. o1,0 INDUSTRY AND ENERGY DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER INDUSTRY SERIES PAPER No. 57 Building a Competitive Edge in Sub-Saharan African Countries The Catalytic Role of Foreign and Domestic Enterprise Collaboration in Export Activities April 1992 Teodaknsyn eyeamta The~~ ~ ~ ~ Wol akInutyad nryDpatet S INDUSTRY AND ENERGY DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER INDUSTRY SERIES PAPER NO. 57 BUILDING A COMPETITIVE EDGE IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES The Catalytic Role of Foreign and Domestic Enterprise Collaboration in Export Activities Appnl 1992 The World Bank Industry and Energy Deparment, OSP BUILDING A COMPETITIVE EDGE IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES The Catalytic Role of Foreign and Domestic Enterprise Collaboration in Export Activities April 1992 Induty Development Division Office or Operation and New Itiatives Industry and Energy Department Bureau for Affica Operations and Sectoral Policy The United States Agency for The World Bank International Development TABLE OF CONTETST Pase so. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. . . . . i I. INTODUCSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I II. DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY AND FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC ENTERPRISE COLLABORATION FOR EXPORT ACTIVITIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 A. Outward-Orientation and Foreign/Domestic Enterprise Collaboration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 B. Human Resource Development and Foreign/Domestic Enterprise Collaboration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 C. Private Sector Development and Foreign/Domestic Enterprise Collaboration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 III. MODES OF FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC ENTERPRISE AND PERSONNEL COLLABORATION FOR EXPORT ACTIVITIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 A. Foreign and Domeatic Collaboration for Export Activities--Broadly Defined. 9 B. Foreign and Domestic Enterprise Collaboration for Export Activities--Narrowly Defined . . . . . . . . . . 13 C. Risk-Taking by Foreign and Domestic Partners . . . . . 14 D. Medium-to-Long-Term Commitment by Foreign Partners . . 15 E. Gap Between Demand for and Supply of Various Modes of Foreign Collaboration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 IV. INTERVIEWS WITH EXPORTERS IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES . 19 A. Interviews with FLrms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 B. Sample Selection ..19 C. Questionnaire Design . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 D. Carrying Out Field Interviews . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 E. Sample Characteristics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 V. CONTRIBUTION TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN DEVELOPMENT OF FOREIGN/DOMESTIC EXPORT COLLABORATION . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 A. Contribution to Export Development . . . . . . . . . . 28 B. Contribution to Human Resource Development . . . . . . 35 C. Contribution to Private Sector Development . . . . . . 37 Page No. VI. LEGACIES OF INWARD-ORIENTED FOREIGN COLLABORATORS vs. NEW BREED OF OUTWARD-ORIENTED FOREIGN COLLABORATORS . . . . . 40 A. Distinction Between Outward-Oriented and Inward-Oriented Foreign Collaberators . . . . . . . . . 40 B. Survey Results of Manufacturing Exporters . . . . . . . 41 C. Survey Results of Primary Resource-Based (Non-Traditional) Exporters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 VII. MAJOR FACTORS CONSTRAINING SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES' EXPORT EXPANSION .... . . . . . ..... . . . . . . . . 51 A. Major Demand-Side Constraints . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 B. Major Supply-Side Constraints . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 VIII. SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN FIRMS' DESIRE FOR NEW OR ADDITIONAL FOREIGN COLLABORATION FOR EXPORT INITIATION OR EXPANSION . 55 A. Survey Results for Manufacturing Exporters . . . . . . 55 B. Survey Results for Primary Resource-Based (Non-Traditional) Exporters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 IX. IMPERFECT INFORMATION BETWEEN POTENTIAL FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC COLLABORATORS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 A. Major Factors Constraining Foreign Collaborators' Involvement in Sub-Saharan African Export Activities 71 B. Collaborators' Access to Information on Potential Partners for Manufacturing Exports . . . . . . . . . . 73 C. Potential Foreign Collaborators' Access to Risk Coverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ... . . . . . 82 D. Strategies to Narrow the Information Gap Between Potential Foreign and Domestic Collaborators . . . . . 83 X. IMPLEMENTATION OF EXPORT POLICY INSTRUMENTS . . . . . . . . . 