DRAFT FOP. STAFF USE ONLY THE RELATIVE MERITS OF ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO APPLIED WELFARE ECONOMICS Anne Case (Consultant) and Lyn Squire CPD Discussion Paper Number 1985-1 February 1984 cPn Discussion Paper~ report on work in Progress and are circu1ated t0r Sank staff use to stimulate dis~ussion and comment. The ~il!Ws tnd interpretations are those of the authors. Abstract The Relative Merits of Alternative Approaches to Applied Welfare Ecnoaics This paper compares alternative methods of analyzing price policy. The "single-market" approach uses the standard technique of consumer and pro- ducer surplus. In agriculture, where substitution possibilities may be espe- cially strong, a single-market approach may leave out important repercusions in related markets. Accordingly, the single-market approach is compared with a "11lll ti-market" approach in which an effort is made to inco~porate all those markets likely to experience significant repercusions following an interven- tion in any one market. The comparison takes advantage of a multi-market model prepared for the analysis of agricultural pricing policy in Korea by Braverman, Hammer, and Ahn (CPD Discussion Paper No. 1983-2). The comparison reveals that there are important linkages with other markets. For example, a 10 pe~cent reduction in the producer price of HYV rice results in an 11 percent decline in the use of fertiliser according to the multi-market model. The single-market model is unable to capture this effect. Similarly, because of an induced change in the price of traditional rice, the 10 percent reduction in the price of HYV rice results in a 7.5 percent decline in real rural incomes according to the multi- market model whereas the single-market model reports a decline of only 1.5 percent. The interactions between markets that prove important in the Korean case are those between the price of HYY rice and the use of fertiliser and between the same price and the price of traditional rice. The final section of the paper, therefore, shows how a simple extension of the standard consumer surplus/producer surplus method can adequately allow for these considerations. The paper concludes that a single-market analysis may often yield misleading or incomplete results but that it may be possible to improve the situation substantially by relatively simple methods. TABLE OF CONTENTS ?age ~,umber I. Introduction---•••••·•••••·•·•·•·••••••••••••· II. Korean. Agricultural Pricing Policy •••••••••••• III. The Two Methods Multi-market Analysis ••••••••••••••••••••••• Single-market Analysis •••••••••••••••••••••• IV. Comparison of Results Estimation •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Positive Analysis ••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Normative Analysis ••••••••••••••.••••••••••• V. An Alternative Approach Testing for Interactions •••••••••••••••••••• An Augmented Single-Market Approach ••••••••• VI. Conclusion .••.••.••..•......... .. Appendix A: Compensating Varia Appendix B: Consumer Surplu~-·· Appendix C: Regression Results. The Relative ~terits of Alternative Aopr,,,.ches to :\f>D lled Welfare ~co"o1111£.!_ I. I '.':TRODUCTION This paper compares the positive and normative results of a ~ultt• market, agricultural pricing model with those of a single-market approach. The main advantage of the first approach is its explicit treatment ~f market interactions and interdependencies that may affect policy conclusions significantly but which are ignored by the second method. A further advantage of the particular multi-market model analyzed here results from t':"1e use of microeconomic demand systems that allow direct calculations of co::.pensating variation (or a close approximation) as the basis for welfare state111ents. ~e single-market approach, on the other hand, relies on measures of consW1er surplus. These advantages of the multi-market approach must, however, be set against its greater cost both in eonstruction ano probably in implementation. The issue, therefore, is whether the &lle~ed sup•rior accuracy of the multi-market. approach is of sufficient ~•lue to offset its presumed greater cost. The analysis takes advantage of at1 existing multi-market model for Korea [Braverman, Hammer, Ahn, 19811. 1i,e model was l!onstructed to explore alternative methods of reducing the deficit in the central buda•t arisi~g frOtl the government's agricultural pricin~ policie~. Section tl contains a brief description of the major feature• of Korean agriculture and Section ttt outlines the 1tr1Jcture of the multi-market model and deflne, the ~lfat•e m•~•ure9 for the two alternative approaches. The comparison of ?OSitlve and - 2 - developed and then compared with the full multi-market method in Section V. s~cc ion VI summarizes che main conc:usions, draws several operational ir:1p aca- tlons, and ~~ggests directions for fu~ther research. II. KOREAN AGRICULTURAL PRICING POLICY In order to achieve self-sufficiency in rice, stabilize grain prices, and uttain parity between urban and rural incomes, the government of South Korea has managed public trade in rice and barley for almost thirty years. The Grain Management Fund (GMF), responsible for all public sales in rice and barley, purchases a significant portion of the rice and barley produced each year l./ and then sells t~is grain in the urban sector at prices below the GMF's own purchase prices, but at prices well above the international prices of these grains. In ~·ears when the domestic production is insufficient to meet domestic demand, the GMF is !esponsible for importing the .necer:~ry grains. Similarly, all public trade in fertilizer