DRAFT
                                                       FOP. STAFF USE ONLY




THE RELATIVE MERITS OF ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO APPLIED
WELFARE ECONOMICS




Anne Case (Consultant)
and
Lyn Squire


CPD Discussion Paper Number 1985-1
February 1984




cPn   Discussion Paper~ report on work in Progress and are circu1ated
t0r   Sank staff use to stimulate dis~ussion and comment. The ~il!Ws
tnd   interpretations are those of the authors.
                                   Abstract

  The Relative Merits of Alternative Approaches to Applied Welfare Ecnoaics



            This paper compares alternative methods of analyzing price policy.
The "single-market" approach uses the standard technique of consumer and pro-
ducer surplus. In agriculture, where substitution possibilities may be espe-
cially strong, a single-market approach may leave out important repercusions
in related markets. Accordingly, the single-market approach is compared with
a "11lll ti-market" approach in which an effort is made to inco~porate all those
markets likely to experience significant repercusions following an interven-
tion in any one market.

         The comparison takes advantage of a multi-market model prepared for
the analysis of agricultural pricing policy in Korea by Braverman, Hammer, and
Ahn (CPD Discussion Paper No. 1983-2). The comparison reveals that there are
important linkages with other markets. For example, a 10 pe~cent reduction in
the producer price of HYV rice results in an 11 percent decline in the use of
fertiliser according to the multi-market model.    The single-market model is
unable to capture this effect. Similarly, because of an induced change in the
price of traditional rice, the 10 percent reduction in the price of HYV rice
results in a 7.5 percent decline in real rural incomes according to the multi-
market model whereas the single-market model reports a decline of only 1.5
percent.

         The interactions between markets that prove important in the Korean
case are those between the price of HYY rice and the use of fertiliser and
between the same price and the price of traditional rice. The final section
of the paper, therefore, shows how a simple extension of the standard consumer
surplus/producer surplus method can adequately allow for these considerations.
The paper concludes that a single-market analysis may often yield misleading
or incomplete results but that it may be possible to improve the situation
substantially by relatively simple methods.
                               TABLE OF CONTENTS


                                                      ?age ~,umber

  I.   Introduction---•••••·•••••·•·•·•·••••••••••••·
 II.   Korean. Agricultural Pricing Policy ••••••••••••

III.   The Two Methods
         Multi-market Analysis •••••••••••••••••••••••
         Single-market Analysis ••••••••••••••••••••••

 IV.   Comparison of Results
         Estimation ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••
         Positive Analysis •••••••••••••••••••••••••••
         Normative Analysis ••••••••••••••.•••••••••••

  V.   An Alternative Approach
         Testing for Interactions ••••••••••••••••••••
         An Augmented Single-Market Approach •••••••••

 VI.   Conclusion .••.••.••..•......... ..

       Appendix A:   Compensating Varia
       Appendix B:   Consumer Surplu~-··
       Appendix C:   Regression Results.
                            The Relative ~terits of Alternative
                          Aopr,,,.ches to :\f>D lled Welfare ~co"o1111£.!_

I.   I '.':TRODUCTION

           This paper compares the positive and normative results of a ~ultt•
market, agricultural pricing model with those of a single-market approach.
The main advantage of the first approach is its explicit treatment ~f market

interactions and interdependencies that may affect policy conclusions
significantly but which are ignored by the second method.                    A further advantage

of the particular multi-market model analyzed here results from t':"1e use of
microeconomic demand systems that allow direct calculations of co::.pensating

variation (or a close approximation) as the basis for welfare state111ents.                  ~e

single-market approach, on the other hand, relies on measures of consW1er
surplus.    These advantages of the multi-market approach must, however, be set
against its greater cost both in eonstruction ano probably in

implementation.         The issue, therefore, is whether the &lle~ed sup•rior
accuracy of the multi-market. approach is of sufficient ~•lue to offset its

presumed greater cost.
           The analysis takes advantage of at1 existing multi-market model for
Korea [Braverman, Hammer, Ahn, 19811.             1i,e   model was l!onstructed to explore
alternative methods of reducing the deficit in the central buda•t arisi~g frOtl
the government's agricultural pricin~ policie~.                Section tl contains a brief
description of the major feature• of Korean agriculture and Section ttt
outlines the 1tr1Jcture of the multi-market model and deflne, the ~lfat•e
m•~•ure9 for the two alternative approaches.                The comparison of ?OSitlve and
                                           - 2 -


developed and then compared with the full multi-market method in Section V.

s~cc ion VI summarizes che main conc:usions, draws several operational ir:1p aca-

tlons, and ~~ggests directions for fu~ther research.



II.    KOREAN AGRICULTURAL PRICING POLICY
             In order to achieve self-sufficiency in rice, stabilize grain prices,

and uttain parity between urban and rural incomes, the government of South

Korea has managed public trade in rice and barley for almost thirty years.

The Grain Management Fund (GMF), responsible for all public sales in rice and

barley, purchases a significant portion of the rice and barley produced each

year   l./   and then sells t~is grain in the urban sector at prices below the

GMF's own purchase prices, but at prices well above the international prices

of these grains.       In ~·ears when the domestic production is insufficient to

meet domestic demand, the GMF is !esponsible for importing the .necer:~ry

grains.

              Similarly, all public trade in fertilizer is managed by the Ferti-

lizer Fund (FF).       The FF, under contracts prenegotiated with Aomestic pro-

ducers, purchases specified amounts of fertilizer at prices above interna-

ei.onal prices, and then sells this fertilizer to farmers at prices below the

FF procurement price.       When domestic demand falls short of the amount that the

FF has guaranteed to purchase, the fertilizer remainin~ is sold by the FF in
cha international market at prices lower even than the far:n ourchase price.