86 A. Free Trade Status . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86 B. Trade Finance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 C. Investment Finance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 D. Investment and Regulatory Regimes for Foreign Collaborators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102 E. Exchange Rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107 F. Primary Input Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 XI. PHYSICAL TRADE INFRASTRUCTURE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112 A. Survey Results .... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112 B. Strategies to Correct Poor Physical Trade Infrastructure Service ................ 116 Page so. XII. DIRECTION OF FUTURE WORK . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118 A. PrioritY in Building a Competitive Edge in Most Sub-Saharan African Countries . . . . . . . . . . 118 B. Strategies to Narrow the External Gap Between High Demand for, and Negligible Supply of, Foreign Collaborators .... . . . . ...... . . . . . . . 119 C. Strategies to Narrow the Internal Gap Between Private Enterprises' High Demand and Government Agencies' Restrictive Policies for (Export- Oriented) Foreign Collaboration . . . . . . . . . . . . 119 D. Strategies to Narrow the Information Gap Between Potential Foreign and Domestic Collaborators .122 R2FERENCES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125 ANNiuES Annex. I: Types of Foreign Collaboration and Export Orientation of Sample Firms Interviewed in the 16 Sub-Saharan African Countries . . . . . . . . . . . 127 Annehx II: Sample Exporters' Comments on Duty (Indirect Tax, and Restriction)-Free and Foreign Exchange Access Administration for Raw Material/Intermediate Input and Capital Goods for Export Production . . . . . . . 147 Annex III: Questionnaires for Foreign/Domestic Collaboration Company for Industrial or Primary Resource-Based (Non-Traditional) Export (or Potential Export) (available on request) Annex IV: Questionnaires for Company Without Foreign/Domestic Collaboration for Industrial or Primary Resource-Based (Non-Traditional) Export (or Potential Export) (available on request) TABLES Table 3.1 Modes of Forei%n/Domestic Enterprise Collaboration for Industrial and Non-Traditional Export Activities in Sub-Saharan African Countries Table 4.1 An Overview of Types of Foreign Collaboration Reported by Sample Manufacturing Firms in 16 Sub-Saharan African Countries Table 4.2 An Overview of Types of Foreign Collaboration Reported by Sample Primary Resource-Based Firms in 16 Sub-Saharan African Countries Table 4.3 Product Specialization of Sample Firms Table 4.4 Size Distribution of Sample Firms Table 5.1 Relationship Between Types of Foreign Collaboration and Degree of Export Orientation in Manufacturing Export Table 5.2 Relationship Between Types of Foreign Collaboration and Degree of Export Orientation in Primary Resource-Based (Non-Traditional) Export Table 5.3 Private vs. Publlc Ownership of Sample Enterprises Table 6.1 Use of Foreign Collaboration for Manufacturing Export: Inward- Oriented vs. Outward-Oriented Enterprises Table 6.2 Percentages of Sample Manufacturing Firms Belonging to Five Different Market Orientation Categories Table 6.3 Use of Foreign Collaboration for Primary Resource-Based (Non- Traditional) Export: Inward-Oriented vs. Outward-Oriented Enterprises Table 6.4 Percentages of Sample Primary Resource-Based Firms Belonging to Five Different Market Orientation Categories Table 7.1 Sample Firms' Evaluation of Major Factors Constraining Sub-Saharan African Countries' Export Growth Table 8.1 Sample Manufacturing Export Enterprises' Intentions Regarding New or Additional Foreign Collaboration Table 8.2 Relationship Between Future roreign Collaboration Intentions and Market Orientation/Current Collaboration Status of Sample Manufactured Firms Table 8.3 Difference Between Demand Weights Attached by Sample Manufactured Firms and Current Weights on Modes of Narrowly Defined Foreign Collaboration Table 8.4 Difference Between Desired Weights Attached by Sample Primary Resource-Based Firms and Current Weights on Modes oo .Narrowly Defined Foreign Collaboration Table 9.1 Past Supply Sources of Foreign Collaboration for Sample M4anufacturing and Primary Resource-Based (Non-Traditional) Exporters m ECUTIVE SUARY Qbgjgti..and Methodology i. Although the most profound economic development lessons of the last four decades derive from the superb performance of outward-oriented development strategies, the intricacies of initiating an outward industrial development process in low-income countries have yet to be explored and articulated. Particularly for Sub-Saharan African countries, finding the Uraceical means to initiate an outward-oriented development strategy is the most challenging task for the 1990s. The World Bank-U.S.A.I.D joint research project (Phase I) identifies key components of such a task based on firm-level