is managed by the Ferti- lizer Fund (FF). The FF, under contracts prenegotiated with Aomestic pro- ducers, purchases specified amounts of fertilizer at prices above interna- ei.onal prices, and then sells this fertilizer to farmers at prices below the FF procurement price. When domestic demand falls short of the amount that the FF has guaranteed to purchase, the fertilizer remainin~ is sold by the FF in cha international market at prices lower even than the far:n ourchase price. The r.MF and FF procurement and release prices and the international prices of rice, barley and fertilizer for recent years are shown in Table 1. I/ tn 1979, the GMF purchased 1.7 milllon metric t~ns of rice, 31 percent ~f Mtfona1 production, 11nd ton percent oF. marketed 1turplus of bulev. Table I: Prices of Rice, Barley and Fertilizer Crop Rice Rice elf Barley Barley elf Fert i Uzer Fer I. t l izer cif Year Purchase Selling ·Price Purchase Selling · Pr lee Purchase Selllng Price Price Price of Rice Price Price of Price Price of Barley Fertilizer 1977 330273 319513 n.a. 190908 187805 148588 n.a. 103356 69212 1978 392277 338338 n.a. 238471 194379 87604 n.a. 104156 81796 1979 486860 432125 223000 267062 195255 90024 129000 106717 82280 (77586) 1980 638318 540086 343000 303472 221735 10161.0 187055 122916 122280 (118750) n.a.: Prices not available. Note: For rice and barley, the prices are for polished grain. (;'I Fertilizer purchase price ls a quantity weighted average of the prices of urea, potash, phosphate and three complex fertilizers. Sources: Selling prices of rice and barley: Annual Report oQ the Price Survey, EPB. Selling price of fertilizer: Report on the Results of Production Cost Survey of Agricultural Products, HAF. Purchase price of fertilizer, EPR. elf price of fertilizer: Anderson (1981), with prices provided by EPR in parenthesis Jtf price of rice: GMF elf price of barley: Anderson (1981) - 4 - The differences between government purchase and release prices, as well as the cost of processing and storing the grains and fertilizer, have left both t~e Q-!F and FF ~ith substantial deficits-in recent years. Tables 2 and 3 show the mark~d rise in Grain Management and Fertilizer Fund deficits. At present, the government of Korea wishes to reduce the GMF and FF deficits through changes in the rural procurement and urban release prices of rice and barley and the sale price of fertilizer. lf As expenditure on rice and barley accounts for approximately 30 percent of an average urban household's expenditure on food and 50 percent for that of an average rural household, the government's pricing of grains has a ·significant effect on households, as consumers, in both sectors. Y Farm households are affected additionally, as producers, by both government grain and fertilizer prices. In 1979, the average farm household produced 3700 kg. of unhulled rice and 990 kg. of unhulled common barley; sales of the two grains accounted £or 70 percent of the farm's agricultural gross receipts. In addition, the average farm used over 800 kg. of gove1·nment fertilizer in crop production, amounting to 11 percent of the farm's agricultural 1.1anagement expenditures. Thus, any change in the government's pricing of grains and fertilizer is likely to affect the welfare of l:ousebn"..ds in both sectors, as consumers, and is likely to have an additional affect on the we .. ~are of rural households, as producers. l/ Because the government is under contract with fertilizer producers, it is assumed that the ~overnment purchase price of fertilizer ma? not be changerl during the time period of the analysis. Z/ Information on urban households ls from issues of the Family Income and Expenditure Survey, Economic Planning Board. Information on farm households is from issues of the Farm Household Economic Surve:·, ~inistry of Agriculture and Fisheries (MAF), and from the Production Cost %r·•ey. -s- Table 2: Deficit in the grain Management Fund Year Rice Barley Other Subs:dy Total Grains fo,'. Wheat Flout 1970 4 28 4 28 1971 (51) 45 6 1972 (49) 61 4 .6 22 1973 (9) 88 10 165 254 1974 327 356 19 548 1250 1975 163 220 7 546 936 1976 197 286 5 15 503 1977 219 433 (2:1) 631 1978 1540 145 (94) 1591 1979 1851 285 (49) 2087 1980 1400 1068 (51) 2417 Total 5592 3015 (160) 1280 9727 - Note: Parenthesis denotes a surplus. Source: XAF, Food Grain Policy Bureau. Table 3: Deficit in the Fertilizer Fund Year 1979 1980 1981 Deficit 483 1257 1677 Cumulated 1715 2972 4649 Deficit Source: MAF III. THE TWO METHODS '.1ul ti-market Analysis The multi-market approach is developed from a microecononic base describing consumer and producer behavior. Let the indirect utility function of a representative household be: V = V (p, y) where pis a vector of consumer prices and y is full income and may be expressed as: y • A + wT + " (q, r, K) where A is unearned income, w is the wage rate, T the stock of time available to the househ~ld, and ff is profit from the household's agricultural enterprises written as a function of p~oducer prices (q), input prices including wages (r), and fixed factors (K). The compensating variation (E) for any given change in selec·,ed consumer and producer prices may be obtained from: o o l . l v(p , y) • v(p , y + E) -1- where the superscript O indicates base values and the superscript 1 denotes final values. Thus, E measures the payment that is required to keep the individual as well off with the new price regime as he was with the old - 7 - regime. The-forms for the indirect utility function and the profit function used in the Kor~a model and the implied expression f;)r conpensating variation are described in Appendix A. The pr~fit and indirect