convinced
about the detrimental effects of protection, they would not vote for the
politicians who set up or maintain such trade barriers. As Downs (1957)
points out, in a world where politicians act to maximize their chances
of election, the optimal policies implied in a neo-classical model would
be still preferred if costless, perfect knowledge could be shown to
prevail. Since this is evidently not the case, protectionist pressures
tend to have varying,impacts. A normally diffused group of consumers,
either unaware of the adverse effects of protection on the economy as
a whole and on their income in particular, or persuaded that liberalization
of trade would be detrimental to the national interests, would tend to
accept protection. Even in cases where consumer organisations have
created some awareness to the contrary, the high cost of organizing
campaigns against the influence of the protectionist lobbies would
probably discourage any such action. On the other hand, the import-
competing industry, highly aware of the threat to its income level,
will organize itself and lobby for protection or assistance.
While this line of reasoning provides the basis for the
empirical analysis which attempts to explain the structure of protection,
the nature of the model necessitates particular care in the interpretation
of the results. As Pincus (1975) points out, conceptually, such a model
contains two parts, namely, the determinants of the intensity of pressure
group activity and the decision making body's response to that pressure.



-3-
In the empirical analysis, neither the lobbying pressure, nor the
governmental response to such pressure are directly measured. It is
implicitly assumed that the explanatory variables such as the degree
of regional concentration of industries, magnitude of the value added,
and soon accurately reflect the extent of the protectionist pressures,
and that the governmental response to such pressures is reflected in
the structure of protection. But given the fact that lobbies for
industries with given characteristics may not always react towards
trade policy in the same manner in every country or in every situation,
it is not always possible to predict the sign of the explanatory
variables. The question of the governmental response is even more
problematic. Governments - hopefully even in parliamentary democracies -
might refuse to cede to lobbying pressures and take trade policy decisions
on the basis of other considerations. For example, as Helleiner (1977)
points out, the pattern of the prevalent tariff structures are the results
of successive tariff-cutting bargains on the basis of reciprocity between
countries.  The national governments do not always have the power to
modify the structure of protection, even if they wish to do so. Thus,
for example, Belgium, like other members of the European Community,
has to accept, most of the time, the Common External Tariffs (CET) as
given. One could of course argue that both in the case of international
tariff-cutting negotiations and the formation of common regional tariffs,
the position taken by the individual governments reflects the pressures
generated by the domestic protectionist lobbies. Further, the protect-
ionist interests in most high income countries tend to have some common
ground such as opposition to imports of labour-intensive products. They
have also organized themselves at regional levels. Nevertheless, given
the fact that the nature of trade policy at a given point in time is
the net result of the interaction between different kinds of pressures
and the responses of decision making bodies at different levels, it
would be incorrect to hypothesize a direct relationship between the
structure of protection and variables which serve as a proxy for
domestic protectionist pressures. But the results of an empirical
analysis of the type outlined above could be certainly used to verify
whether the structure of protection that has developed through this
complex process, does correspond to certain characteristics of the
industries.
It is evident that the above line of reasoning is mainly
'positive' rather than normative. Assuming that some of the variables
representing protectionist pressures prove to be empirically significant
in explaining the structure of protection, one should not, of course,
fall into the temptation of rationalizing the process. But the know-
ledge gained from such an analysis can be of use in the effective
encouragement of 'first best' policies. After all, as Caves (1976)
states succinctly, "without a positive theory of public decision
making, normative economics can only crank out blue-prints for the
wise statesman".



-4 -
II. THE ANALYTICAL RATIONALE
In the empirical analysis of the structure of protection, the
dependent variable used by various authors has varied from nominal
tariffs (Pincus 1975), nominal and effective tariffs separately (Caves
1976), nominal and effective rates as well as changes in their levels
(Helleiner 1977) and effective rates of assistance to an industry
(Anderson 1978a, 1978b). Caves (1976) has argued that the effective
tariffs are the most appropriate dependent variable because they measure
better than the nominal tariffs the net pulls on resource allocation
and proportional increases in payments to the domestic factors of
production caused by tariffs. But it should be noted that in the
Belgian case, strong rank correlation exists between the effective and
the nominal rates of protection (Ilzkovitz and Kestens 1978). Never-
theless, in our regressions, we have followed a procedure similar to
that of Caves (1976) and Helleiner (1977), by introducing alternatively,
the effective and the nominal rates of tariffs as the dependent variable
in the regressions, with the purpose of noting any d,ifferences that a
comparison of the pattern of results might reveal.-I
Most of the above-mentioned authors, with the notable exception
of Anderson (1978a, 1978b), have confined their investigation to the
structure of tariff protection. But tariffs are only one of the
protectionist devices used by most of the countries. Non-tariff
barriers (NTBs), in particular, became more prevalent during the
1970s. Information on the NTBs available from the documents qf the
GATT Joint Working Group on import restrictions (GATT, 1974)2/ was
made use of in constructing a sample of dummy variables which were
introduced as the dependent variable in separate multiple regressions
to investigate the determinants on non-tariff protection. The method
used and some of its limitations are explained elsewhere in this paper.
Assistance to industry can often have a protectionist character.
In Belgium, the assistance to industry is given mai ly within the frame-
work of the Belgian Economic Expansion Legislation:! which contains
measures to foster economic activities in depressed regions. Although
l/ For detailed information on the sources and methods relied upon in
the quantification of all the variables used in the present
exercise, see the statistical appendix.
2/ The information contained in this document has to be interpreted
with caution. It lists all types of measures considered by some
members of GATT Working Group on Import Restrictions. It does
not imply that the importing countries concerned accept that
these restrictions are operative.
3/ The Laws of 17th and 18th of July 1959 and the 30th of December 1970.