              The r.MF and FF procurement and release prices and the international

prices of rice, barley and fertilizer for recent years are shown in Table 1.




 I/    tn 1979, the GMF purchased 1.7 milllon metric t~ns of rice, 31 percent      ~f
Mtfona1 production, 11nd      ton   percent oF. marketed 1turplus of bulev.
                                            Table I:   Prices of Rice, Barley and Fertilizer



Crop         Rice         Rice        elf         Barley       Barley        elf      Fert i Uzer   Fer I. t l izer     cif
Year       Purchase      Selling     ·Price      Purchase      Selling     · Pr lee    Purchase       Selllng          Price
             Price        Price     of Rice       Price         Price        of        Price            Price           of
                                                                           Barley                                     Fertilizer

1977         330273       319513       n.a.        190908       187805     148588           n.a.          103356          69212

1978         392277       338338       n.a.        238471       194379      87604           n.a.          104156         81796

1979        486860        432125     223000        267062       195255      90024         129000          106717          82280
                                                                                                                         (77586)

1980         638318       540086     343000        303472       221735     10161.0        187055          122916         122280
                                                                                                                        (118750)


n.a.:   Prices not available.

Note:   For rice and barley, the prices are for polished grain.                                                                    (;'I
        Fertilizer purchase price ls a quantity weighted average of the prices of urea,
        potash, phosphate and three complex fertilizers.

Sources:   Selling prices of rice and barley: Annual Report oQ the Price Survey, EPB.
           Selling price of fertilizer: Report on the Results of Production Cost Survey
           of Agricultural Products, HAF.
           Purchase price of fertilizer, EPR.
           elf price of fertilizer: Anderson (1981), with prices provided by EPR in parenthesis
           Jtf price of rice: GMF
           elf price of barley: Anderson (1981)
                                      - 4 -



The differences between government purchase and release prices, as well as the

cost of processing and storing the grains and fertilizer, have left both t~e

Q-!F and FF ~ith substantial deficits-in recent years.   Tables 2 and 3 show the

mark~d rise in Grain Management and Fertilizer Fund deficits.     At present, the

government of Korea wishes to reduce the GMF and FF deficits through changes

in the rural procurement and urban release prices of rice and barley and the

sale price of fertilizer.   lf
          As expenditure on rice and barley accounts for approximately 30

percent of an average urban household's expenditure on food and 50 percent for

that of an average rural household, the government's pricing of grains has a

·significant effect on households, as consumers, in both sectors.   Y   Farm

households are affected additionally, as producers, by both government grain

and fertilizer prices.    In 1979, the average farm household produced 3700 kg.

of unhulled rice and 990 kg. of unhulled common barley; sales of the two

grains accounted £or 70 percent of the farm's agricultural gross receipts.         In

addition, the average farm used over 800 kg. of gove1·nment fertilizer in crop

 production, amounting to 11 percent of the farm's agricultural 1.1anagement

expenditures.   Thus, any change in the government's pricing of grains and

 fertilizer is likely to affect the welfare of l:ousebn"..ds in both sectors, as

 consumers, and is likely to have an additional affect on the we .. ~are of rural

households, as producers.




 l/ Because the government is under contract with fertilizer producers, it is
 assumed that the ~overnment purchase price of fertilizer ma? not be changerl
 during the time period of the analysis.

 Z/ Information on urban households ls from issues of the Family Income and
 Expenditure Survey, Economic Planning Board. Information on farm households
 is from issues of the Farm Household Economic Surve:·, ~inistry of Agriculture
 and Fisheries (MAF), and from the Production Cost %r·•ey.
                                               -s-
                    Table 2:      Deficit in the grain Management Fund



Year               Rice         Barley         Other     Subs:dy         Total
                                               Grains      fo,'.
                                                          Wheat
                                                          Flout

1970                  4             28             4                        28
1971                (51)            45             6
1972                (49)            61             4         .6             22
1973                 (9)            88            10        165            254
1974                327            356            19        548           1250
1975                163            220             7        546            936
1976                197            286             5         15            503
1977                219            433          (2:1)                      631
1978               1540            145          (94)                      1591
1979               1851            285          (49)                      2087
1980               1400           1068          (51)                      2417


Total              5592           3015          (160)       1280          9727


-
Note:     Parenthesis denotes a surplus.

Source:    XAF, Food Grain Policy Bureau.




                           Table 3:   Deficit in the Fertilizer Fund



            Year                      1979      1980           1981


            Deficit                      483    1257           1677


            Cumulated                 1715      2972           4649
            Deficit

            Source:       MAF
III. THE TWO METHODS

'.1ul ti-market Analysis

          The multi-market approach is developed from a microecononic base

describing consumer and producer behavior.                   Let the indirect utility function

of a representative household be:



                                            V   =   V   (p, y)




where pis a vector of consumer prices and y is full income and may be

expressed as:



                                      y • A + wT + " (q, r, K)



where A is unearned income, w is the wage rate, T the stock of time available

to the househ~ld, and          ff   is profit from the household's agricultural

enterprises written as a function of p~oducer prices (q), input prices

including wages (r), and fixed factors (K).

          The compensating variation (E) for any given change in selec·,ed

consumer and producer prices may be obtained from:


                                         o   o      l . l
                                      v(p , y) • v(p , y + E)                         -1-



where the superscript      O
                                    indicates base values and the superscript 1 denotes

 final values.    Thus, E measures the payment that is required to keep the

individual as well off with the new price regime as he was with the old
                                      - 7 -


regime.   The-forms for the indirect utility function and the profit function

used in the Kor~a model and the implied expression f;)r conpensating variation

are described in Appendix A.