interviews of 121 manufacturing exporters (and potential exporters) and 56 primary resource-based (non-traditional) exporters (and potential exporters) in 16 Sub-Saharan African countries (Botswana, Burundi, Cote d'Ivoire, Ghana, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mozambique, Nigeria, Seoegal, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia, and Zimbabwe) ii. The most critical components identified by the exporters are: (i) foreign/domestic collaboration; (ii) export policy instruments; and (iii) physical trade infrastructure. A cress country methodology based on interview data was employed for the purpose of discovering comon issues related to these components across the Sub-Saharan African uountries. The ultimate objective was to suggest an imaginative approach for common strate- siu. Contribution to Sub-Saharan A�fican Develogment by Foreiln/Domestic Enter=rise and Personnel Collaboration in Export Activities iii. Foreign collaboration as a necessarv condition for manufactured gnports. Virtually all sample manufacuing exorters (randomly selected with respect to foreign collaboration status, size, etc.) cited at least one case of (broadly defined) foreign/domestic enterprise or personnel collaboration. one factor became clear, which was that almost all the manufacturing firms that did not engage in any type of foreign collaboration were unable to export their products (i.e., they might be poteatial exporters). This confirms that some sort of foreign collaboration is a necessary condition for manufactured exports. iv. Capacity to export. Because African firms lack the full capacity to export, foreign collaborators have to bring the following elements of that capacity into African manufacturing industries: (a) technical, marketing, and managerial kno-how, critical for starting up manufactured exports; (b) access to the established world market ntwor; (c) ca2acitX to *2ackage' (i.e., put together) (a) and (b) with local and external capital and with local labor and entrepreneurial resources; and (d) financial resources for investment and working capital. - it - v. Modes of foreign collaboration. Exporters of manufactured goods in Sub-Saharan Africa have relied on 13 types of broadly-defined collaboration between foreign and domestic enterprises (and personnel) to bring in the above four elements, in part or combination, to their countries and enterprises: (1) foreign direct investment (FDI); (2) joint ventures (JV); (3) technical/- marketing/management agreements; (4) sub-contracting agreements; (5) foreign trade agents' export sales intermediation; foreign trading companies' export sales intermediation; (7) foreign companies' original establishment; (8) foreign companies' loan guarantees; (9) localize.d foreigner's family legacy; (10) brand-name licensing; (11) technical, marketing, or management consulting (assistance); (12) foreign-educated or foreign-company-educated owners; and (13) partial affiliation with foreign companies. vi. In particular, (1), (2), (3), and (4) (so-called narrowx defined foreign/domestic entorrise collaboration) were the core of foreign/domestic collaboration because the foreign partner took responsibility for the entire scope of (a) know-how and (b) world market access, and for the entire scope or part of (c) the capacity to package (plus (d) capital, in the case of FDI and JV). vii. Foreign collaboration-for orimary resource-based (non-traditional) exgort orimarily for market access and cagital. In the case of certain primary resource-based (non-traditional) goods, even though foreign collabora- tion was not necessarily an absolute essential for exporting (about 15% of the sample firms export without any foreign collaboration), its role is signifi- cant primarily in terms of providing access to the world market and supplying capital. The five important types of foreign collaboration (including "no collaboration") for primary resource-based (non-traditional) exports were reported to be (in order of importance): (i) JV; (ii) FDI; (iii) 'no collab- oration"; (iv) foreign trade agents/foreign trading companies; (v) a foreign company's original establishment. The comparable types for manufactured export were: (i) FDI; (ii) localized foreigners' family legacy; (iii) JV; (iv) technical consulting/marketing consulting/management consulting; and (v) sub-contracting, technical/marketing/management agreements, or foreign company's original establishment. viii. Human .rsource develonment, Virtually all workers in the sample firms that engaged in collaboration with foreign companies were recruited from the unskilled worker pool. Indigenous workers (including semi-skilled and skilled workers, supervisors, and managers) acquired skills through on-the-job trainirg and learning-by-doing on the factory floors, in export salesrooms, and in the offices of managers, under the guidance of foreign supervisors or managers (or local supervisors or managers who had acquired their skills under foreign supervisors