utility functions allow the derivation of output supply, input demand and consumer demand. These functions can be aggregated for all household groups to arrive at market demand and supply functions. Markets clear according to various institutional arrangement1. In the specific case of Korea, the prices of high-yielding variety (HYV) rice, barley, and fertilizer are set by the government, any imbalance between domestic supply and demand being eliminated by means of international trade. The price of traditional rice, however, is determined within the model by the interaction of domestic supply and demand. The microeconomic foundations of the model and the market-clearing conditions allow the analyst to examine the consequences of seve~al interactions. Toes~ arise from: substitution possibilities in consumption, substitution possibilities in production, input - output linkages, the income effect of a change in profits on consumer demand, and - price endogeneity. The effects of these interactions are fully captured in the multi-market model- Their presence affects predictions concerning the effect of price changes on production and consumption as well as on compensating variation through changes in farm profits and through induced changes in consumer prices. The calculation of the overall impact of pricing policy on production and consumption allows an assessment of the implications for government - s- revenue. In particular, for the Korea exercise, government revenues can be ~here R is government revenues, Si is the marketed surplus of the i th crop or sales of domestically produced fertilizer, Mi is the quantity of imports of the 1 th item, and p: is the c.i.f. price of the i th item. The change in government revenue (6R) resulting from changes in controlled prices is then simply the differences in revenue under the old and new price regimes: -2- In this calculation, full allowance is made for the general equilibrium interactions noted above. To complete the an .• lysis, it is necessary to derive a measure of efficiency gain. From aquations 1 and 2, the ~hange in welfare (tM) associated with any change in producer and consumer price is: where n- th group. _, is the m1mber of households in the j t:,.W meas•1res the change in real income to the economy. lJ If t;.W is positi·.re, welfare haR increased. Equations 1, 2 and 3 comprise the normative componenc of the analysis. These equations are us2d in the subsequent comparison of the two lJ See Zabalza (1982). - 9 - approaches. In addition, ~e report the effects of changeq in pricing policy on production and c0nsumption when full allowance is made for the ~arket interactions noted above. Single-market Analysis We now want to derive a similar set of measurP.s for a single-market analysis. Starring with ecp.~ati on 1, the true measure of comoensating variation, Appendix B identifies the assumptions required to arrive at th~ standard, single-market approximation associated with consumer surplus analysis. This procedure yields tht.? following approxi.mation: -4- where !)CS i is the change "in consumer surplus arising from changes in the price of HYV rice and barley and ~S is the change in producer surplus i arising from changes in the prices of the same crops and fertilizer. In arriving at this !pproximation, several assumptions are required. The first bea~s solely on the normative analysis. A general expression of welfare change can be derivP.d that requires only the assumption of approximate constancy of the marginal utility of income. To implement this measure, however, it would be necessary to allow for all the market interactions and interdependencies associated ~ith the multi-market analysis. To arrive at a single-market analysis, it is necessary to eliminate these interactions. Such elimination will affect bo:h the notmativ~ and the positive analyses. In particular, for the single-market analysis, all induced price changes are ignored and all cross-price effects arising from changes in controll•~d ;>rices are lgnot·ed (see Appendix B). - 10 - As a ·result of these aPsumption, changes in ccnsumotion and production predicted ~y the s in_gle-market model will differ fror.i those of the multi.:..market model. It follows that single-market predictions of changes in government revenues (see equation 2) and changes in welfare (see equation 3) will also differ. These differences are explored in Section IV. IV. COMPARISON OF RESULTS Estimation For the multi-market approach an AIDS consumer demand system and Cobb-Douglas profit functione were estimated from cross-sectional, household data. For the single-market approach, however, linear demand and supply curves were estimated from "data" generated by the multi-market model. The intention here is to duplicate the behavior of an analyst applying the single market approach. We have, therefore, assumed that the analyst is confronteJ with a set of historical "observations" on consumption, production, and prices. These observations are derived from tne multi-market model by setting government-controlled prtces and reading off the associated levels of production and consumption. In this way, the historical "data" for the s'.ngle-marke~ analysis incorporate fully all the interactio"s and market inde?endencies of the real world as capt~red in the multi-market model. The single-market analyst is then assumed to run a series of linear regressions relating consumption or production to own-price only. This procedure introduces two types of error. First, the true relationship between quantity and price is unlikely to be linear. And second, the analysis fails to control for changes in other important