          The pr~fit and indirect utility functions allow the derivation of

output supply, input demand and consumer demand.    These functions can be

aggregated for all household groups to arrive at market demand and supply

functions.    Markets clear according to various institutional arrangement1.    In

the specific case of Korea, the prices of high-yielding variety (HYV) rice,

barley, and fertilizer are set by the government, any imbalance between

domestic supply and demand being eliminated by means of international trade.

The price of traditional rice, however, is determined within the model by the

interaction of domestic supply and demand.

          The microeconomic foundations of the model and the market-clearing

conditions allow the analyst to examine the consequences of seve~al

interactions.    Toes~ arise from:



              substitution possibilities in consumption,
              substitution possibilities in production,
              input - output linkages,
              the income effect of a change in profits on consumer demand, and
          -   price endogeneity.



The effects of these interactions are fully captured in the multi-market
model-    Their presence affects predictions concerning the effect of price

changes on production and consumption as well as on compensating variation

through changes in farm profits and through induced changes in consumer

prices.

           The calculation of the overall impact of pricing policy on production

and consumption allows an assessment of the implications for government
                                        - s-

revenue.    In particular, for the Korea exercise, government revenues can be




~here R is government revenues, Si is the marketed surplus of the i th crop or

sales of domestically produced fertilizer, Mi is the quantity of imports of

the 1 th item, and   p: is   the c.i.f. price of the i th item.    The change in

government revenue     (6R) resulting from changes in controlled prices is then

simply the differences in revenue under the old and new price regimes:



                                                                               -2-


In this calculation, full allowance is made for the general equilibrium

interactions noted above.

           To complete the an .• lysis, it is necessary to derive a measure of

efficiency gain.     From aquations 1 and 2, the ~hange in welfare

 (tM)   associated with any change in producer and consumer price is:




where n-                                       th group.
       _, is the m1mber of households in the j                  t:,.W meas•1res the

change in real income to the economy.     lJ   If   t;.W is positi·.re, welfare haR

increased.    Equations 1, 2 and 3 comprise the normative componenc of the

analysis.    These equations are us2d in the subsequent comparison of the two




lJ   See Zabalza (1982).
                                         - 9 -



approaches.     In addition, ~e report the effects of changeq in pricing policy

on production and c0nsumption when full allowance is made for the ~arket

interactions noted above.



Single-market Analysis

            We now want to derive a similar set of measurP.s for a single-market

analysis.     Starring with ecp.~ati on 1, the true measure of comoensating

variation, Appendix B identifies the assumptions required to arrive at th~

standard, single-market approximation associated with consumer surplus

analysis.     This procedure yields tht.? following approxi.mation:



                                                                              -4-



where   !)CS i is the change "in consumer surplus arising from changes in the

price of HYV rice and barley and      ~S       is the change in producer surplus
                                           i
arising from changes in the prices of the same crops and fertilizer.

            In arriving at this !pproximation, several assumptions are

required.     The first bea~s solely on the normative analysis.       A general

expression of welfare change can be derivP.d that requires only the assumption

of approximate constancy of the marginal utility of income.           To implement this

measure, however, it would be necessary to allow for all the market

interactions and interdependencies associated ~ith the multi-market

analysis.     To arrive at a single-market analysis, it is necessary to eliminate

these interactions.      Such elimination will affect bo:h the notmativ~ and the

positive analyses.      In particular, for the single-market analysis, all induced

price changes are ignored and all cross-price effects arising from changes in

controll•~d ;>rices are lgnot·ed (see Appendix B).
                                          - 10 -



           As a ·result of these aPsumption, changes in ccnsumotion and

production predicted ~y the s in_gle-market model will differ fror.i those of the

multi.:..market model.     It follows that single-market predictions of changes in

government revenues (see equation 2) and changes in welfare (see equation 3)

will also differ.        These differences are explored in Section IV.



IV.     COMPARISON OF RESULTS

Estimation

            For the multi-market approach an AIDS consumer demand system and

Cobb-Douglas profit functione were estimated from cross-sectional, household

data.     For the single-market approach, however, linear demand and supply

curves were estimated from "data" generated by the multi-market model.             The

intention here is to duplicate the behavior of an analyst applying the single

market approach.     We have, therefore, assumed that the analyst is confronteJ

with a set of historical "observations" on consumption, production, and

prices.     These observations are derived from tne multi-market model by setting

government-controlled prtces and reading off the associated levels of

production and consumption.        In this way, the historical "data" for the

s'.ngle-marke~ analysis incorporate fully all the interactio"s and market

inde?endencies of the real world as capt~red in the multi-market model.             The
single-market analyst is then assumed to run a series of linear regressions

relating consumption or production to own-price only.          This procedure
introduces two types of error.        First, the true relationship between quantity

and price is unlikely to be linear.        And second, the analysis fails to control

for changes in other important va~iables.          This way of defining the single-

market approac~ nas the advantage that we avoid issues concernin~ the ability

of the multi-market model to capture reality.          The multi-market model is
                                      - 11 -



assumed to be a faithful reflection of reality so that differences between the

results of this ~odel and those of the single-market analysis ari~e s0lely

from the two so~rces of error noted above.     The l~near regression results are

reported in Appendix    c.


Positive Analvsis

         The overall significance of the difference between the two app,..oachl?s

for estimates of production and consumption can be seen in Table 4.      Note that

the single market mo~el captures accurately changes in consumption and

production expected to accompany changes in the rural price of HYV.

