} ;'J \ . ~�q , ., SDF74 nl! "", ":"1'IIl'j! , '.~; ~'''' f''' ,'~'. ~ ""'1 f/?' 1"1 : : (:: r~ ; .." ~"i"'';' '! WW-l .11 VItt"" �� � "" DOMESTIC FINANCE STUDIES NO ltrf ::;. 4. ON STRUCTURAL CHANGE A.~D DEBT SERVICING CAPACITY By Homi Kharas rhe views presented in this paper are solely those of the author d" not necessarily reflect the official opinions of the World Bank Ilrt.:i or ita affiliates. August 1981 JOINT BANK-FUND LIBRARY . Public and Private Finance Division JLC014322 De~elopment Economics Department De',el ;)pmen t Policy Staf f 1 I. Introduction It seems to have become conventional wisdom to claim that LDC debt rescheduling problems are reflections of the failure of borrowers to invest the:.r loans in appropriate productive activities)! In a macroeconomic cont:ext, this is interpreted as the proposition that a low average propensity to :.nvest out of foreign capital inflows is cause for concern. The prevalence of t:his view appears rooted in two areas. First, it resembles the macroeconomic analogue to the intuitive micro hypothesis that profit max:.mizing firms will borrow as long as the marginal returns to investment exct!ed the marginal costs. If a firm failed to invest its borrowed funds, it wou:.d quic.kly go bankrupt. Second, it reflects the intertemporal coincidence of t:wo substantive recent developments in international capital movements: the rapid growth in volume of total outstanding debt and debt service obLgations (and the concomitant growth in concern about defaults) and the reduction in the earmarking of aggregate foreign loans for investment pro.iects, accompanied by a dramatic change in the composition of the source of funes towards commercial lenders. A primary aim of this paper is to evaluate the operational relevance of a.n approach which focuses on the use to which externally borrowed funds are put I first present in Section II a general long-run theory of crecitworthiness that suggests that present concerns over the degree to which 1/ "International financing must serve to increase productive investment in debtor countries and to improve their capacity to repay their external debt." Excerpt of speech by J. de Larosiere. ~naging Director of the IX:. delivered before the Economic and Social Council ,f the L~, Geneva, July 3, L981. 2 countries invest externally borrowed money are misplaced. Other structural parameters of the macroeconomy, particularly the marginal propensity to save and the average capital/output ratio are much more important. In Section III, I sllow that several stylized facts which have characterized recent historical defc.ult cases can be readily explained within this theoretical framework. Section IV then applies the theory to three countries, Brazil, Korea and Peru which were chosen because of their diverse international credit experiences. I f:,nd that defaults are associated with specific kinds of structural change in rhe economy and that such changes are normally leading indicators of defilUlt. These findings suggest that the methodology may be refined and devE!loped into a short-run predictive model of defaults with obvious policy imp:, ica t ions for both borrowers and lenders. II. A ~del of Creditworthiness Although defaults may be associated with short-run liquidity pro")lems, one may look for the cause of defaulting in the context of more long-run considerations related to the simultaneous accumulation of domestic cap~tal and external debt. This focus has as a central premise the notion tha: there exist a variety of sources, including IMF arrangements, reserve run�-downs, short-term supplier credits and longer-term commercial eurocredits, from which countries can readily obtain funds to tide over temporary liquidity pro':)lems, if their long-run position is fundamentally sound 11 Thus, for 1/ For example Heller [1966] shows that the probability of default may be independent of the variance of the current account if this variance is known and countries adjust optimal ~eserve holdings in. response. Bilson and Frenkel [1979] provide econometric evidence for a broad cross-section of LDCs showing that reserve holdings are indeed positively related to current account fluctuations. 3 countries with access to capital markets, the cause of both short-term cash- flow problems and defaults is rooted in the long-run growth-cum-debt process. The starting point of our long-run model is the general observation that central governments and semi-autonomous public agencies are the main borrcwers. Because of their public nature, investments by these agents are ofter. not accompanied by cost-recovery programmes. Rather, the returns to the inve~tments accrue to the private sector, while the government relies on incrEases in the tax base (national output) to fuel its revenue requirements for cebt servicing purposes. We assume that because of weaknesses in the inst;tutiona1 framework, the government is constrained from arbitrarily raisj.ng effective tax rates)! This wedge between the agents that benefit (the private sector) and the agents that bear the repayment obligations (the publ:.c sector) is the central externality that distinguishes this problem from the (;ne in which a traditional treatment of optimal foreign borrowing yields the J'u1e that the marginal rate of return to investment should be equated with the T~rgina1 cost of funds~ We emphasize the importance of an appropriate valuation of the marginal benefit of borrowing, in the face of constraints on government macro-management. We start by relating output to the domestic capital stock by a simp:.e fixed-coefficients function. 3/ :~ome such constraints must also be present whenever income distributional ',eights are applied in project evaluation as in, for example, Little and >tl.rrless [1974]. 