data on the cost incurred by the state for this purpose (through interest
reductions, capital premiums, etc.) are available for the period studied
here, their high level of aggregation and the consequent smallness of
the sample precludes meaningful use of multiple correlation regression
analysis. Hence, in the case of this particular possible component of
protection, we have, as will be explained below, relied on the calcula-
tion of Spearman rank correlation coefficient between variables
representing the concentration of assistance to industry and each one
of the postulated determinants of protection.
The choice of appropriate explanatory variables as proxies
for the protectionist pressures is crucial to the whole exercise.
Caves (1976) suggests that for all three types of models (see above p 1),
the value added per worker TVA would be relevant, but its interpretation
would be quite different, dep nding on whether the structure of protection
has been determined by the national policy model or by either one of the
two other models. He argues that in the case of the "adding machine"
model, the relevance of this variable is that, the lower the value
added per worker, the more workers benefit from a tariff that protects
a given amount of value added from import competition. Helleiner (1977)
modifies this somewhat by reasoning that the reciprocity principle in
the successive tariff cutting negotiations has led to large (at least
before the introduction of the GSP) reductions of tariffs on capital
intensive products, so that the structure of the present day tariffs
in the industrialised countries is likely to be inversely correlated
with unskilled labour intensity or non-wage value added per worker
(!!VA). Pincus (1975) on the other hand implies that for nationalistic
reasons a country is likely to foster industries which use physical
and human capital intensively; hence a positive correlation between
the structure of protection and value added per worker should be
expected. Anderson (1978a) uses a labour intensity variable and
expects it to be negatively correlated with the effective rate of
assistance. In the present analysis we have used either the total
value added per person or the non-wage value added per person, both
in free trade prices, as one of the explanatory variables of the
Belgian tariff and non-tariff protection, as well as of assistance
to the industry.
The second set of explanatory variables used by most of the
authors are those representing the degree of concentration in the
industry. Anderson (1978a, 1978b), Caves (1976) and Helleiner (1977)
use the market share or the share of the output of the largest four
firms as a proxy for the pressure for protection that would emanate
from such groups. All three authors expect this variable to be
positively correlated with the rate of protection or effective rate
of assistance. As Pincus (1975) argues tariffs have the characteristics
of a public good, and this can give rise to a free rider problem in the
sense that a certain number of would-be beneficiaries might try, with-
out contributing to the costs involved in the process, to enjoy the
fruits of the efforts of others to persuade the public authorities to



-6-
maintain the protection. This problem is likely to be less sharp if the
benefits can be appropriated by, and the costs involved assigned to, a
limited number of firms. This is often the case in the industries
characterised by a high degree of concentration of output. But this
argument is not completely without ambiguity. While large firms have
greater cohesiveness for lobbying and larger resources at their disposal,
they also have often more international connections and sub-contracting
arrangements which make them less protectionist. In the present analysis
we have used, alternatively, two different indices of concentration,
namely, a Herfindahl index (CH) and the market share of the output of
the largest four firms (C4).
A similar line of reasoning can be evidently extended to the
geographical concentration of workforce by industry. If particular
industries have their workforce concentrated in certain regions, they
could normally be expected to lobby energetically for greater protection
through their regional representatives. But the pattern of the Belgian
regional concentration of workforce by industry need not coincide with
that of the more influential members of the European Communities, thus
casting some doubt on its likely impact on the structure of CET. In
the present analysis, we have measured the degree of the geographical
concentration of workforce by industry (RC) by using a Gini-Hirschman
index.
Another set of important explanatory variables used by some
authors is some proxy for the vulnerability of an industry, under the
assumption that the greater such vulnerability, the greater would be
the efforts of the industry to obtain protection or assistance. Anderson
(1978a) argues that assistance to such industries could be readily
justified by the governments as a welfare measure, especially if rapid
change is seen as undesirable.  Average wage per employee (W)   the
proxy often used to represent this variable, was also used gere.
Among the authors mentioned, Helleiner (1977) alone includes
a natural resource intensity variable in the equation to explain the
structure of protection. He relied on Vanek's (1963) measure of
natural resource intensity for the U.S. for this purpose. He argues
that since a number of developing countries compete with the natural
resource processing industries in Canada, there is the possibility
that protection would be positively correlated with the natural
resource content. But he hedges on this by pointing out that most
of the large firms operating in this sector might prefer relatively
free trade in natural resource products. Belgium is, of course, a
clear-out example of a natural resource poor country. We have used
an index of natural resource product requirements (NR) developed in
an earlier study for Belgium (Tharakan, Busschaert, Schoofs and Vaes,
1976).
To sum up: in our empirical analysis we take into account
three components of the structure of protection in Belgium, namely:



-7-
tariff duties, non-tariff barriers and assistance to industry. Both
nominal and effective tariff rates are analysed. On the basis of
theoretical analysis elaborated above, the various industry charac-
teristics  [(TVA)  NVA)   NR, (p),     CC and RCI were related to the
levels of nominal (NT) and effective (EY) rates q Aprotection as well
as to the non-tariff barriers (NTBs). Because (-p--) is a substitute
for (-F-) and C4 for CH' the following alternative formulations were
used:
f(TVA)        W
r = f [( p )s NR, f(p), C4, RC]
= f    (NVA)W, NR, () C4, RC
f            W    43 RC]
NT = f t(TpVA, NRI, (p), i, RC]
Nr = f [(pVA    NR , (-f   ,   C
The same formulations were used to explain effective rates of protection
and non-tariff barriers. In the regressions for NTBs, the dependent
variable took the value of 1 in the cases of those commodities for which
Belgium is reported to use non-tariff barriers, and 0 for all the other
products. There are no theoretical reasons suggesting the appropriate-
ness of a particular functional form; we chose to use a simple linear
function in our regressions. The data used in the regressions pertain
to the year 1970, which was a relatively normal year in the sense that
no major economic convulsions took place during that period. It was
also the pre-Generalised Scheme of Preferences (GSP) period so that
the tariff rates for that year probably reflect the maximum tariff
protection against imports from developing countries reached in Belgium
during the 1970s. In the case of assistance to industry, estimates of
the industry concentration of the governmental investment incentives
were available for various years. The Spearman rank correlation of
these concentration indices with qach one of the explanatory variables
mentioned above were calculated.1"
1/ Unlike the structure of tariffs, the concentration of assistance
to industry has varied substantially over a period of time.
Hence, in our calculations, we have used data pertaining to the
assistance to industry covering the period 1959-1976.



-8-
III. RESULTS
In Table III.1 we have reported the regression results which
were obtained by using nominal tariffs as the dependent variable. Each
of the f&dr specifications described in the preceding section were
regressed at two different levels of aggregation of the sample data
to verify whether the degree of aggregation has influenced the pattern
of results obtained. In the case of the first four regressions reported
in the table, in which the data used consisted of 37 observations, the
level of aggregation corresponded to that which is used in the Belgian
national industrial statistics. For the last four regressions shown in
the table, the same sample of industries were aggregated into 18 obser-
vations, corresponding to the Belgian input-output classification of
1970.
As can be seen from the table, at both levels of aggregation,
the total value added per person is positively and significantly
correlated with the structure of nominal tariff protection in Belgium.
The pattern remains the same in alternative formulations when total
wage value added per person is replaced by non-wage value added per
person. Thus in Belgium, in contrast to Canada or Australia, the
structure of nominal tariff protection is favourable to industries
with high value added per person.
The national resource product requirement variable has
consistently yielded a positive sign but is not significant in the
first four regressions at any of the acceptable levels. When the
data used are more aggregative (in the last four equations) the level
of significance of this coefficient shows some improvement and is
acceptable, in alternate specifications, at 10 or 15 per cent confidence
levels. In general, the performance of the NR variable suggests that
the CET provides some protection to natural resource processing indus-
tries in natural resource scarce Belgium.
The average wage per employee (-) consistently yielded a
negative sign. In the first four regressYons this coefficient is
significant at 5 per cent confidence level. In the next two regressions,
for which the data were used in a more aggregative form, this variable
remained equally significant. Note, however, that in the last two
specifications (regressions 1.7 and I.8) its level of significance shows
a slight decline. In Belgium as in other industrial countries, indus-
tries with low average wage levels, which probably contain a large
number of low-skilled labourers, tend to receive high nominal tariff
protection.
Neither of the indices of industrial concentration yielded
significant results. This could at least partly result from tension
between the diverging attitudes of large firms towards the question
of protection; they find it easier to appropriate the benefits of