Differences occur, however, for estimates of traditional rice production and

fertilizer use.     These differences between the models' estimates are due

primarily to three of the interactions present in the multi-market model:

input-output links, substitution in production and price endogeneity •
                                       .
         The important input-output linkage is that between output price And

fertilizer use.     Change in fertilizer price has only a small impacc on HYV and

barley production (not shown in Table 4), but changes in commodity prices have

significant effect on demand for fertilizer.     For example, a 30 percent

reduction in rural HYV price reduces fertilizer use by 31 percent.      This

cha.nge in fertilizer use is not monitored by the sin~le market model.

          Further, the multi-market model's incorporation of substitution in

production proves to be important.     A reduction in the rur~ 1 HYV subsidy

causes farmers to switch out of HYV production and into that of traditional

rice.   While the single-market model capturas the reduction in HYV production,

it fails to predict that, simultaneously,_ traditional rice production

increases.   F,Jr example, a 30 percent reduction in HYV rice results in a l 5
                                     Table 4
                    Predictions of Conqumption and Production

                                            Percent Change in ?rice of:
                                     Rural HYV     Fertilizer     All Prices l/

Percent Effect on: Z/                -10    -30        10       30       10         30
HYV Production                      -TI:7 ~ - 5       -=cr. 7   -=r.9    -To.1    -5o.7
                              s~ -15.9 -47.7                0        0   -15.9    -47.7


Traditional Rice Production   ~       4.6    15. 1          0   -0 .1      5.6     18 .8

                              SM       0          0         0        0        0      0


Use of Fertilizer             MM    -11.3   -31.4      -9.9     -24.8    -22.S    -63.3

                              SM       0          0   -13 .4    -40.0    -13.4    -40.0


Rural HYV Consumption         MM      1.3    10.3           0    -0.1      3 .1     9.6

                              SM      3.4    10.1           0        0     3.4     10 .1


1/   Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is
     .rural HYV and barley prices are reduced and urban HYV, urban barley and
      fertilizer release prices are increased.
y    Base values for the analysis (in 1000 metric tons) are: HYV production -
     3577.1, traditional rice production - 2110.8; Fertilizer use in barley and
     rice production - 882.9; Rural HYV consumption - 722.3.
3/   ~1 - multi-market analysis; SM - single-market analysis.
                                     - 13 -



percent increase in traditional rice production.   This has further effects

~hich are lost in the single-market model.    In order for the traditional rice

m~rket to clear, the increase in supply of traditional rice must be matched by

an increase i.t demand, which is brought about by a fall in traditional rice

price.   Changes in the price of traditional rice, endogenous in the multi-

market model, then affect rural and urban consUtnption, farm profits and rural

and urban welfare.    In the single market model, all of these interactions are

lost.



~formative Analysis

          Differences in the two approaches' estimates of change in government

revenue, sector welfare and efficiency can be seen in Tables.     Note that the

single market model, in capturing accurately changes in production and con-

sumption of grains given changes in the rural price of HYV, provid~s estimates

of deficit changes which are not quantitatively different from those of the

multi-market model.    For example, the single market model estimates that a 30

percent reduction in HYV price will be accompanied by a 100 percent reductior.

in the government deficit, while the multi-market model predicts a 93 percent

reduction in the deficit.    The small difference in these estimates arises

because of the input-output linkage present in the multi-market model:

ignoring the reduction in deoand for fertilizer when rural HYV price is

reduced, the single-market model overestimates the deficit reduction.   1J




1J  Fertilizer not sold in the rural sector must be exported at a price ~ven
lo~er than rural release price,
                                          Table 5
                          Predictions of Welfare Gains and Losses

                                                   Percent Change in Price of:
                                           Rural 1-{YV    Fertilizer     All Prices ti

Percent Effect on: 2/                      -10     -30         10
                                                                        .30        10         30


Government Budget Deficit           MMY   -42.4     -92.6      -4.5     -11.8     -80. 7   -184.7

                                    s~    -46.3    -1on.2      -1.8      -3.5     -81.5    -19().6


Average Rural Welfare               MM     -2.7      -7.5      -0.1      -0.3      -3.3      -8.8

                                    SM      -0.8     -1.5      -0.1      -0.2       -1.2     -2.2


Average Urban Welfare               MM       0.2         0.5        0         0    -0.2      -0.3

                                    SM        0           0         0         0    -0.2      -0.7


Efficiency Gain                     MM    1,356    2,965       144       381      2,591    5,834

(in 100 million won)!:./            SM    1,685    3,242        58       112      2,650    6,163


l/     Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is
       rural HYV and barley priees are reduced and urban HYV, urban barley and
       fertilizer release prices are increased.
21     Base values for the analysis are: Government Budget Deficit 324~ hundred
       million won; Average Rural Real Disposable Income: 29900 won: Average
       Urhan Real Disposable Income: 23900 won.

1/     MM - multi-market analysis; SM - single-market analysis.

!:./   USS   m   484 won in 1979.
                                      -   lS -



           The single-market model does not fare as well in predicting the

change i~ deficit ex?ected to accompany a change i~ fertilizer price.      This

occurs for two reasons.     First, in overestimating the reduction in demand for

fertilizer whe~ the fertilizer price is increased, the single-market model

underestimates government savings.     In addition, an increase in fertilizer

price reduces both barley and HYV production, which results in a smaller rural

subsidy.    While the multi-market approach models this interaction and the

consequent government savings, the single-market a?proach ignores both.     JJ
           Similarly, one of the interactions present in the multi-market model

is partially responsible for differences in the approaches' estimates of

welfare change.    The single market model, failing to capture the effects of a

change in HYV price on the traditional rice market, underestimates rural

welfare loss.     Reduction in the rural HYV price results in reduction of the

trt:o~.itional rlce price, which causes crop profits and rural welfa·re to fall

farther than they otherwise would have.      For the same reason, the single-

market model cannot capture the increase in urban welfare which results from

the decrease in traditional rice price.