4/ .>ee, for example, Bardhan [1967]. 4 Y = bK (1) Aggregate private consumption is based on net-of-tax private income. As the pr:~vate sector obtains the returns from all domestic capital, ( 2) Tht~ government obtains revenue from taxes and from borrowing externally, F. It first services its outstanding external debt, D, paying interest at a rate r, and amortization at a rate, 0, and then allocates a fixed proportion of re'llaining resources to investments. (3) As the private sector is not a borrower 2i, total investment in the country is thtc. sum of government investment and local private savings. I = IG + Sp = aK + a2 (F - (r+e)D) - Co (4) b[(I-c) (l-t) + a2t] Tht' change in outstanding debt over time is given as an accounting identity by gross new borrowings less repayment of principal. D = F - eD (5) 2/ The essence of the analysis remains unchanged if we allow private foreign borrowing. 5 If the capital stock depreciates at a constant rate, 6, the full growth-cum debt development may be written as a function of the level of capital inflows and the initial values of domestic capital and outstanding debt. (6 ) whel'e - 6. Let the government choose foreign capital inflows in each time per:.od to maximize some national income or consumption objective, subject to the constraint that long-run creditworthiness be maintained, in the sense that tax revenues are always expanding fast enough to cover interest on debt. This ens11res that ever increasing new borrowings would not be required for debt ser.rice payments. We show below that this constraint implies that borrowing onlf takes place when a1 > r. The intuition is that a 1 reflects the marginal fut .ire expansion in the tax base (and tax revenues) when one unit of domestic capLtal is added to the economy, while r is simply the marginal future cost of debt. The optimal level of foreign borrowing at any time is determined by setting the marginal benefit equal to the marginal cost. It can be shown that in ,1 linear system as described above, these will be independent of the actual lev~l of the state variables K and Dj} In a long-run framework, the terms on which debt is contracted reflect the viability of the whole joint accunulaticn ~ The complete solution to the optimalcontrol problem is treated in more depth in Kharas [1980J 6 patt of domestic capital and external debt. As this path is known (from (5) and (6� once the borrowing profile is specified, there is no new information contained in observations of the state variables as time progresses. Thus, the shape of the supply curve facing the country remains constant; its pos:.tion, howeve, is clearly subject to a scale factor. As world capital marLets expand, supplier portfolio considerations imply a larger level of bon'owing is available at any given interest rate, and so the amount of bor,:owings that maintains marginal benefit equal to marginal cost expands at thi:> exogenous rate, f. F = Fo eft o <f <r (7) The growth rate of new borrowings is constrained to be less than the interest rat,~ to guarantee that the country does become a net supplier of real res)urces to the rest of the world at some future time, a condition which see�rlS necessary for the existence of a rational market solution}J The solution to the system (5) - (7) is described by: - a, where the X's are the eigenvalues and the V's the associated eigenvectors. As the two roots are real and of opposite sign, the system must be characterized by a saddle point. Figure 1 below illustrates characteristic paths for capital and debt accumulation. The scale along the axes ~ill be expa.nding at a rate f over time. 2! This problem was first noted by Domar [1950]. To ensure a finite optimal level of borrowing,it is clearly necessary to stipulate that real resources do not come into the country at all times. K -_... \�1 2. Figure 1 We define a creditworthy country, in this model, as one with the ploperty of being on a path that leads to an ever-expanding capital stock. In trms of Figure 1, if the initial position is above the eigenvector V2 , then it will never be necessary continuously to run-down (or sell off) domestic cl:.pital to meet debt-service obligations. The product from domestic capital wi.ll be more than sufficient to cover desired consumption expenditure, capital r:placement and interest on debt. Because the country remains creditworthy in tbis sense, there should be no danger of external resources drying up. Debt w:.ll be constantly rolled over. Both the contribution of foreign capital and domestic output are, therefore, important in analyzing creditworthiness. It is clear that the structure of the time paths along which ~Imestic capital and external debt progress will depend on the initial values 0:' these two variables relative to the contours shaped by the technical and ~!havioral parameters governing the position and slope of the eigenvectors of the phase diagram. This joint variable/parameter relationship underlying 8 creditworthiness has often been overlooked, with emphasis almost exclusively directed at the variables. The most common position is that if the values of the variables appear inconsistent with a successful outcome, then debt fin~nc1ng should be delayed. Failure to look at the parameters has made ru1es-of-thumb for analyzing debt-servicing capacity in terms of indicators hard to implement across different countries �� From the eigenvector V2 in Figure 1, we get the trade-off between the initial values of domestic capital and outstanding debt that leaves the cocntry in a creditworthy situation. That is, if a country is on the margin of creditworthiness (on V2 ) and then accumulates an extra unit of debt by borrowing from abroad, then the domestic capital