TABLE III.1: RESULTS OF THE REGRESSIONS IN WHICH NOMINAL TARIFFS (NT) WERE USED AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE
PFREGS                 TVA        NWVA)        N                                                             2           NUMBER
SION    CONSIANT (1)            (p            NR                       C4           CH          RC         R2      F      of
NUKBER                                                                                                                   OBSER-
VATIONS.
I.1.     725.066e    7.4571                  1.549      -8.188       0.483                    -3.070t      0.34   3.20     37
(2.932)    (3.554)                 (0.993)     (-2.620)    (0.868)                   (-2.035)
I.2.     723.328*               4.537*       1.556      -5.2568     0.483                     -3.063A      0.34   3.21     37
(2.928)                (3.559)     (0.997)     (-1.991)    (0.868)                   (-2.032)
I.3.     694.0311    7.6511                  1.489      -7.543*                  0.00725      -2.686X      0.33   2.98     37
(2.778)    (3.608)                 (0.940)     (-2.428)                 (0.042)      (-1.817)
I.4.     692.2771               4.654*       1.495      -4.535A                  0.00728      -2.6801      0.33   2.99     37
(2.714)                (3.614)     (0.945)     (-1.749)                 (0.0426)     (-1.814)
I.5.     1194.708    5.9768                  1.5830     -9.032*     0.293                     -7.025 x     0.39   1.46     18
(1.681)    (2.212)                 (1.383)     (-1.803)    (0.280)                   (-1.139)
I.6.     1030.731               3.538        1.5210     -6.9341     0.443                     -4.678       0.49   2.28     18
(1.624)                (2.914)     (1.466)     (-1.808)    (0.469)                   (-0.838)
I.7.     1252.931    6.2231                  1.296X     -8.4030                  -0.133       -7.429x      0.38   1.49     18
(1.779)    (2.311)                 (1.141)     (-1.713)                (-0.417)      (-1.208)
I.8.     1062.32t               3.5831       1.399'     -6.4600                  0.0386       -4.740       0.48   2.20     18
(1.669)                (2.292)     (1.330)     (-1.688)                (0.133)       (-0.850)
Note: The figures in brackets are t values.
(x) Indicates that the coefficient is significant at 5% confidence level; (0) indicates that the coefficient is signifi-
cant at 10% confidence level, and, (x) indicates that the coefficient is significant at the 15% confidence level.



- 10 -
protection, but the nature of their operations tends to make them more
free-trade oriented. In contrast to the concentration of output
variable, the variable representing the geographic concentration of
workforce by industry (RC) has a negative coefficient, which is highly
significant in the first four regressions although it is less so in
the last four. A possible explanation of this puzzling result is that
the pattern of the geographic concentration of workforce by industry
in the major member countries of the Community, which probably has
influenced the structure of the CET, is the opposite of that of Belgium.
This hypothesis has to be verified.
In Table III.2, we have reported the regression results
obtained by using the effective rates of tariffs (ET) as the dependent
variable. In general, the pattern of the results obtained is very
similar to that of the preceding exercise, in which the nominal rates
were the dependent variable. Irrespective of the level of aggregation,
the coefficients of total value added per person (TVA) and non-wage
value added per person (VA) are positive and highly significant.
The natural resource product requirement variable (NR) has once again
a positive coefficient in all equations and is more significant here
than in the previous regressions explaining nominal protection. This
lends further support to the belief that effective rates of protection
tend to be higher for industries processing primary products.
The coefficient of the variable (-) has again consistenly
yielded a negative sign, but its level of significance is noticeably
lower, particularly when the set of data used are more aggregative.
Both the Herfindahl index and the market share of the largest four
firms have turned out, once again to be unimportant in explaining the
structure of protection. Similar results were obtained for the
variable representing the regional concentration of the workforce
(RC) which is negatively correlated with the structure of effective
protection, probably for the reasons which were suggested for the
nominal tariff rates.  Note that the summary statistics reported in
Table I.1, which are respectable for cross-section regressions, show
marginal improvements for most of the equations in Table II.2.
Analysis of the simple correlation coefficients and the scatter of
residuals indicated no serious problems of multicollenearity.
The positive and significant correlation between the value
added variables and the nominal and effective rates of protection
warrants further consideration. It is of course possible that with a
different sample and with different estimation procedures, the significance
of this positive correlation might deteriorate or even disappear. But
given that the present sample covers,3 substantial part of the products
entering into Belgian foreign trade,-0 it is unlikely - and here one
1/ A list of the products as well as their share in the total value
added can be obtained from the author.