           The endogeneity of the traditional rice price is the first of two

reasons why the models' welfare measures differ.      The second is due to the

difference between the approximations of welfare change employed by the
models.    Sl)ecifically, the multi-market model's welfare estimate al)!)roximates

compensating variation, and therefore approximates the area beneath a Hicks:an

compensated demand curve.     The single-market models' welfare estimate is that




1/ While a 10 percent increase in fertilizer price reduces HYV production b~•
only 1 percent (25 thousand metric tons), this results in substantial govern-
ment savings. On each ton of HYV rice imported rather than purchased do~esti-
cally, the government saves 152000 won.
                                        - 16 -



of change in consumer surplus, or the area beneath a Marshallian demand

curve.    13elow i:1itial equilibrium price, the Ricksian der.tand curve lies i!lside

the '.larshallian demand curve for a normal good.     This re.suits in a single

market model overestimation of welfare ~ai!l when rice and barley prices

fall.    This error, which only affects the triangle, is more than outweighed by

the failure to allow for the price endogeneity of traditional rice.

           The differences in the approaches with respect to deficits and

welfare measures carry over to estimates of efficiency gain.        For example,

when the rural HYV price is reduced 30 percent, the single market model

estimates an efficiency gain which is 28 billion won larger than that of the

multi-market model.     The reasons for this difference are two-fold.     First, the

single-market model overestimates deficit reduction.       This accounts for most

of the difference between the estimates (25 billion won).        Also, the single-

market analysis consistently overestimates gain to consumers when prices fall,

and underestimates loss to producers.     lf


V.      AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH

           The preceeding analysis reveals that in the Korea case only certain

interactions and market interdependencies prove quantitatively significant.


substitution possibilities in production coupled with price endogenity and the




lJ  ~1ote that, in failing !'o take into account the effect of a decrease in
trarlitional rice price, the sin~le market model underestimates loss to
producers. Because at the same time it underestimates gain to rural and urban
consumers, this insufficiency of the sin~le mar~et appro~ch has little effect
on the estimate of efficiency gain.
                                      - 17 -



dependence of fertilizer demand on output price are quantitatively il!lportant

interactions.    0n the other other hand, substitution poss~bilities i~

consumption and the "profit" effect prove less important.     Had one possess·ed

this information in advance, it would have been a relatively simple matter to

incorporate the major interactions within the fram~work of consumer surplus

analysis.    We demonstr.ate this point below, but first we examine the question

of how, in the absence of a model, one might begin to identify those

interactions which warrant inclusion.



Testing for Interactions

            In principle, one can link the change in any variable of policy

interest with the change in any given policy instrument.     The variables that

may be of policy interest include production, consumption, and fertilizer use
                                                              .
(positive variables), and government budg~t deficits, urban and rural welfare,

and deadweight loss (normative variables).     The possible policy instruments

are the urban and rural prices of HYV rice, the urban and rural prices of

barley, and the farmgate price of fertilizer.

            Consider first the positive variables.   Any of the interactions noted

in Section III could be of importance.     Let us examine the profit effect, that

is, the effect of a change in the price of an output or input on profits and

thence on total household income and consumer demand.      In particular, do we

think that a change in the price of fertilizer will work through profits and

income to affect demand for, say, HYV rice?     First, we note that fertilizer

costs are only 6.6 percent of average farm profits and that farm profits are

only 13 percent of average household full income.      It follows immediately that

any change in the price of fertilizer is unlikely to have a lar~e impact on

householri full income.    Second, we know that income elasticities of demand for
                                        ~   18 -



staples are usually ~ess than one so that, whatever the percentage change in

household incone, the percentage change in consumption of MYV rice will be

even smaller.   JJ   EKperimentation with plausible numbers reveals quickly that

this interaction is unlikely to be i~portant and can, therefore, be dropped.

This is not to suggest that this effect will be unimportant in other

contexts.     In fact, there is considerable microeconomic evidence to suggest

that it often will he important.      ~evertheless, in the Korean context, it

seems safe to ignore this particular-interaction, not only for changes in the

price of fertilizer but also for changes in output prices.

            Now let us turn to input - output linkages.    The single-market

analysis reveals a substantial reduction in•the production of HYV rice as its

price is reduced.     Since HYV rice is a major user of fertilizer, a reduction

in production can be expected to have significant implications for fertilizer

demand.     It follows that _the price of HYV rice may be an importan.t determinant

of fertilizer demand.     On   the other hand, since fertilizer accounts for only a

small part of total costs, a change in the price of fertilizer is unlikely to

have a big impact on output.     Y    Simple linear regressions of fertilizer




l/ For marginal changes, the elasticity of HYV consumption with respect to
the price of fertilizer equals the elasticity of HYV consumption with respect
to income (<1) times the share of profits in total income (very small) times
the ratio of fertilizer cost to net profit (also small).

1:./For a marginal change, the elasticity of the demand for fertilizer with
respect to the price of the output equals the elasticity of output with
respect to the price of fertilizer weighted by the ratio of the value of
output to the cost of fertilizer. Thus, even if the elasticity of output with
respect to the price of fertilizer is small, the elasticity of fertilizer
demand can still be large if the ratio of the value of output to the cost of
fertilizer is large.
                                        - 19 -



demand on own-price and the price of HYV, and of HYV on own price and the

price of fertilizer, reveal the diffe~ent degrees of interaction clearly.