stock must increase by at 1e~st a2(r+e)/(a 1+e) if the country is to remain on or above V2 � But we know from (6) that the actual increase in domestic capital due to one unit of fo::eign borrowing is a2' Hence the constraint that a country can only borrow if it maintains its creditworthiness is equivalent to the condition a 2 ) a 2 (r+e)/(a 1+e) which simplifies to a 1 ) r. By mathematical induction, we can then claim that this is a general criterion for successful borrowing. Several important implications may be derived directly from this bocrowing rule. First, there are a variety of factors embodied in the parameter a 1 that influence creditworthiness. The proportion of foreign borrowing that goes to investment is only relevant insofar as it is correlated with the propensity to invest out of tax revenues. The efficiency of investment (summarized in the capital-output ratio) is a key variable; but perhaps more interesting is the presence of behavioural savings and tax param~ters. Even if the marginal social return on investment is greater than tre cost of externally borrowed funds, a government which invests in social irfrastructure projects may run into debt-servicing problems unless the 9 aggregate marginal propensity to save is sufficiently high. This raises the possibility of moral hazard problems whereby the act of borrowing induces behc.vioural changes which reduce credl tworthiness � For example, i f public invt!stments via subsidized state enterprises reduce opportunities for private secl:or involvement, then unless perfect local capital markets exist, private sav~ngs would fall J! Alternatively, access to foreign financing may reduce the government's determination to collect tax revenues, again resulting in a fall in aggregate domestic savings. These are cases where poor macro manlgement creates problems by permitting a 1 to fall as borrowing takes pla~e. A second implication, however, is that if al falls ~elow I' because of some structural change in the behavioural and technological coefficients inc:)rporated in aI' then debt servicing problems can arise even i f the initial borrowing programme was well conceived. This merely reflects the common result that there are risks attached to the fact that borrowing is associated wit':'} a variable stream of benefits while servicing obligations are fixed. The suggestion is that debt service problems may be associated with changes in ai' Figure 2 illustrates this. A country has been borrowing and reaches the pojnt A, with the expectation of maintaining its creditworthiness as growth takes place. A sudden shock, (perhaps a terms of trade deterioration which could lower savings rates), reduces a1 to a level a 1 < r < a 1� Now the ex:.sting position is on an unstable path and i t is likely that both borrowers an,i lenders will seek to reduce rapidly new capital inflows, resulting in liquidity shortages and default. ~ The relationship between private savings and investment opportunities in the presence of imperfect capital markets is derived in detail in Virmani [1981] � 10 K '\ \ \ \1 V Figure 2 III. Stylized Facts of Defaults The relevance of the model to the real world can be ascertained by its ability to explain certain stylized features associated with defaults and the subsequent renegotiation procedure. There have, to date, been few attempts at reconciling generalizations observed in historical case-studies with a theoretical model. We examine briefly below the way in which the model framework accounts for three stylized facts: the preference on the part of lenders to reschedule debt on easier terms rather than writing-off existing loans; the lack of general support by LDCs for generalized debt relief and finally, the attempts made by creditors to ensure that aid is channelled towards basic 'development' needs rather than simply credited against debt ser'lice obligations.J.! ~ This does not imply that economic iactors are the only motivating factors, but that the underlying economic interests may reinforce political opinions. 11 During a rescheduling, creditors will typically agree to accept an alternative stream of debt service payments with a present value substantially bele,w that of the original obligations due J!l/ We may, therefore, characterize the refinancing operations involved in defaults as being equ:,valent to a simple unrequited transfer in perpetuity from the creditors to the borrower. The amount of assistance, A, will depend on the country's abLity to pay W As defined in our model and illustrated in Figure 2, the purpose of the transfer would be to lower the eigenvector V;, !;uch that given the actual level of domestic capital stock and outstanding deb': the country's creditworthiness would be restored. Let the negotiation pro,~ess * result in a transfer of A. By calculating the full expression for v; it is easily seen that such a transfer to the government will result in a The present value of the loss to the , crelitors is simply A* /r. We now ask what quantity of debt, DR' would need to be yritten-off by the creditors to yield the same gain in creditworthiness as * tha: provided by A. The write-off of outstanding debt is simply a leftwards shirt of the initial point, by an amount inversely proportional to the slope of il 2� DR is readily computed as A*(ai+9)/ai(r+6), and represents directly the cost of the rescheduling exercise to the creditors. Comparing the maglitude of losses suffered by the creditors under the two alternative refinancing operations, the creditors would suffer a higher loss by rescinding existing debt when ai < r. But this is precisely the condition which resulted 10/ Extended grace periods and lower interest are used to effect the transfer. Of course, if only amortization is rescheduled at market interest rates, then there is no assistance. But then we ask why a rescheduling was necessary, rather than the country simply borrowing on inter~ational markets. See for example, IMF [1981). ll! ~e prinCiple of ability to pay in debt renegotiations is documented in Cizauskas [1979). 