or managers). As a results of this skill formation, some African companies' labor productivity increased from about 30-50S of the European or South African level to about 60-70% of the foreign level in five years, and their real wage rates were more than 50S higher than the minimu wages or comparable wages of non-exporting companies or companies that did not engage in foreign collaboration. These empirical data demonstrate the impres- sive contribution of export-oriented foreign/domestic enterprise collaboration to the human resource development of *any Sub-Saharan African countries. - iii - ix. Priy.ate sector develgRmnt. Manufacturing and primary resource- based export businesses in most Sub-Saharan African countries are dominated, by foreign and domestic private enterprises (less than one-tenth of the sample firms were 100% public or partly public companies). Foreign/domestic private enterprise collaboration for exporting plays a catalytic roie in the private sector development of Sub-Saharan African countries by building a competitive edge in the world market cnd improving local firms' capacity to export. One disappointing aspect, however, is the lack of skill transfer across many local firms. High unemployment does not allow for incentives for high labor mobili- ty. Inward-Oriented vs. Outward-Oriented Foreign Collaborators x. Outward-orientation vs. inMard-orientation. Even if all foreign collaborators made positive contributions to Africa's development by merely being involved in some export activities, one needs to sort out the superior from the not-so-effective (i.e., outward-oriented from inward-oriented) foreign collaborators. By defining firms that export half or more of their products as outward-oriented, and those that export less than half as inward- oriented, the survey results reveal the following. xi. Large-size (MNC) vs. small- and egdium-size manufacturing firms. Although almost half the medium-size (between 200 and 999 workers) and small- size firms (fewer than 199 workers) in the manufacturing sector are outward- oriented, far less than one-fifth of the large firms (with more than 1,000 workers) are outward-oriented. About three-quarters of the largest manufac- turing MNCs sell more than three-quarters of their products to the domestic market. While the inward-orientation of these MNCs reflects their original, and still curront intent, the inward orientation of small- and medium-size firms appears to be due to their lack of capacity to export, the result of insufficient foreign collaboration. On the other hand, a bright spot in several Sub-Saharan African countries is the emergence - outward-minded small- and medium-size local entrepreneurs who have managed to collaborate with their counterpart foreign firms. Another encouraging aspect is that these outward-oriented small- and medium-size firms are relatively young, unlike the old inward-oriented large-size MNCs. xii. PrimarX resource-based firms. The primary resource-based firms in all size categories are consistently more outward-oriented than are the manufacturing firms. In particular, the large-size primary resource-based firms are highly outward-oriented (with products that have a comparative advantage), unlike the manufacturing firms (with their goods that lack comparative advantage). aijor Factors CQostraaing. Sub-Saliaran African Countries' Export EIpansion xiii. MaloX demand-side constraints. Despite Sub-Saharan Africa exporters' tariff-free and non-quota advantage in the European and U.S. markets, sample firms stated that the competitive edge held by other develop- ing coUntries in the non-regional hard-currency world market is the most notable demand-side constraint. In the regional market, firms cited the i ^ - lv - limited size of the market, its low purchasing power, import restrictions, smuggling, and competition with South Africa as the most important constraints. xiv. Ma10r supplv-side constraints. The lack of capacity to export was reported as the most important supply-side constraint. The most often- mentioned elements lacking ars: access to the world market network, capacity to *package," and technical, marketing, and managerial know-how. The second most important constraint cited by the firms is their governments' failure to implement export policy instruments effectively. The most often-mentioned instruments are the various tools to ensure a free trade status, access to trade and investment finance, and other regulatory regimes for foreign collaboration. The third most important constraint indicated by the sample firms is inadequate Fhysical trade infrastructure. Sub-Saharan African Exporters' Desire for New or Additional Foreign Collabora- tiIn xv. Excegss demand for foreign collaboration. Recognizing their lack of capacity to export a.; the most serious supply-side constraint, which can be resolved only through stepped-up foreign collaboration, a majority of the sample firms revealed their desire to engage in new or additional foreign