TABLE III.2:   RESULTS OF THE REGRESSIONS IN WHICH EFFECTIVE TARIFFS.(ET) WERE USED AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE
REGRES                 TVA        (NV)                       W                                    RC                NF      U
SION4   CONSI'ANt    (-p   (-p                NR(W)                                              RCR2               rOf
NUMBER                                                                                                                     OBSER-
VATIONS.
II.1.     1087.29k   13.015*                 3.602X      -11.186*    0.246                     -7.493       0.36   3.49      37
(2.368)     (3.341)                 (1.244)    (-1.928)     (0.238)                   (-2.676)
II.2.     1084.39*               7.921*      3.613X      -6.070X     0.245                     -7.482       0.36   3.50      37
(2.364)                (3.347)      (1.248)    (-1.239)     (0.237)                   (-2.674)
II.3.     1051.05i   13.234                  3.480 X     -10.562 X                -0.097       -7.145t      0.36   3.50      37
(2.295)     (3.404)                 (1.198)    (-1.854)                 (-0.309)      (-2.636)
II.4.     1048.15*               8.053*      3.491 x     -5.361 X                 -0.0968      -7.134t      0.36   3.51      37
(2.291)                (3.411)      (1.202)    (-1.128)                 (-0.39)       (-2.634)
II.5.     1848.50'   9.372                   4.221t      -9.410      -0.465                    -16.033A     0.40   1.63      18
(1.344)     (1.795)                 (1.907)    (-0.971)     (-0.229)                  (-1.344)
II.6.     1587.56X               5.458*      4.121*      -5.984      -0.227                    -12.378*     0.47   2.09      18
(1.240)                (2.229)      (1.969)    (-0.773)     (-0.119)                  (-1.240)
I1.7.     1883.060   9.620                   3.945A      -9.108                   -0.361       -16.4900     0.42   1.73     18
(1.394)    (1.863)                  (1.811)    (-0.968)                 (-0.592)      (-1.398)
II.8.    1583.63                 5.4060      4.080i     -5.881                    -0.0991      -12.46lX     0.47   2.10 -   18
(1.244)                (2.204)      (1.952)    (-0.769)                 (-0.171)      (-1.105)
Note: The figures in brackets are t values.
(x) Indicates that the coefficient is significant at 5% confidence level; (0) indicates that the coefficient is signifi-
cant at 10% conficence level, and, (x) indicates that the coeffificient is significant at 15% confidence level.



- 12 -
chooses one's words carefully - that the use of alternative samples
or procedures would yield a significant negative correlation between
the structure of tariff protection and value added per person in
Belgium.  I  the value added per person is a good proxy for capital
intensity,1  the results obtained are indeed unconventional insofar
as they suggest that the structure.of the nominal and effective protection
tends to favour capital intensive industries in a highly capital-endowed
country. As the cross-section data pertain to the last year of the pre-
GSP period, it can be hardly argued that the structure of tariff protection
could have taken an opposite orientation in the ensuing years.  Part of
the answer to the riddle could be that Belgium, as a small high income
country trading mostly with other high income countries, suffers dis-
economic,s of scale which cannot be compensated bX capital intensity
alone.JV We have empirically verified elsewhere>3/ that, while capital
intensity has some significance in explaining the 'revealed comparative
advantage' of Belgium vis-a-vis the developing world, it has none in
the explanation of Belgium's comparative advantage with the rest of
the world. Given this vulnerability, it is possible that industries
with high capital intensity, facing competition from their counter-
parts in other high income countries, exert whatever pressure they
can muster at the European level to preserve a structure of tariff
protection that is in their favour.
This by itself does not of course, mean that Belgian trade
policy is not protectionist particularly with respect to the products
for which the developing countries have comparative advantage. It is
quite possible that in a given country, the high value added industries
might succeed in obtaining tariff protection while labour intensive
industry groups are awarded non-tariff barriers and assistance. We
shall now proceed to test 'the latter part of this proposition.
Table III1.3 shows the results of the regressions in which
the non-tariff barriers (NTBs) were used as the dependent variable.
The basic statistical problems associated with the models in which
the dependent variable is dichotomous and equal to one or zero'
(depending in, the present case, on whether the4jmports are subjected
to NTBs or not) have been dealt with elsewhere- in detail and will
1/  There is some evidence that in the Belgian case this is a'rather
good proxy, see Tharakan and Vandoorne (1979).
2/  This point has been dealt with in more detail by Dreze (1959) and
(1960), Tharakan et al (1978).
3/  These results are available from the author on request.
4/  See Bowen, W. G. and Finegan, T.A., The Economics of Labor Force
Participation, Princeton, N. J., Princeton University Press,> 1969.