12 in a default in the first place. Hence, we may claim that when a country de::aults, creditors who desire to restore the country to a creditworthy po:;ition at minimum cost to themselves would choose a refinancing operation ra:her than writing-off a portion of their loans. The symmetrical argument also indicates why LDCs have been unable to ge1erate cohesive support in their bargaining for generalized debt relief in th~ context of the North-South dialogueJl! For creditworthy countries, a 1 is gr=ater than r, so they get more benefit from additional transfers than from across-the-board reductions in debt where these yield the same improvement in creditworthiness. Consequently, the focus of their efforts is in enlarging the net transfer of additional resources. Bitterman [1973] summarizes his analysis of debt refunding methods by noting that aid has rarely been specifically directed towards providing resources for debt service payments, being used instead to encourage desirable development activities. We may paraphrase this in terms of the model to say ttat donors attempt to influence domestic actions to raise a 1 to provide ttemselves with an additional cushion against defaults. Similarly, rEnegotiations are often linked to stabilization programmes designed to irtprove public savings. Recipient countries, on the other hand, who are originally presumably choosing al to maximize some intertemporal objectives, r!!sist being forced to raise a l , and correctly note that the tying of aid in this manner reduces the net benefit to the country. There is a difference b!~tween the borrower's intertemporal trade-off and the lenders' desire to ~lximize creditworthiness. We may conclude this section by noting that the c~editworthiness constraints yields economic arguments in support of the lU See Roths tein [1979]. 13 vartous positions defended by aid donors and recipients in historical refunding exercises. IV. Empirical application The hypothesis that structural change in the economy, resulting in a lowering in a1' is the major instigating factor behind defaults can be emFirically investigated. Because a1 includes both behavioural and technical parameters, it will reflect changes in the economic and sociopolitical en"ironments. It has often been argued that in the last analysis it is the lack of political confidence of foreign investors that triggers a default at SOlle precise moment in time. One may imagine these foreign investors, es)ecially the international commercial banks, deriving their information from lo::al clients or branches of international clients. In these circumstances, a de:~line in foreign confidence in the economy will always lag behind a decline of local investor confidence. This latter would be reflected in a fall-off of private savings and investment. The structural change considered is thus a ctange i~ private intertemporal decisions. We investigate below the association of changes in aggregate savings rates with default, for three c(,untt'ies, Brazil, Korea and Peru which have had substantially different e::periences in the international credit markets over the last 20 years. T~ for Structural Change The theory tells us both that downward changes in a1 will precede d;~fault observations and that changes in a2 are likely to be irrelevant. We d;) not wish, therefore, to restrict the test to the hypothesis that a sudden change in a 1 at an ex ante determined time is significant in default events. Father, we shall sacrifice the strength of a high-powered significance test of 14 an :.mposed formulation of the change in a 1 ll, and instead permit the data to bring out any evidence of structural change by graphical methods. The pro,~edure used was introduced by Brown, Durbin and Evans (1975]. A basic regression model is conditional on normal uncorrelated err:>rs. If the specification of parameters as being constant over time is inc)rrect, then we would expect this to show up in the behavior of the residuals. It has been found that plotting the ordinary least-squares residuals (or their squares) against time does not yield sensitive indications of gradual changes in the parameters. In certain situations, the cumulative sun or sum of squares is better; this latter, however, is not very amenable to statistical tests of departure from the expected value. An alternative ap~roach is to derive a new series of recursive residuals, W , defined as the t difference between an observation of the dependent variable Yt and the least sq\,ares predictor of the observation, yt' based on a regress ion of y on the incependent variables, X, over the period t = 1, ��� ,t-I. The recursive ref:iduals are, therefore, based on changes in the estimates of the regression pal:ameter vector, resulting from the consecutive addition of observations to 2 thl; sample. .. It can be shown that the W. are N(O, cr) under the null hypothesis that no structural change occurs. We expect that when a change d04~s occur, then this will show up relatively quickly in the behavior of the re�~ursive residuals. Under the null hypothesis, the cumulative sum of the squared re:ursive residuals, normalized by the cusum-squared statistic for the whole salple, has a beta distribution with an expected value of zero at t :: k and 1 at t =T where k is the number of parameters to be estimated and T is the full 14 sanple size. , We may draw a confidence band around the expected value line, 131 Such as an exact Chow-test. 14/ cf. Brown, Derbin and ~vans [1975] 15 such that if the CU8um-squares series crosses outside the band, we may reject the ~ull hypothesis at any required level of significance. The procedure may be r~peated with residuals obtained by running the regression backwards over time as well as forwards. This yields added information on changes which may have occurred close to the starting point. Brown etal. "prefer to regard the lines constructed in this way as yardsticks against which to assess the observed sample path rather than pro�dding formal tests of significance." An independent test, which can further help locate departures from the null hypothesis is the Quandt log- likelihood ratio test. This models an alternative hypothesis that the pare,meters are constant until a given point in time when they switch to a different, but still constant, value. If the alternative hypothesis is true, then the log-likelihood ratio (LLR) will have a pronounced minimum at the time of ':he switch. Although no formal test can be constructed for the min LLR, as its distribution under the null hypothesis is not known, the plot of the LLR indi.cates whether a sharp transition (marked, jagged minimum) or a gradual cha'lge in the coefficients has taken place. Res llts The backwards and forwards cusum-squares and the Quandt log- likelihood ratio tests were applied to the simple investment equation (6) for Brazil, Korea and Peru over the period 1957-78. All the variables were deflated by a price index. GDP was used as a proxy for the domestic capital stc,::k. Although export taxes are a primary source of government revenue for Peru, because exports are highly collinear with GDP, the GDP variable was retained to facilitate comparison with the other results. Use of GDP implies an emphasis on changes in savings rates as the main source of variation of the paramet:er al. 16 Figure 3 shows the Brazilian cusum-squared tests. A 90% confidence inter'lal is drawn, such that the null hypothesis that no structural change has taken place is only rejected outside this interval. Clearly for any predictive model of defaults the confidence interval would be adjusted depending on the loss functions associated with Type 1 and Type 2 errors. If failcre to predict defaults is more costly then wrongly predicting defaults, then the confidence interval would be much narrower (perhaps only 20% or so) than drawn here. For the present, as we are trying to establish the relationship between structural change and defaults, the more stringent interval is considered. Both backwards and forwards cusum-squared plots show some evidence of structural change around 1963/65, althoug~ this is not sufficiently marked to rl!ject the null hypothesis. In addition, the backwards plot indicates chan:~e in the 1966-68 period. Inspection of the numerical progression of the coef:'icients as the length of the estimation period is increased (Table 1) sugg~sts that the first change is associated with a rapid decline in a 1 which ~ott)med out in 1965 and then reversed itself into a sustained rise, which was contLnued through the mid-1970's. By contrast, the movement in the a2 coefF.icient seems much less important, as well as being quite random over the sample period. In fact, the confidence level at which a2 is significantly diffl!rent from zero is quite low until the sample size reaches the full 22 observations. Additional evidence that the pre-1965 investment regime was significantly different from the post-1965 regime is provided by the Quandt log-likelihood ratio plot which displays a deep minimum in 1965. To gain more infermation on which coefficients were changing, the sample was partitioned inte two at 1965 and separate regressions run for the two parts. The serial 17 F'i gure 3 Forwards and Backwards Cusum-Squared Plots (1957-78) - Brazil � � " " 1960 "" \ ~i~nificance line . 965 "" " 1970 " " \ " " " " " 1975 .... ' "" " \ ... " " " "" 1980 " 0.00 1.00 / / / / / I 1960 / / 'O~ Sb:nificance line / / / I / 1965 / / / / / / I 1970 / / / / � / / I / / / 1975 / / / / / / / / - 18 Table 1 Changes in Coefficients Over Sample Period - Brazil for regression!' - ,. K p t + cons. GDP al p t a2 Net cap. inflows + e p CONSTANT t-Stat. a t-Stat. a2 , t-Stat. l 1957 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1958 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1959 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1960 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1961 -0.218 - 0.682 0.237 1. 955 1.626 0.578 1962 -0.132 -0.635 0.210 2.410 0.800 0.472 1963 0.041 0.449 0.134 4.399 1.927 1.649 1964 0.035 0.422 0.140 5.442 1. 433 2.174 1965 0.119 0.849 0.126 2.855 -0.406 -0.566 1966 0.046 0.225 0.153 3.063 -0.410 -0.478 1967 -0.047 - 0.313 0.185 4.106 -0.054 -0.064 1968 -0.195 -1.598 0.232 6.656 0.623 0.815 1969 -0.274 - 2 . 503 0.257 8.587 0.794 1.021 B7C -0.307 - 3. 327 0.268 11 .059 0.940 1.307 1971 -0.300 -3.943 0.266 13.727 0.876 1.603 1972 -0.290 -4.325 0.263 15.750 0.806 1.650 1973 -0.271 -4.740 0.258 18.599 0.772 1.632 1974 -0.281 - 4. 861 0.262 19.237 0.230 1.111 1975 -0.294 -5.252 0.266 20.137 0.268 1 .321 1976 - 0.270 -5.379 . ~.O.259 22.671 0.316 1.606 1'377 -0.223 -5.074 0.246 27.389 0.493 2.813 197E -0.202 . -4.999 . 0.241 31. 06~ 0.555 3.306 2.' All variables drawn from International Financial Statistics of the IMF. Figure 4 Quandt Log-likelihood Ratio - Brazil 1960 1965 197C 197: -.