collaboration. In particular, the majority of small- and medium-size manufac- turing firms were seeking new or additional collaboration. On the one hand, inward-oriented small- and medium-size manufacturing firms were desperate to become outward-oriented through new foreign collaboration, and already outward-oriented small- and medium-size firms were seeking additional foreign collaboration to deepen their presence in the world market. On the other hand, only small fraction of large manufacturing firms expressed a desire for additional foreign collaboration, primarily due to their preference to focus Inward to domestic African markets. xvi. For their part, primary resource-based firms (including large firm) seek additional foreign collaboration even though they are already more outward-oriented than are manufacturing firms. However, most of the small- and medium-size manufacturing firms that expressed a strong desire for additional or new foreign collaboration did not know the specific channels through which to find potential export-oriented foreign collaborators. This leaves a huge excess demand for export-oriented foreign collaborators, unmatched by any serious attempt to locate potential supplies. xvii. Demand vs. actual foreign collaboration. A mirror image of the huge excess demand for outward-oriented foreign collaboration, particularly by the new breed of outward-minded small- and medium-size manufacturing firms, is the huge discrepancy between their preferences for, and actual supplies of, particular Ines of foreign collaboration. The most notable discrepancy involves the predominant wish for technical/marketing/management agreements. These were matched in the past mostly with a substitute--technical consult- ing/marketing consulting/management consulting. The strong demand for an integrated 2ackaae of (i) access to the world market, (ii) capacity to "package,' and (iii) know-how was met only by the supply of know-how without the most critical other elements. This implies that in the past the strong demand for export-oriented foreign gntargrLses was actually met by the supply of foreign geso2m orly (consultants). In any event, the most dominant mode of foreign collaboration, preferred by both manufacturing and primary re- source-based firms, is technical/marketing/management agreements, which in the past were only a small fraction of the supply of foreign collaboration. For manufacturing firms, the second most desired mode is subcontracting agree- ments, and for primary resource-based firms, the second preference is for joint ventures. External Ca Astwee n High Demand for. and Negligible Sugnly of. Yxgort- Oriented ForeXgn Co11aborators xviii. Because the source of export-oriented foreign collaborators is external to the host African countries, the aferementioned huge excess demand for outward-oriented fore'.gn collaborators is the result of an extenal ggn between the high demand for, .and the negligible supply of, foreign collaborators. However, some of the key factors determining potential foreign collaborators' supply intentions are not purely external, because the follow- ing key internal factors in most Sub-Saharan African countries also influence their decision to become involved: (i) the information gao that exists between potential foreigr. and domestic collaborators, which includes an extremely negative image that foreigners have of Africa; (ii) the itra poliy 8gag between local enterprises' high demand for, and government agencies' restrictive policies on (export-oriented) foreign collaboration; and (iii) Africa's poor physical trade infrastruct-ure. Compared to these very negative internal factors, the only positive elements offered by some Sub- Saharan African countries are: (i) tariti-free or quota-free access to the European or U.S. market; and (ii) relatively low nominal wages. It seems that the negatives have outweighed the small positive, however, in most Sub-Saharan African countries. Informatign Can Between Potential Eoreir-n and Domes-tic Collaborators xix. Past gatterns of foreign enterprise involvqeent. The following four types of foreign companies are involved in Sub-Saharan African manufac- turing export activities: * 2Fr:. inward-oriented large MNCs that have been involved in Sub- Saharan African manufacturing since at least the 1960s. These MNCs have started exporting marginally (mostly in the regional market) only very recently. It does not appear that simLlar large MNCs will be interested in new collaboration in most Sub-Saharan African countries (whether for the domestic or export market) in the near future because they have better alternative locations around the world. * Secon , some medium-size foreign collaborators that became in- volved in Afriea as a result of mere accident (such as through tourism). _ vi - * Third. a new breed of outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign companies that have had previous experience in African manufacturing. These firms have begun to