va~iables. This way of defining the single- market approac~ nas the advantage that we avoid issues concernin~ the ability of the multi-market model to capture reality. The multi-market model is - 11 - assumed to be a faithful reflection of reality so that differences between the results of this ~odel and those of the single-market analysis ari~e s0lely from the two so~rces of error noted above. The l~near regression results are reported in Appendix c. Positive Analvsis The overall significance of the difference between the two app,..oachl?s for estimates of production and consumption can be seen in Table 4. Note that the single market mo~el captures accurately changes in consumption and production expected to accompany changes in the rural price of HYV. Differences occur, however, for estimates of traditional rice production and fertilizer use. These differences between the models' estimates are due primarily to three of the interactions present in the multi-market model: input-output links, substitution in production and price endogeneity • . The important input-output linkage is that between output price And fertilizer use. Change in fertilizer price has only a small impacc on HYV and barley production (not shown in Table 4), but changes in commodity prices have significant effect on demand for fertilizer. For example, a 30 percent reduction in rural HYV price reduces fertilizer use by 31 percent. This cha.nge in fertilizer use is not monitored by the sin~le market model. Further, the multi-market model's incorporation of substitution in production proves to be important. A reduction in the rur~ 1 HYV subsidy causes farmers to switch out of HYV production and into that of traditional rice. While the single-market model capturas the reduction in HYV production, it fails to predict that, simultaneously,_ traditional rice production increases. F,Jr example, a 30 percent reduction in HYV rice results in a l 5 Table 4 Predictions of Conqumption and Production Percent Change in ?rice of: Rural HYV Fertilizer All Prices l/ Percent Effect on: Z/ -10 -30 10 30 10 30 HYV Production -TI:7 ~ - 5 -=cr. 7 -=r.9 -To.1 -5o.7 s~ -15.9 -47.7 0 0 -15.9 -47.7 Traditional Rice Production ~ 4.6 15. 1 0 -0 .1 5.6 18 .8 SM 0 0 0 0 0 0 Use of Fertilizer MM -11.3 -31.4 -9.9 -24.8 -22.S -63.3 SM 0 0 -13 .4 -40.0 -13.4 -40.0 Rural HYV Consumption MM 1.3 10.3 0 -0.1 3 .1 9.6 SM 3.4 10.1 0 0 3.4 10 .1 1/ Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is .rural HYV and barley prices are reduced and urban HYV, urban barley and fertilizer release prices are increased. y Base values for the analysis (in 1000 metric tons) are: HYV production - 3577.1, traditional rice production - 2110.8; Fertilizer use in barley and rice production - 882.9; Rural HYV consumption - 722.3. 3/ ~1 - multi-market analysis; SM - single-market analysis. - 13 - percent increase in traditional rice production. This has further effects ~hich are lost in the single-market model. In order for the traditional rice m~rket to clear, the increase in supply of traditional rice must be matched by an increase i.t demand, which is brought about by a fall in traditional rice price. Changes in the price of traditional rice, endogenous in the multi- market model, then affect rural and urban consUtnption, farm profits and rural and urban welfare. In the single market model, all of these interactions are lost. ~formative Analysis Differences in the two approaches' estimates of change in government revenue, sector welfare and efficiency can be seen in Tables. Note that the single market model, in capturing accurately changes in production and con- sumption of grains given changes in the rural price of HYV, provid~s estimates of deficit changes which are not quantitatively different from those of the multi-market model. For example, the single market model estimates that a 30 percent reduction in HYV price will be accompanied by a 100 percent reductior. in the government deficit, while the multi-market model predicts a 93 percent reduction in the deficit. The small difference in these estimates arises because of the input-output linkage present in the multi-market model: ignoring the reduction in deoand for fertilizer when rural HYV price is reduced, the single-market model overestimates the deficit reduction. 1J 1J Fertilizer not sold in the rural sector must be exported at a price ~ven lo~er than rural release price, Table 5 Predictions of Welfare Gains and Losses Percent Change in Price of: Rural 1-{YV Fertilizer All Prices ti Percent Effect on: 2/ -10 -30 10 .30 10 30 Government Budget Deficit MMY -42.4 -92.6 -4.5 -11.8 -80. 7 -184.7 s~ -46.3 -1on.2 -1.8 -3.5 -81.5 -19().6 Average Rural Welfare MM -2.7 -7.5 -0.1 -0.3 -3.3 -8.8 SM -0.8 -1.5 -0.1 -0.2 -1.2 -2.2 Average Urban Welfare MM 0.2 0.5 0 0 -0.2 -0.3 SM 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.7 Efficiency Gain MM 1,356 2,965 144 381 2,591 5,834 (in 100 million won)!:./ SM 1,685 3,242 58 112 2,650 6,163 l/ Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is rural HYV and barley priees are reduced and urban HYV, urban barley and fertilizer release prices are increased. 