TABLE III. 3: RESULTS OF THE REGRESSIONS IN WHICH NON-TARIFF BARRIERS (NTBs) WERE USED AS THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE
REGMES                TVA        INWVA                     wNN
SIGNP                  ()                                                                       R                      NUMBER
SIONU    CNSTANT (MBE (R                     NR                       C4                       RC        R2      F       of
NUMB                                                                    4           CH POBSER-
TIONS.
III.1    0.517'     -0.00125                -0.00235   -0.00218     -0.00159�                0.003490    0.18    1.38     37
(1.178)    (-0.336)                (-0.849)   (-0.393)    (-1.598)                  (1.303)
II1.2    0.517X                 -0.000771   -0.00235   -0.00266     -0.001580                0.003490     0.18   1.38     37
(1.178)                (-0.341)    (-0.850)   (-0.568)    (-1.600)                  (1.304)
III.3    0.539x      -0.00142               -0.00251   -0.00313                 -0.0004150   0.00283X    0.17    1.23     37
(1.212)    (-0.377)                (-0.894)   (-0.569)                 (-1.372)     (1.080)
III.4    0.538X                 -0.000873   -0.00251   -0.00368                 -0.0004150   0.00283X     0.17   1.23     37
(1.218)                (-0.383)    (-0.895)   (-0.801)                 (-1.372)     (1.081)
II1.5    0.183      -0.00442                -0.00208   -0.00363     -0.000638                0.0132X     0.38   1.47      18
(0.152)    (-0.968)                (-1.076)   (-0.429)    (-0.360)                  (1.271)
II1.6    0.334                  -0.00189    -0.00201   -0.00628    -0.000779                 0.0117X     0.36   1.39      18
(0.280)                (-0.830)    (-1.033)   (-0.871)    (-0.439)                  (1.117)
III.7    0.197      -0.00425                -0.00227X  -0.00356                 0.000345     0.0129X     0.39   1.56      18
(0.167)    (-0.941)                (-1.190)   (-0.433)                 (-0.647)     (1.252)
111.8    0.338                  -0.00212    -0.00231X -0.00543                  -0.000455    0.0112X     0.39   1.56      18
(0.292)                (-0.946)    (-1.210)   (-0.778)                 (-0.858)     (1.091)
Note: The figures in brackets are t values.
(M) Indicates that the coefficient is significant at 5% confidence level; (0) indicates that the coefficient is signifi-
cant at 10% confidence level, and, (x) indicates that the coefficient is significant at 15% confidence level.



- 14 -
not be analysed here. The essence of the problem is that in dealing
with dichotomous dependent variables, the assumption that the distur-
bance variances are constant from observation to the OLS method does
not produce the best linear unbiased estimates. Also the calculated
probability of obtaining a zero or a one can fall outside the (0, 1)
interval., This must be'borne in mind in analysing the results
presented in Table III.3.
In addition to the problem of heteroscedasticity mentioned
above, note that the results of the regressions in which the NTBs'
were used'as the dependent variable have yielded results of poor quality.
Although the total value added per person and the non-wage added per
person have consistently yielded negative signs, the level of significance
of the estimated coefficients is very low. The other independent
variables have yielded similarly poor results with the exception of
the regional concentration of the work force by industry (RC) which is
positively correlated with the-occurrence of non-tariff barriers and
is significant, in alternate specifications, at 10 to 15 per cent
confidence level. This particular result which is clearly different
from that obtained in'analysing the structure of tariff protection is
more in accordance with the conventional theoretical formulation. It is
mainly explained by the fact that the NTBs are largely concentrated in
the textile sector which has a rather high regional concentration in
Belgium.
The pattern of the government assistance given to Belgian
industry is of special relevance in the present analysis as its structure
depends, unlike tariff protectionf and NTBs, almost entirely on national
centers of decision. As was mentioned in section II, the assistance to
industry in Belgium is given mainly within the framework of the Belgian
Economic Expansion Legislation and consists mainly of interest reductions,
capital premiums, etc.   The inter-industry assistance thus provided can
be ranked according to the investment it helped to generate. Given the
fact that the amount of assistance thus extended to the industry has shown
considerable fluctuations annually, it would be appropriate to analyse
the inter-industry concentration of assistance over a period of time.!-
In a recent study, Taeymans and Vanwynsbergh (1979) have calculated the
concentration indices of government assistance to industry for 1959-76
as a function of the investment generated, for a small and highly
aggregative sample.l/ Table III.4 shows the Spearman rank correlation
coefficient between the weighted index of the concentration of
assistance to the industry, and the different independent variables
used in the preceding multi'ple correlation regressions.
1/  An analysis of the assistance to industry for the year.1970 would
be also somewhat superfluous as some components of such assistance
have already entered into the calculation of the effective rates of
protection for that year.
2/  See the statistical appendix for the method used in the calculation of
this index.



- 15 -
TABLE III.4: SPEARMAN RANK CORRELATIONS BETWEEN INDUSTRY CHARACTERISTICS
AND CONCENTRATION OF ASSISTANCE TO INDUSTRY
INDUSTRY         ,        SPEARMAN
CHARACTERISrICS        RANK CORRELATION
COEFFICIENTS
TIVA
(TVA)                 - .548
(NWA >                 - .571
NR                      -.619
w
(p)                     - .548
C4                        .119
CH                        .071
RC                      - .476



- 16 -
The first point to be noted in analysing the table is that
none of the Spearman rank correlation coefficients show acceptable
level of significance, although the magnitude of the first four
variables approach the 0 05 significance level. Both the total
value added per person (--A) and the non-wage value added per person
(NWVA) show an inverse rank correlation, suggesting that investment
subsidies have been going mainly to industries with low value added
per person. A similai, negative rank correlation is found in the case
of wages per person (p), the natural resource product requirements (NR)
and the regional concentration of work force by industry (RC). Assistance
to industries having low average wages is in accordance with the pressure
group theory of protection. But the negative sign of the RC variable
and its rather low level of significance suggest that as far as the
concentration of assistance for investment is concerned, the regional
concentration of workforce by industry has not had much of an impact.