collaborate with the new breed of outward-minded small- and medium-size local entrepreneurs or localized foreigners. * �aFourth, a new breed of outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign companies who have had previous experience exporting to Africa, and have recently decided to b-tcome involved directly in African exports. Particularly notable are the third and fourth types of foreign collaborators; the key factor that distinguishes them is their previous experience in or with Africa. Their overwhelming presence suggests that because of the extremely negative image about Africa held by most foreign enterprises, firms that have not had experience with Africa tend not even to consider that continent a viable export location. xx. One of the bright spots in most of the Sub-Saharan African countries is the emergence of such outward-minded small- and medium-size local entrepreneurs who are eager to collaborate with the new breed of potential foreign partners. There does not appear to be enough matching stock of this type of foreign collaborator, however. Again, this relates to the negative image of Africa and the information gap. Therefore, innovative mechanisms designed to narrow the information gap need to be developed. To locate potential foreign collaborators, even those with no previous African involve- ment, and bring them to Africa would require an imaginative approach to mechanisms designed to narrow the information gap. xxi. Current match-makinif mechanisms. Many of the new breed of local entreprenout expressed frustration in trying to find mechanisms to assist them in locating outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign enterprises with whom they could collaborate. This is despite the activities of existing international assistance schemes, national investment promotion centers, national export promotion centers, and foreign private agents. Most of the international assistance schemes for fostering enterprise partnership in the Sub-Saharan African countries appear to have fallen back on supplying foreign consultants' technical assistance. This is instead of full partnership with outward-oriented private enterprises for an integrated package of know-how and external market access. Natiotaal agencies have never had financial resouxe or the skills and connections to match-make potential foreign collaborators with local partners. Private foreign agents have worked mainly as buyers' agents for sub-contracting arrangements. There appears to be no domestic private agent that has played a match-making role in outward-oriented foreign collaboration in Sub-Saharan Africa. xxii. Access to risk coverage in exDort-oriented foreign collaboration. There appears to be no easy access for small- and medium-size foreign firms to cover risk-taking in export-oriented foreign collaboration. - vii - Internal Gan Between Private Enterprisen' Hguh Demand for. and Government Aeencies' Restrictive Policies on (Export-Oriented) Foreign Collaboration xxiii. Exort golicy in;ruments. ineffective implementation of export policy instruments to ensure local expo:-ters equal footing wiLh foreign competitors (who operate under free trade and free market mechanisms) reflects officials' restrictive attitude (as opposed to private enterprises' high demand) toward foreign collaboration. This has resulted in the current internal gap that discourages the inflow of foreign collaborators to Africa. Export policy instruments include: (i) various schemes for free trade status; (ii) various institutions to ensure access to trade and investment finance; (iii) investment and other regulatory regimes for foreign collaborators; (iv) realistic real exchange rates; and (v) ensuring competitive primary input prices. xxiv. Free trade status. Many Sub-Saharan African countries have recently introduced or reformed the following free trade instruments: (i) export processing zones (EPZ); (ii) bonded manufacturing warehouses (Bhis); (iii) duty-drawback systems; (iv) duty-exemption systems; (v) import licensing and schemes to provide access to foreign exchange for exporters. However, much work remains to be done to implement these instruments effec- tively in most Sub-Saharan African countries (only Swaziland and Botswana appear to have achieved free trade status, under the Southern African Customs Union). Three major causes for the ineffective implementation of free trade status are: (i) lack of commitment; (ii) lack of know-how and administrative capability; and (iii) lack of inter-agency coordination. For example, lack of expertise in handling imported input-output coefficients, common in most African countries, may call in turn for a common strategy for many African countries for estimating these coefficients. Further, to guarantee speedy access to free trade status with a minimum of red tape for foreign and domestic companies, a two-stage approach is proposed. (Stage 1 is composed of EPZs and BMWs for 100%-export-oriented foreign and domestic companies and