            In the above cases, one can rely on information about shares - the

share of profits in full income, the share of fertilizer costs in the total

value of output - to guide judgements about the importance of particular

interactions.      For substitution possibilities in both consUl!lption and

production, howe,er, there is little one can do other than make judgements

about the size of the cross-price elasticities.       With respect to consumption,

demand studies often reveal relatively small cross-price effects.       While this

can not be treated as a universal conclusion, we, nevertheless, choose to

ignore substitution possibilities in consumption in the remainder of the

analysis.

            On   the production side, however, it is worth investigating the

ultimate destination of 'the resources released from HYV production.          Since

barley is grown in a different season, it cannot be considered a production

substitution for HYV rice.      Traditional rice, on the other hand, is an obvious

substitute.       Furthermore, for the multi-market analysis, the price of

traditional rice is treated as an endogenous variable.       This is not a result

of the model but an input into the construction of the multi-market model.

The information that led to this decision was derived from outside the model

and may, therefore, be assumed to be available to the single-market analyst.

A siople linear regression of production of traditional rice on the price of
                                     - 20 -



HYV rice does, indeed, reveal an important association (see Appendix C).     ]J
Accordingly, in the augmented singlc-:nark~t approach presented belri;;, this

interaction is incorporated.

         The interactions that prove imprrtant for the positive analysis may

or may not prove important fo-r the normative analysis.   The presence of

substitution possibilities by themselves is not sufficient to cause serious

errors in the single-market approach.   Consider, for example, the combination

of strong substitution possibilities between HYV rice and traditional rice and

the price endogeneity of traditional rice.    The im~ortance of these

interactions for the normative analysis depends on the object of interest.        If

one is interested in household welfare, then these interactions are especially

important because they involve an induced change in the price of a commodity

that plays a significant role in the incomes of rural households and in the

expenditures of both rural and urban households.    Had the price change been

small (which it was not) or had the commodity whose price changed been of

little importance in consumption and production (which it was not), this

interaction would have proved unimportant for the normative analysis.       As far

as household welfare is concerned, therefore, the only relevant interactions

are those that lead to large induced price changes for major consumption or

production items.
          Now let us examine the consequences of· the same interaction for

measures of government revenue.    Since the induced price ch~nge occurs in a




lf  For a marginal change, the elasticity of traditional rice output with
respect to the price of HYV rice equals the elasticity of traditional rice
output with respect to its own price times the elasticity of the price of
traditional rice with respect to the price of HYV rice. This latter
elasticity (the general equilibrium effect) is one in the Korean case. This
is probably unusually large so that this effect may often be much less
important than it is here.
                                       - 2l -



market which is free of ~overnment inter,,ention - traditional rice is neither

taxed 11or subsidized - government r't!v,mue is 1Jn,.1ffected by :l1is i:tteraction.

If the primary concern, therefore, is with govern~ent revenue, this particu!ar

interaction could be ignored and one would focus one's attention on changes i~

production or consumption of items that are heavily subsidized or taxed.          In

the·Korean case, this implies that it is more important to worry about

interactions that affect fertilizer use (heavily subsidized) than those that

affect production and consumption of traditional rice.

          Finally, if the focus of attention is deadweight loss, then cne

should concentrate on changes in consumption and production that occur in

distorted markets.    Again, in the· particular case examined here, this would

suggest a focus on the use of (heavily subsidized) fertilizer.         Major price

changes occurring in non-distorted markets (traditional rice, for example) do

not affect deadweight loss.



An Augmented Single-Market Approach

          To demonstrate these points, we augment the single-market analysis of

Section IV to take into account those interactions which an analyst might
identify as important for positive and normative analysis:        the response of

fertilizer demand to change in a controlled output price, and the response of
traditional rice production and consumption to change in rural HYV price.
Table~ presents a compariso" between the multi-market and an augmented

single-market model's est:imates of the changes in production and consumption

expected to accompany change in controlled prices for those cases vher• the

single-market analysis was clearly deficient.       Note that the augmented single-

muket model effectively cloH~ the ~•ps betweei, the multi-riarl(et ~odel 's
estimates and those of the single market model presenttd 1~ S.ction tV.
                                      - 22 -


          The significance of thes..: changes for normative anal~1sis can be seen

in Table 7.   Taking into account the effect of change in out?UC price on input

demand brings the single market ·deficit estimates more into line with those of

the multi-market model's.    Note, however, that in failing to take into account

the effect of a change in fertilizer price on barley and HYV production, the

single-market model continues to underestimate the change in the deficit

resulting from increase in fertilier price.     (See Foot-no ... e 1, pa 15 e 15.)

Further, incorporating the effect of change in the rural HYV price on the

traditional rice market substantially improves the single marlcet .::i,del 's

estimates of rural and urban welfare change.     The remaining differences

between the model's estimates of welfare change are due to the fact that the

single-market model approximates welfare change by measuring the area beneath

Marshallian demand curves.    Hence the gain to rural consumers when HYV and
                  .                                        .
.barley prices are reduced continv.es to be ovet !Stimated by the single-mark.et

model.   Note, however, that the changes incorporated in the single-mark.et

analysis have an almost negligible effect on estimates of efficienrs ga~n.
                                         Tabliit 6
                     Predictions of Consumption and Production

                                                Percent Change in Price of:
                                         Rural HYV     Fertilizer     All P:ices         lf
Percent Effect on:   lJ                  -10      -30       l9..    -
                                                                    30
                                                                       -
                                                                       10
                                                                                     -30




Traditional                     MM1,I     '• .6      15.l      0    -0.1      5.6    1a.s
Rice Production                 SM3/        0           0      0      0       0        0

                                As?'JJ     S.4       16.l      0      0       S.4    16.1


Use of Fertilizer               !iM      -11.3    -31 .4     -9.9   -24.8   -22.s   -63.3

                                SM          0           0   -13.4   -40.0   -13.4   -40.1)

                                ASM       -9.6    -28.7      -1.s   -22.0   -23.1   -69.2

l,I   Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is
      rural HYV and barley prices are reduced and urban HYV, urban barley.and
      fertilizer release.prices are i~creased.