--------______~~~--------------------~~~------------- -20.00 -10.00 - 19 correlation, which is evident for the run using the whole sample and which suggests that the constant coefficients model is misspecified, disappears. To guard against the possibility that one or two bad data points, in the chaotic years 1963-65 were dominating the regression results, a run was tried omitting th '!se years; serial correlation remains. The evidence is very strong that po~t-1965 Brazilian investment reflected a structural change in the economy, with marginal savings rates sharply higher than before. Table 2 Marginal Propensities to Invest Over Time - Brazil 1957-78 Period 1957-78 (omit.63-65) 1957-64 1966-78 Constant -202.72 -170.85 35.83 -78.69 (-4.999) (-5.481) (0.422) (-1.55) GDP .2414 .2400 .1410 .2287 (31.06) (41.62) (5.44 ) (30.32) Cap. inflows .5549 .4896 1.433 .5476 (3.306 ) (3.80) (2.17) (4.235) -2 R .990 .9948 .8007 .9933 D.to] � 1.1577 1.3710 1.756 2.076 The credit history of Brazil reveals a succession of debt consolidation and rescheduling exercises in 1953, 1955, 1958, 1961 and 1963-5 followed by a total absence of such problems up to the present. This is clearly consistent with our theoretical framework suggesting that - 20 creditworthiness is inherently tied to the magnitude of the parameter a 1 � The extremely low value pre-1965 is associated with the periodic reschedulings, but after measures were effected which substantially raised the marginal propensity to invest out of domestic output the country was able to emerge ::rom this debt problem regime into one characterized by long-run t:reditworthiness. The results are made more interesting by the coincidental =all of the propensity to invest out of new capital inflows in the later, ~reditworthy period. Korea provides an example of a country which has managed to avoid debt servicing problems in the recent past, despite having to adjust to major changes in the level and terms of capital inflows. For example, in the years 1955-62 the level of grant aid provided at least one-half of the total resources available for capital accumulation, and in some instances much more. After 1962, this gradually tapered off. The decline in the relative importance of grants and concessional loans is even more clearly seen in the proportion of imports covered by these inflows. On average, between 1953-62 this was 69%; in 1963-64, 41%; in 1965-69, 23% and in 1970-74, 11%~ In conjunction with the authorities' desire to raise total capital inflows to finance more rapid growth, the fall in concessional flows implied a rise in the effective cost of foreign borrowing. This did not, however, lead to debt servicing problems because the government of Korea introduced a new domestic interest rate regime that stimulated private savings, and took measures to raise public savings dramatically from 0.5% of GDP in 1964 to 2.8% in 1966. Hence, the major financial reform of 1965 was in a direction which improved creditworthiness sufficiently to outweigh the problems which may otherwise have resulted from the rise in average foreign interest payments. The 12! See E. Mason etal. [1980], p. 190. - 21 irrmediate impact of these measures was to encourage firms to borrow from atroad and to create an environment in which the risks of default were low and lenders would be prepared to lend. The theory predicts that the increase in savings rates was probably a major factor in reducing risk and in opening up a.:ceS9 of individual firms to international capital markets. The rapid inflow into Korea of private, foreign capital post-1965 created problems of control over the monetary aggregates and a rise in itlflation. The balance of payments, however, was kept in surplus by the capital inflows. After attempts to limit monetary growth by restricting commercial bank lending proved ineffective, the government elected to impose tighter capital controls and banned certain types of loans, including those Idth medium-term (3 year) pay-back periods. To maintain the investment rlomentum, the authorities provided preferential credits for specified items ,md sectors. Both the structural changes in the economy mentioned above are clearly seen in the forwards and backwards cusum-squared plots and in minima i.n the Quandt log-likelihood ratio. Inspection of the change in the estimated ~oefficients of the investment function over time (Table 2) shows the dramatic rise in savings out of domestic output from 0.091 for the 1957-64 period to ~.171 for 1957-66. Of course, the marginal increment in savings rates was even greater than the increase in the period averages quoted above. The second shift of parameters, after 1971, is again associated with a rise in the savings rate, but accompanied by a fall in the propensity to invest out of foreign capital inflows. This latter reflects the growing difficulty facing private firms in obtaining foreign credits and the economic incentives they faced to switch towards preferential domestic loans as a source of credit. As expected, this decline has not led to significant debt problems for Korea; the rise in savings rates more than offsets this. 22 Figure 5 Forwards and Backwards Cusum-Squared Plots - Korea . � '\. '\. '\. '\. '\. '\. 1960 " '\. '\. '\. 1O~~ Silitnificance line " '\. '\. 1965 " '\. "" '\. 1970 " '\. '\. " 1975 ' .... -. "" , '\. , 0.00 1.00 / / / / / / i9O / / 10,';, Significance line / / / / / 1965 / / / / / 1970 / / / / / / / 1975 / / / / / / - 23 Table 3 . Changes in Coefficients OVer Sample Period - Korea a/ K for regression- p - cons.- t + a1 GDP.j. a2 Net cap. inflows + -p- p e CONSTANT t-Stat. a 1 t-Stat. a 2 t-Stat. 1957 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1958 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1959 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1960 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1S61 -0.972 -1. 962 0.160 4.657 0.086 0.365 1962 -l. 426 - 3.541 0.168 4.450 0.294 1.474 1963 -1. 055 - 3.602 0.142 4.220 0.343 1.641 1964 -0.656 - 3.571 0.091 6.273 0.632 4.968 1965 -1. 