21 Base values for the analysis are: Government Budget Deficit 324~ hundred million won; Average Rural Real Disposable Income: 29900 won: Average Urhan Real Disposable Income: 23900 won. 1/ MM - multi-market analysis; SM - single-market analysis. !:./ USS m 484 won in 1979. - lS - The single-market model does not fare as well in predicting the change i~ deficit ex?ected to accompany a change i~ fertilizer price. This occurs for two reasons. First, in overestimating the reduction in demand for fertilizer whe~ the fertilizer price is increased, the single-market model underestimates government savings. In addition, an increase in fertilizer price reduces both barley and HYV production, which results in a smaller rural subsidy. While the multi-market approach models this interaction and the consequent government savings, the single-market a?proach ignores both. JJ Similarly, one of the interactions present in the multi-market model is partially responsible for differences in the approaches' estimates of welfare change. The single market model, failing to capture the effects of a change in HYV price on the traditional rice market, underestimates rural welfare loss. Reduction in the rural HYV price results in reduction of the trt:o~.itional rlce price, which causes crop profits and rural welfa·re to fall farther than they otherwise would have. For the same reason, the single- market model cannot capture the increase in urban welfare which results from the decrease in traditional rice price. The endogeneity of the traditional rice price is the first of two reasons why the models' welfare measures differ. The second is due to the difference between the approximations of welfare change employed by the models. Sl)ecifically, the multi-market model's welfare estimate al)!)roximates compensating variation, and therefore approximates the area beneath a Hicks:an compensated demand curve. The single-market models' welfare estimate is that 1/ While a 10 percent increase in fertilizer price reduces HYV production b~• only 1 percent (25 thousand metric tons), this results in substantial govern- ment savings. On each ton of HYV rice imported rather than purchased do~esti- cally, the government saves 152000 won. - 16 - of change in consumer surplus, or the area beneath a Marshallian demand curve. 13elow i:1itial equilibrium price, the Ricksian der.tand curve lies i!lside the '.larshallian demand curve for a normal good. This re.suits in a single market model overestimation of welfare ~ai!l when rice and barley prices fall. This error, which only affects the triangle, is more than outweighed by the failure to allow for the price endogeneity of traditional rice. The differences in the approaches with respect to deficits and welfare measures carry over to estimates of efficiency gain. For example, when the rural HYV price is reduced 30 percent, the single market model estimates an efficiency gain which is 28 billion won larger than that of the multi-market model. The reasons for this difference are two-fold. First, the single-market model overestimates deficit reduction. This accounts for most of the difference between the estimates (25 billion won). Also, the single- market analysis consistently overestimates gain to consumers when prices fall, and underestimates loss to producers. lf V. AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH The preceeding analysis reveals that in the Korea case only certain interactions and market interdependencies prove quantitatively significant. substitution possibilities in production coupled with price endogenity and the lJ ~1ote that, in failing !'o take into account the effect of a decrease in trarlitional rice price, the sin~le market model underestimates loss to producers. Because at the same time it underestimates gain to rural and urban consumers, this insufficiency of the sin~le mar~et appro~ch has little effect on the estimate of efficiency gain. - 17 - dependence of fertilizer demand on output price are quantitatively il!lportant interactions. 0n the other other hand, substitution poss~bilities i~ consumption and the "profit" effect prove less important. Had one possess·ed this information in advance, it would have been a relatively simple matter to incorporate the major interactions within the fram~work of consumer surplus analysis. We demonstr.ate this point below, but first we examine the question of how, in the absence of a model, one might begin to identify those interactions which warrant inclusion. Testing for Interactions In principle, one can link the change in any variable of policy interest with the change in any given policy instrument. The variables that may be of policy interest include production, consumption, and fertilizer use . (positive variables), and government budg~t deficits, urban and rural welfare, and deadweight loss (normative variables). The possible policy instruments are the urban and rural prices of HYV rice, the urban and rural prices of barley, and the farmgate price of fertilizer. Consider first the positive variables. Any of the interactions noted in Section III could be of importance. Let us examine the profit effect, that is, the effect of a change in the price of an output or input on profits and thence on total household income and consumer demand. In particular, do we think that a change in the price of fertilizer will work through profits and income to affect demand for, say, HYV rice? First, we note that fertilizer costs are only 6.6 percent of average farm profits and that farm profits are only 13 percent of average household full income. It follows immediately that any change in the price of fertilizer is unlikely to have a lar~e impact on householri full income. Second, we know that income elasticities of demand for ~ 18 - staples are usually ~ess than one so that, whatever the percentage change in household incone, the percentage change in consumption of MYV rice will be even smaller. JJ EKperimentation with plausible numbers reveals quickly that this interaction is unlikely to be i~portant and can, therefore, be dropped. This is not to suggest that this effect will be unimportant in other contexts. In fact, there is considerable