JJ    Base values for the analysis (in 1000 metric tons) are: HYV production -
      3577.l, traditional rice production - 2110.8; Fertilizer use in barley and
      rice production - 882.9;
1/ MM - multi-market analysis; SM - stngle-market.analysis; ASM - augmented
      single-market analysis.
                                          -;;~-

                                      Table 7
                      Predictions of Welfare Gains anti Losses

                                                Percent Chan~e in Price of:
                                         Rural HYV     Fertilizer     All Prices 1/

Percent Effect on: 2/

HYV Production                 M~ef
                                         -
                                         -10

                                        -42.4
                                                 -30

                                                 -92.6
                                                           10

                                                           -4.S
                                                                     30

                                                                    -11.8
                                                                                10         30

                                                                                        -184.7
                                                                              -80.7

                               sr:J./   -46.3 -·100.2      -1 .8     -3.5     -81.5     -190.6

                               ASMlf -45.9       -99.2 ·   -2.3      -5.8     -81.1     -187.7


Average Rural Welfare          MM        -2.7     -7.S     -o. 1     -0.3       -3.3      -8.8

                               SM        -().8    -1.S     -0.1      -0.2       -1 .2     -2.2

                               ASM       -1.7     -4.2     -o. 1     -0.3       -2.1      -s.o

Average Urban Welfare          MM         0.2      .0.5         0         0     -0.2      -0.3

                               SM            0         0        0         0     -0.2      -0.7

                               ASM         0.3      o.~         0         0      o.o       0.3


Efficiency Gain                 MM      1,356    2,965     144       381      2,591     5,834

(in 100 million won)            SM      1,685    3,242      58       112      2,650     6,163

                                ASM     1,621    3,203      73       183      2, 86?    6,065

l./    Prices are moved in the direction required to reduce the deficit. That is
       rural HYV and barley prices are reduced, and urban HYV, urban barley and
       fertilizer release prices are increased.
1:./   Base values for the analysis are: ·Government Budget Deficit: 3246
       hundred million won; Average Rural Real Disposable Income: 29900 won;
       Average urban Real Disposable 23900 Income.
1/     MM - multi-market analysis; SM - single-market analysis; ASH - augmented
       single-market analysis.
                                        - 25 -



rv.     CONCLUSION

            0ur conclusions can be su~marized easily:



       i)   Single market analysis that fails to allow for interactions usually

            encountered in the agricultural sector can yield misleading

            predictions for both positive variables (e.g. the change in

            traditional rice production following a change in the rural price of

            HYV rice) and for normative variables (e.g. the change in the deficit

            following a change in the price of fertilizer).



      ii)   Interactions that proved important in the Korean case are

            substitution possibilities in production, the price endogeneity of

            traditional rice, and the link between output price and fe.rtilizer

            demand.



  iii)      A straightforward extension of consumer surplus analysis to

            incorporate these interacttons yielded results reasonably close to

            those of the multi-market model for the variables of interest.



            This exercise suggests th,;.:: che anal;yst should be very wary of
results produced by a single-market/consumer surplus approach.        If, for

reasons of time and resources, the analyst is unable to prepare a multi-market

model, considerable effort should be devoted to exploring the likely

consequences of omitted interactions and, where these prove significant, to

extending the analysis along the lines suggested in this paper.        Finally, fro~

a research perspective, it would be extremely valuable to investigate whether

th~ interactions that proved unimportant in the Korean case can also be

expected to be insignificant in other situations,
                                      - 26 -


APPENDIX A Compensating Variation



The indirect utility function consistent with the AIDS model employed in t~e·

multi-market approach is:



                                                                        (1)




where income (Y) refers to full income and includes wage income, value of

leisure time, crop profits (rural sector only) and other income.    Profits ar2

expressed:



                                                                        (2)



for all crops (n), inputs (i), output prices (P) and input prices (W).        (PI)

refers to the AIDS price index, which is a function of the prices of crops and

leisure.
            From the indirect utility function (1), compensating variation, E, is

derived:



                                                                        (3)



This measure of welfare change is exact, but provides useful information only

when the AIDS cost function is concave and strictly quasi-concave in prices.

As this is not true of the Korea AIDS cost function in the price range in

which simulation takes place, an approximation to welfare loss must be

employed.     The approximation chosen here is change in real disposable income

deflated by the AIDS price index.
                                        - 27 -




                                                                         ( 4)




(DY) refers to nominal full income minus the value of leisure.

         ~ote that this approximation is equivalent to compensating variation

provided two assumptions hold.   First, it is assumed that demands are

hornothetic (i.e., Bn = o for all n).     In addition, it is assumed that the

value of leisure is not affected by change in controlled or endogenous prices.
                                                         - 28.-


APPENDIX B:       Consumer and Producer Surplus                    lJ


D~finirion of Compensating Variation



                                                                                                                  -1-



Differentiate l wrt all prices:



Example:   For i th price,



                                                                                                                  -2-



(If producer prices are not affected,                        dy0 /dp0 •     Q .•     If consUt11er prices are
                                                                        i
not affected,



By Roy's Identity,         C
                               i
                                   •




                                                                                      dE
                                                                                           0
                                                                                                                  -3-


                                                                    0
~sumption_,!_                                 dv/dy1 ,:, dv/dy


                                                     0
                                        -ci + dy /dp~ • dE/dp~                                                    -4-