049 -2.265 0.148 4.866 0.280 0.922 1966 -2.265 -2.869 a. 171 2.801 0.725 1.231 1967 -2.804 -4.137 0.171 2.707 1.020 1.835 1968 -2.971 -4.813 O. 155 2.701 1.265 3.004 1969 - 3.171 -5.689 0.160 2.841 1.312 3.199 1970 -3.476 --7.848 0.191 4.333 1 . 127 3.187 1971 - 3. 08::1 - 6. 712 0.164 3.406 1.232 3.085 1972 -3.312 - 8.300 0.209 10.936 0.871 4.717 1373 - 3. 533 -7.467 0.253 19.204 0.511 3.249 1974 -3.155 -7.675 0.252 18.481 �0.380 2.831 1975 - 3. 184 - 8.532 0.253 20.003 0.382 2.937 1976 -3.200 - 8.893 0.256 33.720 0.354 3.883 1977 - 3. 246 - 7 . 684 '. 0'.271 42.804 0.202 2.346 ~/ All variables drawn from International Financial Statistics .,E the IMF. Figure 6 Quandt Log-likelihood Ratio Plot - Korea 1960 1965 1970 1975 �30.00 -20.00 -10.00 - 24 Peru has experienced continued reschedu1ings over the past twenty years. the most recent being in 1979/80. Despite the fact that the country has large collateral in the form of oil and other mineral reserves which would ~eem to augur well for long-term prospects, and which provides the base for Peruvian participation in euromarkets on a large scale, creditors have periodically lost confidence in the economic development path, forcing the authorities to undertake stabilization measures and renegotiate debt service obligations. 1963 was a year of formal reschedu1ings as was 1968. Default was marginally averted in 1975 and in 1976 the government announced a new series of stabilization measures which were to be monitored by a steering committee of private banks. The breakdown of the programme culminated in a broad restructuring of debt in December 1978. The forwards cusum-squared plot of the investment function shows signs of structural change in 1963 to 1968 and this is further brought out in the backwards run. The Quandt log-likelihood ratio shows minima in 1963, 1967 and a steep decline into a trough in 1974. The first two declines in the LLR correspond to crisis times which were precipitated by a fall in the marginal propensity to invest out of domestic output. It is interesting to note that although earlier rescheduling exercises included attempts to raise domestic savings, these measures were ineffective. For example. in 1968 the government tried to curtail expenditures, raise taxes and restrict credit, but as we can see in Table 4, the marginal propensity to invest out of domestic output was not raised. Similarly, the stabilization program of 1976/77 failed to improve the situation. It is of particular interest that in the Peruvian case the aftermath of the formal defaults was ~ return to the old situation, in strict contrast to the 1965 Brazilian experience. Examination of the changes in coefficients - 25 s~own in Table 4 shows that although the propensity to invest out of net capital inflows was increased from 0.286 for the period 1957-67 to 0.539 for period 1957-77, the propensity to invest out of domestic output remained Essentially unaltered at 0.076 and 0.075 for these sample periods lespectively. Hence, there is no indication that the renegotiations of debt over this period were sufficiently broad to restore long-run creditworthiness, nor was Peru able to initiate programs under which future borrowing would help ~elieve the situation. Indeed, between 1970-75, the ratio of gross domestic Lnvestment in GDP rose from 13% to 19%, mostly attributable to substantial foreign capital inflows and steady rises in the propensity to invest out of these inflows, but due to the low magnitude of the savings rate, this process did not improve stability. 26 - Fi gure 7 Forwards and Backwards Cusum-SQuared Plots {1957-77} - Peru I ", " , " " " , 1960 I " 10~ Significance lines " ! , " " , I "", " , 1965 " ", I , ,, 1970 ! " , " " ", . " 1975 ....." " "- ", I " "" I 0.000 " 1.000 / / / 1960, / .' 1O~ Significance lines / / / / / 1965 / / / / / / 1970 / / / / / / / / / / 1975 / / 1 / I / / / - 27 Table 4 Change in Coefficients Over Sample Period* - Peru . K GD~ for Regression!! p � const. + a 1 p a2 Net cap. inflows + p e CONSTAnT t-Stat. a l t-Stat. a2 t-Stat. 1957 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1958 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1959 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1960 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1961 -0.494 -1. 570 0.387 3.010 1. 291 3.631 1962 -0.481 -3.211 0.381 6.467 1.279 5.665 1963 0.014 0.073 0.184 2.546 0.586 1.825 1964 0.079 0.491 0.156 2.610 0.619 2.031 1965 0.185 1.504 0.115 ' 2.598 0.471 1. 752 1966 0.219 2.431 0.102 3.277 0.424 1.832 1967 0.290 3.726 0.076 2.904 0.286 1.300 1968 0.316 4.077 0.064 2.547 0.376 1.753 1969 0.325 4.423 0.060 2.567 0.426 2.229 1970 0.319 4.578 0.063 2.865 0.392 2.312 1971 0.332 5.445 0.058 3.133 0.378 2.354 1972 0.328 6.120 0.060 3.741 0.383 2.520 1973 0.323 7.438 0.061 4.960 0.393 2.911 1974 0.301 8.644 0.068 7.168 0.479 5.277 1975 0.296 9.092 0.069 7.835 0.509 8.226 1976 0.282 8.384 0.074 8.172 0.540 8.523 1977 0.283 8.897 0.075 8.690 0.539 8.789 !of All variables drawn from International Financial Statistics of the IMP. * No accurate data available for 1978. Figure 8 quandt Log-likelihood Ratio Plot -'Peru 1965 1970 1975 -15.0�J -10.00 - 28 There are three generalizations that emerge from the case studies. First, the renegotiations are associated with a fall in the marginal propensity to invest out of domestic output. By using sensitive techniques for detecting structural change, useful information on the likelihood of a default in the near future can be generated. Second, a successful renegotiation, in the sense that a country emerges into a long-run creditworthy regime, involves a substantial rise in the level of the savings rate. Refinancing exercises that fail to generate more domestically-financed investment are typically