microeconomic evidence to suggest that it often will he important. ~evertheless, in the Korean context, it seems safe to ignore this particular-interaction, not only for changes in the price of fertilizer but also for changes in output prices. Now let us turn to input - output linkages. The single-market analysis reveals a substantial reduction in•the production of HYV rice as its price is reduced. Since HYV rice is a major user of fertilizer, a reduction in production can be expected to have significant implications for fertilizer demand. It follows that _the price of HYV rice may be an importan.t determinant of fertilizer demand. On the other hand, since fertilizer accounts for only a small part of total costs, a change in the price of fertilizer is unlikely to have a big impact on output. Y Simple linear regressions of fertilizer l/ For marginal changes, the elasticity of HYV consumption with respect to the price of fertilizer equals the elasticity of HYV consumption with respect to income (<1) times the share of profits in total income (very small) times the ratio of fertilizer cost to net profit (also small). 1:./For a marginal change, the elasticity of the demand for fertilizer with respect to the price of the output equals the elasticity of output with respect to the price of fertilizer weighted by the ratio of the value of output to the cost of fertilizer. Thus, even if the elasticity of output with respect to the price of fertilizer is small, the elasticity of fertilizer demand can still be large if the ratio of the value of output to the cost of fertilizer is large. - 19 - demand on own-price and the price of HYV, and of HYV on own price and the price of fertilizer, reveal the diffe~ent degrees of interaction clearly. In the above cases, one can rely on information about shares - the share of profits in full income, the share of fertilizer costs in the total value of output - to guide judgements about the importance of particular interactions. For substitution possibilities in both consUl!lption and production, howe,er, there is little one can do other than make judgements about the size of the cross-price elasticities. With respect to consumption, demand studies often reveal relatively small cross-price effects. While this can not be treated as a universal conclusion, we, nevertheless, choose to ignore substitution possibilities in consumption in the remainder of the analysis. On the production side, however, it is worth investigating the ultimate destination of 'the resources released from HYV production. Since barley is grown in a different season, it cannot be considered a production substitution for HYV rice. Traditional rice, on the other hand, is an obvious substitute. Furthermore, for the multi-market analysis, the price of traditional rice is treated as an endogenous variable. This is not a result of the model but an input into the construction of the multi-market model. The information that led to this decision was derived from outside the model and may, therefore, be assumed to be available to the single-market analyst. A siople linear regression of production of traditional rice on the price of - 20 - HYV rice does, indeed, reveal an important association (see Appendix C). ]J Accordingly, in the augmented singlc-:nark~t approach presented belri;;, this interaction is incorporated. The interactions that prove imprrtant for the positive analysis may or may not prove important fo-r the normative analysis. The presence of substitution possibilities by themselves is not sufficient to cause serious errors in the single-market approach. Consider, for example, the combination of strong substitution possibilities between HYV rice and traditional rice and the price endogeneity of traditional rice. The im~ortance of these interactions for the normative analysis depends on the object of interest. If one is interested in household welfare, then these interactions are especially important because they involve an induced change in the price of a commodity that plays a significant role in the incomes of rural households and in the expenditures of both rural and urban households. Had the price change been small (which it was not) or had the commodity whose price changed been of little importance in consumption and production (which it was not), this interaction would have proved unimportant for the normative analysis. As far as household welfare is concerned, therefore, the only relevant interactions are those that lead to large induced price changes for major consumption or production items. Now let us examine the consequences of· the same interaction for measures of government revenue. Since the induced price ch~nge occurs in a lf For a marginal change, the elasticity of traditional rice output with respect to the price of HYV rice equals the elasticity of traditional rice output with respect to its own price times the elasticity of the price of traditional rice with respect to the price of HYV rice. This latter elasticity (the general equilibrium effect) is one in the Korean case. This is probably unusually large so that this effect may often be much less important than it is here. - 2l - market which is free of ~overnment inter,,ention - traditional rice is neither taxed 11or subsidized - government r't!v,mue is 1Jn,.1ffected by :l1is i:tteraction. If the primary concern, therefore, is with govern~ent revenue, this particu!ar interaction could be ignored and one would focus one's attention on changes i~ production or consumption of items that are heavily subsidized or taxed. In the·Korean case, this implies that it is more important to worry about interactions that