- 17 -
IV. CONCLUSIONS
We have tried to explain the pattern of nominal and effective
tariffs, non-tariff barriers, and the inter-industry concentration of
governmental assistance.  The national government's control over the
first two components of protection are much less than that over NTBs
and assistance to industry. Possibly partly for that reason, as well as
because of certain special characteristics of the Belgian economy, the
pattern of results we have obtained differs, in some respects, from
those found in other industrial countries. Thus for the sample of
products taken into account, nominal and effective tariffs are positively
correlated with total value added per person and non-wage value added
per person. It cannot of course be argued that the interests of the
Belgian lobbies or the pressures emanating from them had any decisive
impact on the structure of the CET. But given that Belgian industries
face intense competition from non-community high income countries with
endowment patterns which are similar to that of Belgium, it is quite
likely that the most influential among the Belgian industrial lobbies
would be happy with the maintenance of whatever protection which the
present pattern of the CET can provide for the high value added indus-
tries. On the other hand, industries using scarce natural resources,
appear to receive some tariff protection, particularly when the
effective rates are taken into account.
There is, of course, the possibility that while the structure
of tariffs provides some protection against competition from non-community
high income countries, the pattern of non-tariff barriers and assistance
to industry is skewed in favour of the more labour intensive items.
Because of the low statistical significance of the results obtained in
the empirical analysis of the structure of the NTBs and of the concentration
of assistance to industry, it is not possible to fully confirm - or reject -
this hypothesis. In general, the indications are that government assistance
to industry on the whole favours sectors with characteristics making them
vulnerable to competition from the developing countries. Thus, even a
relatively open economy such as Belgium's appears to use various national
and regional protectionist devices to shield industries facing competition
origination from countries with differing endowment patterns.



- 18 -
STATISTICAL APPENDIX
Data on effective and nominal protection rates (ET and NT)
are from the recent work of Ilzkovitz and Kestens (1978) a I European
Community sources. The products for which non-tariff barriers (NTBs)
are operative were identified with the help of the information contained
in GATT (1974). Data on the inter-industry concentration of assistance
for investments are from Taeymans and Vanwynsberghe (1979). The latter
authors estimated the concentration index by dividing the sector's share
of government assistance by the share of the investment generated.
Data on  o    value added per person ( p ) and non-wage value
added per person (-F--) are from Tharakan, Busschaert, Schoofs and Vaes
(1976).  In this study, the value added per person was calculated for
each of the industries by taking the total sales and the transfers to
other establishments, deducting from them the cost of the materials used,
and adjusting these results for changes in inventories of finished
products and of goods in processing between the first and the last day
of the year. The figures were deflated to take account of the impact of
tariffs on value added.
The natural resource product requirements are also from the
Tharakan, Busschaert, Schoofs and Vaes (1976) study in which the method
of an earlier study by Vanek (1959) was followed. The procedure used
is as follows: the structure of the input-output table is defined as
(I-A)x = f
where     I-A .    the identity matrix minus the matrix of direct
coefficients;
x       the vector of total output, and,
f    =  the vector of final demand.
The same structure can be also represented as:
(I-A)  f  =x
where:     (I-A)     = the inverse of (I-A) or the matrix of the
direct and indirect coefficients.
Matrix (I-A)    consists of elements bik which indicate the
input of good i which is required to produce a unit of final demand of
good k. We are interested here only in the additional amount of natural
resource products i* that are required to produce one unit of k. The
natural resource products were specified to contain the following sectors
in the Belgian input-output table:



- 19 -
(01) agricultural wood and forest products;
(02) fishing products;
(14) coal;
(16) crude petroleum and natural gas;
(33) iron ore;
(34) ores of non-ferrous metals;
(35) non-metallic minerals.
The total natural resource product requirements (NR) for each of the
products k:
�t b i*kX
W        The data used in the calculation of average wages per employee
(p)  are from N.I.S. (1973).   The Herfindahl index of concentration (CH)
and the share of the four largest firms (C4) are from Van Lommel, E.,
Liebaers, D., De Brabander, B. and Demeulenaere, J. (1976). In that study
CH was calculated using the following version of the Herfindahl formula:
n      2
ilxi
CH      n n    2
(E X.)
where:    Xi = the output of enterprise i.
Data available in N.I.S. (1975) on the industrial workforce
per district in Belgium were used to calculate the indices of regional
concentration of workforce per industry (RC). The following version of
the Gini-Hirschman formula was used for that purpose:
n =w10      2
RC =100       E     i
i=1



- 20 -
where:    wj = total workforce in industry i in year J.
w d  = the workforce in industry i in district d in year j.
iiJ
If the entire workforce' in a given industry were concentrated
in one district, the coefficient obtained by the above formula would be,
of course, -100.