              -l
Since   E •
              pl
              J
                      Po
                       2   ....        dE
                                                dP       +
                                                              pl pl
                                                               1J 2
                                                                            Po
                                                                             3     ....    dE
                                                                                                    dP            -s-
              Pl
                  0   po
                       2   ....        dP l          1        po po
                                                               l  2
                                                                            po
                                                                             3 ••••
                                                                                           dP
                                                                                                2
                                                                                                         2 ••••




lJ   See Glaister (1974) for a similar argument.
                                                               - 29 -


                                                                l
                                                + ••••        Pnd    dE
                                                                                 dP
                                                                     dP               n
                                                    •••• Pn               n



                                pl                                          dy
                                                    Po                                     Po      ) ~
                   E =      I
                            J
                                Po
                                         C   (P 1    2       ....   y)
                                                                          - dP
                                                                                 1
                                                                                      (Pl' - 2 •••• dp
                                     l
                                .,
                           p .,
                            1
                         - Pn°           C
                                                1
                                             (P 1 • • • •,    p
                                                               n'
                                                                    y)   - dy
                                                                           dPn
                                                                                        1
                                                                                      (p1       .... Pn>    dp   -6-


                                1                                                 l                1
           E ..,    -    6CS, (Pl' 00
                                   •l ,
                                                         0
                                                      p2····>       -    ecs 2 (P 2'        0
                                                                                          p 2' p 1'
                                                                                                        0
                                                                                                       ?3••··>


                                                                                                                 -7-


                                                                  + ty


Assumption 2

         Set   c~ 1     • o for all 1 where d? 1                          , some arbitrarily small constant




Assumption 3

         Assume independent price changes.



                                              E .. -     r6           . , Po.
                                                              csj ( P 1         o -1:j )
                                                                           . , Pk               + 6y             -8-
                                                                     .1    J



The change in money income                      (6y) is derived:



                                                                                                                 -9-
                                     - 30 -



where (i) denotes each output whose price undergoes change and (f) denotes

fertilizer.   ~oting that, from the profit function,                d 1Ti/dp~ = x        and
                                                                                    i'
differentiating (9) with respect to initial outp~t und input prices yie!ds:


                                     dni
                                  - --=    -   L    X    f i   = - ,cf                         -10-
                                     dP~       :r         '


Expressing (9) as



                                               ~                1
                                                              (Pl' P2,
                                                                      1   • ·p~ ) ~
                                                                               n dp            -11-
                                               dP
                                                    l1




and substituting from (10) yields:



                                                                                                -12-




Given that each x 1 denotes an output supply curve and xf denotes an input

demand curve, and again assumin~ independent price changes, we can express

 t:.y as:




Compensating variation can now be expressed:
                                       - 31 -



APPENDIX C:     Regression Results



          A   data set for single market analyses was generated by simulating the

results of the multi-marKet model for 37 different sets of controlled

prices.   For each simulation, a controlled price was changed by 5-30 percent

from its initial level.     For 6 of the simulations, all controlled prices were

varied by 5-30 percent.     OLS regressions were performed on this data set, and

the coefficients of these regressions were employed in the singl~ market

analysis of Section IV.     All coefficients were significant on 95 percent

confidence interval.



     Supply HYV           = -2088.27 + 14.99    * Rural Price HYV           (R 2 • 0.918)

     Supply Barley        = 1375.27 + 10.94 * Rural Price Barley           (R2 - 0.993)

     Demand Fertilizer .. 190.8.36 - 11.13     * Rural   Price Fertilizer (R 2 • o•. 524)




     Urban Demand HYV       = 2904.05 - 2.48    * Urban Price HYV
     Urban Demand Barley~ 213.15 - 0.4          * Urban Price Barley (R 2 • 0.360)




     Rural Demand HYV       • 1501.25 - 1.01    *   Rural Price HYV     (R 2 • 0.997)

     Rural Demand Barley• 501.27 - 0.62         * Rural Price Barley (R 2 • 0.360)


          In Section V, the single market model is augmented to take into

account the effect of rural HYV price on production and consumption of

traditional rice and ~he effect of rural HYV and barley prices on demand for

fertilizet.     The following regressions were run on the same set of tUUlti-
                                       - 32 -



market similation results, and the coefficients were employed in the au~mented

si~gle ~arket analysis of Section V.      All coefficients were sig~ificant on a

95 percent confidence interval.



     Supply Trad. Rice       = 3249.75     - 3.02    * Price Rural HYV (R 2 = 0.967)
     Rural Demand Trad. Rice= 953.99 - 0.62         * Price Rural HYV       (R 2 = 0.99;)

     Urban Trad. Rice        =    2033.56 - 2.16     * Price Rural HYV (R 2 = 0.946)


         Demand Fertilizer~ 172.61 - 6.68 * Rural Price Fertilizer

                                  + 2.2   *   Rural Price HYV + 1.95    *    Rural Price

                                                                 Barley (R 2 = 0.987)
                                        - 33 -



References



Braver;nan, Avishay, Jeffrey   s.   Hammer and Choorg Yong Ahn, "Government Deficit

     Reduction and Alternative Agricultural Pricing Policies in Korea", CPD

     Discussion Paper No. 1983-2 (revised), August, 1983.



Glaister, Stephen, "Generalized Consumer Surplus and Public Transport

     Pricing", Economic Journal, December, 1974, Vol. 84, No. 336, pp. 849-

     867.



Zabalza, A.~ "Cocpensating and Equivalent Variations, and the Deadweight Loss

     of Taxation", Economica, August, 1982, Vol. 49, No.____, pp. 355-359.