affect fertilizer use (heavily subsidized) than those that affect production and consumption of traditional rice. Finally, if the focus of attention is deadweight loss, then cne should concentrate on changes in consumption and production that occur in distorted markets. Again, in the· particular case examined here, this would suggest a focus on the use of (heavily subsidized) fertilizer. Major price changes occurring in non-distorted markets (traditional rice, for example) do not affect deadweight loss. An Augmented Single-Market Approach To demonstrate these points, we augment the single-market analysis of Section IV to take into account those interactions which an analyst might identify as important for positive and normative analysis: the response of fertilizer demand to change in a controlled output price, and the response of traditional rice production and consumption to change in rural HYV price. Table~ presents a compariso" between the multi-market and an augmented single-market model's est:imates of the changes in production and consumption expected to accompany change in controlled prices for those cases vher• the single-market analysis was clearly deficient. Note that the augmented single- muket model effectively cloH~ the ~•ps betweei, the multi-riarl(et ~odel 's estimates and those of the single market model presenttd 1~ S.ction tV. - 22 - The significance of thes..: changes for normative anal~1sis can be seen in Table 7. Taking into account the effect of change in out?UC price on input demand brings the single market ·deficit estimates more into line with those of the multi-market model's. Note, however, that in failing to take into account the effect of a change in fertilizer price on barley and HYV production, the single-market model continues to underestimate the change in the deficit resulting from increase in fertilier price. (See Foot-no ... e 1, pa 15 e 15.) Further, incorporating the effect of change in the rural HYV price on the traditional rice market substantially improves the single marlcet .::i,del 's estimates of rural and urban welfare change. The remaining differences between the model's estimates of welfare change are due to the fact that the single-market model approximates welfare change by measuring the area beneath Marshallian demand curves. Hence the gain to rural consumers when HYV and . . .barley prices are reduced continv.es to be ovet !Stimated by the single-mark.et model. Note, however, that the changes incorporated in the single-mark.et analysis have an almost negligible effect on estimates of efficienrs ga~n. Tabliit 6 Predictions of Consumption and Production Percent Change in Price of: Rural HYV Fertilizer All P:ices lf Percent Effect on: lJ -10 -30 l9.. - 30 - 10 -30 Traditional MM1,I '• .6 15.l 0 -0.1 5.6 1a.s Rice Production SM3/ 0 0 0 0 0 0 As?'JJ S.4 16.l 0 0 S.4 16.1 Use of Fertilizer !iM -11.3 -31 .4 -9.9 -24.8 -22.s -63.3 SM 0 0 -13.4 -40.0 -13.4 -40.1) ASM -9.6 -28.7 -1.s -22.0 -23.1 -69.2 l,I Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is rural HYV and barley prices are reduced and urban HYV, urban barley.and fertilizer release.prices are i~creased. JJ Base values for the analysis (in 1000 metric tons) are: HYV production - 3577.l, traditional rice production - 2110.8; Fertilizer use in barley and rice production - 882.9; 1/ MM - multi-market analysis; SM - stngle-market.analysis; ASM - augmented single-market analysis. -;;~- Table 7 Predictions of Welfare Gains anti Losses Percent Chan~e in Price of: Rural HYV Fertilizer All Prices 1/ Percent Effect on: 2/ HYV Production M~ef - -10 -42.4 -30 -92.6 10 -4.S 30 -11.8 10 30 -184.7 -80.7 sr:J./ -46.3 -·100.2 -1 .8 -3.5 -81.5 -190.6 ASMlf -45.9 -99.2 · -2.3 -5.8 -81.1 -187.7 Average Rural Welfare MM -2.7 -7.S -o. 1 -0.3 -3.3 -8.8 SM -().8 -1.S -0.1 -0.2 -1 .2 -2.2 ASM -1.7 -4.2 -o. 1 -0.3 -2.1 -s.o Average Urban Welfare MM 0.2 .0.5 0 0 -0.2 -0.3 SM 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.7 ASM 0.3 o.~ 0 0 o.o 0.3 Efficiency Gain MM 1,356 2,965 144 381 2,591 5,834 (in 100 million won) SM 1,685 3,242 58 112 2,650 6,163 ASM 1,621 3,203 73 183 2, 86? 6,065 l./ Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is rural HYV and barley prices are reduced, and urban HYV, urban barley and fertilizer release prices are increased. 1:./ Base values for the analysis are: ·Government Budget Deficit: 3246 hundred million won; Average Rural Real Disposable Income: 29900 won; Average urban Real Disposable 23900 Income. 1/ MM - multi-market analysis; SM - single-market analysis; ASH - augmented single-market analysis. - 25 - rv. CONCLUSION 0ur conclusions can be su~marized easily: i) Single market analysis that fails to allow for interactions usually encountered in the agricultural sector can yield misleading predictions for both positive variables (e.g. the change in traditional rice production following a change in the rural price of HYV rice) and for normative variables (e.g. the change in the deficit following a change in the price of fertilizer). ii) Interactions that proved important in the Korean case are substitution possibilities in production, the price endogeneity of traditional rice, and the link between output price and fe.rtilizer demand. iii) A straightforward extension of consumer surplus analysis to incorporate these interacttons yielded results reasonably close to those of the multi-market model for the variables of interest. This exercise suggests th,;.:: che anal;yst should be very wary of results produced by a single-market/consumer surplus approach. If, for reasons of time and resources, the analyst is unable to prepare a multi-market model, considerable effort