followed by further reschedulings. Similarly, if increasing recourse to more expensive commercial loans is taken, maintenance of creditworthiness necessitates an improved savings performance. The Brazilian and Korean cases are examples of how countries with poor historical records could have been predicted as having a low risk of future defaults on debt servicing payments once they managed to alter the fundamental conditions affecting creditworthiness. The Peruvian example, on the other hand, illustrates the ability to predict continued debt-servicing problems even after renegotiations had alleviated the most immediate pressures. Third, the degree to which foreign capital inflows are invested and changes in this coefficient are not especially important. We show examples where differences between countries are inversely correlated with creditworthiness (Korea vs. Peru), and where the movement of one country from an uncreditworthy to a creditworthy environment is associated with a fall in the propensity to invest out of external funds-(Brazil). A corollary of this is that attempts by an inherently uncreditworthy country to emerge into a viable growth system by borrowing heavily from abroad and investing the funds domestically, will Simply exacerbate the future debt service problems unless savings rates are bOosted. - 29 Conclusion We have developed a theoretical framework in which a country may renE~ge on its debt-servicing obligations when payment of these in full would sevE:rely cripple consumption and investment plans. The essence of the problem is t:.hat the main borrower of external credits, the public sector, often allows the returns on its investments to accrue directly to the private sector. As genl~ral government collection of real resources to repay foreign debt depends on~he overall growth of the economy, public and private savings playa dom~nant role in the appropriate valuation of the marginal benefit of bor:-owing and hence in determining creditworthiness. This framework was used to ~xplain the economic underpinnings of the positions advanced by various agelts (lenders, creditworthy and uncreditworthy borrowers) in the context of the North-South dialogue. We suggest that the two considerations of crelitworthiness and of resource transfers from North to South, would yield the observed pattern of concerns. This is taken as justification of the relevance of the theory to the real world. The implication that creditworthiness depends on the marginal propensity to invest out of domestic capital relative to the real cost of external funds yields empirically testable hypotheses of a positive nature (th,:it defaults are accompanied by a fall in savings rates) and a negative nat'.lre (that the level of and changes in the propensity to invest out of foreign capital inflows is unimportant). The results from three case studies sUFPort these proportions both across countries and for one country over tin.e. A technique for identifying structural change in the investment eqtation by the use of recursive residuals is shown to be useful in predicting WhEther a default is likely in the short-term future. The cusum-squared - 30 analysis used grows out of a more general methodology designed to detect changes in variable means in industrial quality control. It is much more sensitive than an analysis based on actual residuals and is, therefore, part.icularly suited to the problem of predicting potential debt crisis sit\,ations for individual countries. REFERENCES Bardhan, P.K. 1967 "Optimum foreign borrowing," in K. Shell (ed.), Essays on the Theory of Optimal Economic Growth M.I.T., Cambridge, Mass. BilsOl, J.F. and J.A. Frenkel, 1979. "Dynamic Adjustment and the Demand for International Reserves," National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 407, Cambridge, MA. Bitterman, H.J., 1973. The Refunding of International Debt, Durham, N.C. Duke University. Brown, R.L., J. Durbin and J.M. Evans, 1975. "Techniques for Testing The Constancy of Regression Relationships Over Time," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, B, 37, No.2. Cizauskas, A.C., 1979. "International Debt Renegotiation: Lessons From the Past," World Development, February. Doma I, E. S " 1950. "Foreign loves tment and the Balance of Payments," American Economic Review, December. HellEr, H.R., 1966, "Optimal International Reserves," Economic Journal June. Inter'national Monetary Fund .1981. "External Indebtedness of developing count.ries", Occasional Paper. Kharcls, H.J., 1980. "Optimal Foreign Borrowing by Less Developed Countries Theory and Practice," unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass. LitLe, ~.D. and J.A. Mirrless, 1974. Project Appraisal and Planning for Developing Countries, Heinemann, London. MaSO"l, E. etal. 1980. The Economic and Social Modernization of the Republic of Korea, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass. MathLeson, D.J., 1979. "Financial Reform and Capital Flows in a Developing Economy," IMF Staff Papers, September. Puz, R., 1977. "How to Find Out When a Sovereign Borrower Slips From A-I to C-3," Euromoney, December. Rothstein, R.L. 1979. Global Bargaining. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J. Sargen, N., 1977. "Use of Economic Indicators and Country Risk Appraisal," Economic Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Fall. Solcmon, R.A., 1977. "A Perspective on the Debt of Developing Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2. van Agtmael, A., 1976, "Evaluating the Risks of Lending to Developing Countries," Euromoney, April. Virmrlni, A., 1981. "The Nature of Credit Markets in Less Developed Countries: A Framework for Policy.Analysis; Domestic Finance Study No. 71, World Bank, Washington, D.C.