- 21 -
REFERENCES
Anderson, K. (1978a). "The Political Market for Government Assistance
to Industry" (mimeo), Australian National University.
Anderson, K. (1978b). "Politico-Economic Factors Affecting Structural
Change and Adjustment" (mimeo), Macquarie University, Sydney.
Baldwin, R. E. (1978). "An Introduction to the Analysis of Protection
Issues" (mimeo).
Bowen, W. G. and Finegan, T. A. (1969). The Economics of Labour Force
Participation, Princeton, N. J., Princeton University Press.
Caves, R. E. (1976). "Economic Models of Political Choice: Canada's
Tariff Structure".   The Canadian Journal of Economics (IX,l)
May, pp. 278-300.
Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy, Harper and Row,
New York.
Dreze, J. (1960). "Quelques re'flexions sereines sur l'adaptation de
l'industrie Belge au Marche Commun", Comptes Rendus des
Traveaux de la Societe Royale d'Economie Politique de Belgique,
no. 275, decembre.
Helleiner, G. K. (1977), "The Political Economy of Canada's Tariff
Structure: An Alternative Model", The Canadian Journal of
Economics, (X,2), May, pp. 318-326.
N.I.S. (1973). Industriele Statistieken, 1872, nummber 3, Koninkrijk
Belgi'e, Ministerie van Economische Zaken, Brussels.
N.I.S. (1975). Volkstelling 1970, Koninkrijk Belgie, Ministerie van
Economische Zaken, Brussels, pp. 320-346.
Pincus, J. J. (1975). "Pressure Groups and the Pattern of Tariffs",
Journal of Political Economy, 83, No. 4, August, pp. 757-778.
Taeymans, P. and Vanwynsberghe, D. (1979). "Regionale Inkomensverdeling:
Gevolgen en Beleid", Veertiende Vlaams Wetenschappelijk Congres,
Inkomens - en Vermogensverdeling, Referaten, Centrum voor
Econometrie en Management Sciences, Vrije Universiteit Brussel,
pp. IV. 2.1.-IV.2.68.
Tharakan, P.K.M., Busschaert, J.A., Schoofs, W.M. and Vaes, A. (1976).
"Measurements of Factor Intensities and National Resource Content".
Centre for Development Studies, University of Antwerp, (mimeo).



- 22 -
Tharakan, P.K.M., Soete, L.G. and Busschaert, J.A. (1978). "Heckscher-
Ohlin and Chamberlain Determinants of Comparative Advantage",
European Economic Review, pp. 221-239.
Tharakan, P.K.M., Vandoorne, M. (1979). "Structure of Comparative
Advantage of Belgium vis-a-vis the Developing World", Cahiers
Economigues de Bruxelles, May, pp. 215-234.
Vanek, J. (1959). "The Natural Resource Content of Foreign Trade
1870-1955, and the Relative Abundance of Natural Resources in
the United States", Review of Economics and Statistics, May,
pp. 146-153.
Vanlommel, E., Liebaers, D., De Brabander, B. and Demeulenaere, J.
(1976). "Vergelijking van Alternatieve Concentratiemaatstaven
voor de Industriele Sectoren in Belgie", N.I.S., Statistisch
Tijdschrift, September, no. 9. pp. 889-905.



MARKET PENETRATION RESEARCH PROJECT--WORK-IN-PROGRESS REPORTS
425      Britain's Pattern of Specialization in Manufactured Goods      Vincent Cable &
with Developing Countries and Trade Protection                Ivonia Rebelo
426      Worker Adjustment to Liberalized Trade: Costs and              Graham Glenday
Assistance Policies                                           Glenn P. Jenkins
John C. Evans
427      On the Political Economy of Protection in Germany              H.H. Glismann &
F.D. Weiss
428      Italian Commercial Policies in the 1970s                       Enzo Grilli
429      Effects of Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade on Prices,
Employment, and Imports: The Case of the Swedish
Textile and Clothing Industry                                 Carl Hamilton
430      Output and Employment Changes in a "Trade
Sensiti',e" Sector: Adjustment in the U.S. Footwear           John Mutti &
Industry                                                      Malco'.m Bale
431      The Polit'cal Economy of Protection in Belgium                 P.K.M. Tharakan
432      European Community Protection Against Manufactured             Eric Verreydt
Imports from Developing Countries: A Case Study in                 &
the Pol'tical Economy of Protection                           Jean 11aelbroeck