should be devoted to exploring the likely consequences of omitted interactions and, where these prove significant, to extending the analysis along the lines suggested in this paper. Finally, fro~ a research perspective, it would be extremely valuable to investigate whether th~ interactions that proved unimportant in the Korean case can also be expected to be insignificant in other situations, - 26 - APPENDIX A Compensating Variation The indirect utility function consistent with the AIDS model employed in t~e· multi-market approach is: (1) where income (Y) refers to full income and includes wage income, value of leisure time, crop profits (rural sector only) and other income. Profits ar2 expressed: (2) for all crops (n), inputs (i), output prices (P) and input prices (W). (PI) refers to the AIDS price index, which is a function of the prices of crops and leisure. From the indirect utility function (1), compensating variation, E, is derived: (3) This measure of welfare change is exact, but provides useful information only when the AIDS cost function is concave and strictly quasi-concave in prices. As this is not true of the Korea AIDS cost function in the price range in which simulation takes place, an approximation to welfare loss must be employed. The approximation chosen here is change in real disposable income deflated by the AIDS price index. - 27 - ( 4) (DY) refers to nominal full income minus the value of leisure. ~ote that this approximation is equivalent to compensating variation provided two assumptions hold. First, it is assumed that demands are hornothetic (i.e., Bn = o for all n). In addition, it is assumed that the value of leisure is not affected by change in controlled or endogenous prices. - 28.- APPENDIX B: Consumer and Producer Surplus lJ D~finirion of Compensating Variation -1- Differentiate l wrt all prices: Example: For i th price, -2- (If producer prices are not affected, dy0 /dp0 • Q .• If consUt11er prices are i not affected, By Roy's Identity, C i • dE 0 -3- 0 ~sumption_,!_ dv/dy1 ,:, dv/dy 0 -ci + dy /dp~ • dE/dp~ -4- -l Since E • pl J Po 2 .... dE dP + pl pl 1J 2 Po 3 .... dE dP -s- Pl 0 po 2 .... dP l 1 po po l 2 po 3 •••• dP 2 2 •••• lJ See Glaister (1974) for a similar argument. - 29 - l + •••• Pnd dE dP dP n •••• Pn n pl dy Po Po ) ~ E = I J Po C (P 1 2 .... y) - dP 1 (Pl' - 2 •••• dp l ., p ., 1 - Pn° C 1 (P 1 • • • •, p n' y) - dy dPn 1 (p1 .... Pn> dp -6- 1 l 1 E .., - 6CS, (Pl' 00 •l , 0 p2····> - ecs 2 (P 2' 0 p 2' p 1' 0 ?3••··> -7- + ty Assumption 2 Set c~ 1 • o for all 1 where d? 1 , some arbitrarily small constant Assumption 3 Assume independent price changes. E .. - r6 . , Po. csj ( P 1 o -1:j ) . , Pk + 6y -8- .1 J The change in money income (6y) is derived: -9- - 30 - where (i) denotes each output whose price undergoes change and (f) denotes fertilizer. ~oting that, from the profit function, d 1Ti/dp~ = x and i' differentiating (9) with respect to initial outp~t und input prices yie!ds: dni - --= - L X f i = - ,cf -10- dP~ :r ' Expressing (9) as ~ 1 (Pl' P2, 1 • ·p~ ) ~ n dp -11- dP l1 and substituting from (10) yields: -12- Given that each x 1 denotes an output supply curve and xf denotes an input demand curve, and again assumin~ independent price changes, we can express t:.y as: Compensating variation can now be expressed: - 31 - APPENDIX C: Regression Results A data set for single market analyses was generated by simulating the results of the multi-marKet model for 37 different sets of controlled prices. For each simulation, a controlled price was changed by 5-30 percent from its initial level. For 6 of the simulations, all controlled prices were varied by 5-30 percent. OLS regressions were performed on this data set, and the coefficients of these regressions were employed in the singl~ market analysis of Section IV. All coefficients were significant on 95 percent confidence interval. Supply HYV = -2088.27 + 14.99 * Rural Price HYV (R 2 • 0.918) Supply Barley = 1375.27 + 10.94 * Rural Price Barley (R2 - 0.993) Demand Fertilizer .. 190.8.36 - 11.13 * Rural Price Fertilizer (R 2 • o•. 524) Urban Demand HYV = 2904.05 - 2.48 * Urban Price HYV Urban Demand Barley~ 213.15 - 0.4 * Urban Price Barley (R 2 • 0.360) Rural Demand HYV • 1501.25 - 1.01 * Rural Price HYV (R 2 • 0.997) Rural Demand Barley• 501.27 - 0.62 * Rural Price Barley (R 2 • 0.360) In Section V, the single market model is augmented to take into account the effect of rural HYV price on production and consumption of traditional rice and ~he effect of rural HYV and barley prices on demand for fertilizet. The following regressions were run on the same set of tUUlti- - 32 - market similation results, and the coefficients were employed in the au~mented si~gle ~arket analysis of Section V. All coefficients were sig~ificant on a 95 percent confidence interval. Supply Trad. Rice = 3249.75 - 3.02 * Price Rural HYV (R 2 = 0.967) Rural Demand Trad. Rice= 953.99 - 0.62 * Price Rural HYV (R 2 = 0.99;) Urban Trad. Rice = 2033.56 - 2.16 * Price Rural HYV (R 2 = 0.946) Demand Fertilizer~ 172.61 - 6.68 * Rural Price Fertilizer + 2.2 * Rural Price HYV + 1.95 * Rural Price Barley (R 2 = 0.987) - 33 - References Braver;nan, Avishay, Jeffrey s. Hammer and Choorg Yong Ahn, "Government Deficit Reduction and Alternative Agricultural Pricing Policies in Korea", CPD Discussion Paper No. 1983-2 (revised), August, 1983. Glaister, Stephen, "Generalized Consumer Surplus and Public Transport Pricing", Economic Journal, December, 1974, Vol. 84, No. 336, pp. 849- 867. Zabalza, A.~ "Cocpensating and Equivalent Variations, and the Deadweight Loss of Taxation", Economica, August, 1982, Vol. 49, No.____, pp. 355-359.