includes a fixed-drawback scheme; Stage 2 introduces duty exemption and individual drawback schemes as imported input-output coefficients are avail- able.) xxv. Trade and investment finance. Most Sub-Saharan African countries have failed to provide equal footing with foreign competitors in ensuring access to trade finance (based on trade transaction-based, self-liquidating mechanisms) and investment finance without physical collateral even though some of them have recently introduced trade finance rediscount schemes and investment funds. Most countries are in an infant stage in trade and long- term finance institution-building. xxvi. Investment and other regulatorv reaimes for foreign collaborators. The common practice in Africa of restricting expatriate workers' transfer of know-how and of imposing licensing requirements for technical/marketing/mana- gement agreements and for technical/marketing/management consulting are equivalent to telling potential foreign collaborators that the country does = want them, despite the high demand for them by private enterprises. To close this obvious internal gap, all foreign collaboration activities generat- - viii ing export earnings should be allowed to operate under an almost-free regla- tory regime similar to the EPZ regime (that is, not only under free trade but almost free from foreign exchange restrLctLons, profit repatriation restric- tions, expatriate work permlts, domestic labor regulations, etc.). xxvii. exehanfze rates. Significant progress has been made in many Sub- Saharan African countries in adjusting the nominal exchange rates to maintain realistic real exchange rates. Two of the sample countries (Senegal and GOte d'lvoire) have adopted a different approach, of compensating exchange rate over-valuation through cash grants to exporters. But this approach has failed to provide international competitiveness. Furthermore, recently the budget mismanagement has forced the discontinuation of even the cash grant payments for exporters. Physical Trade Infrastructure xxviii. Most Sub-Saharan African countries have failed to provide their exporters with the physical trade infrastructure (such as good port and transport facilities, roads, communLcations, and utilities) that would help them to compete with foreign firms in the world market. More disappointing than the poor physical situation is the lack of commitment as reflected in high port charges, inefficient public services, and undisciplined private monopolies in cargo handling, transport, utilities, etc. Direction of Luture Work xxix. To narrow the external gag. The biggest development challenge in most Sub-Saharan African countries may be how to devise imaginative strategies for narrowing the enormous external gap between the high demand for, and , negligible potential supply of, export-oriented foreign (enterprises) collabo- rators. Such strategies must have three distinct components: (i) strategies to narrow the internal gap between local private enterprises' and managers' high demand for (export-oriented) foreign collaboration and government agencies' restrictive policies; (li) strategies to narrow the lnformation gap between potential foreign and domestic collaborators; and (iii) strategies to Improve the physical trade infrastructure. The direction of future work is to take a common approach to (i) and (ii), as summarized below. xxX. Common strategies to arrow the internal gag. A common strategy to narrow the internal gap would consist of three elements: (i) an awareness can.dLin on the critical importance of foreign/domestic enterprise collabora- tion for private sector and human resource development, as well as for outward-oriented development; (ii) the absolute necessity of yovernsent commitment (to implement export policy instruments effectively); and (iII) tehInical know-how to implement these policies and instruments. As for (iii), for example, successful implementation of a duty-free import adminis- tration depends on the manner in which the imported input-output coefficients are handled. If the ad hoc and piecemeal approach to these coefficients is replaced by a systems approach supported by common resources that many Sub- Saharan African countries may use separately, as well as by the pool of ix - requisite expertise, then maximum common efficiency can be gained with minimum common resources. xxxi. Common strategies to narrow the information gap. In considering strategies to narrow the information gap, two institutions might play a catalytic role: (i) private match-making mechanisms; and (11) export-oriented foreign/domestic enterprise collaboration rlsk-coverage schemes. These inastitutions would be exclusively for Sub-Saharan African export activities. They would be desigr.ed to attract a new breed of outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign enterprise whose strong negative image on Africa has so far led them to exclude Africa as a potential collaboration site. In design- ing the detailed mechanisms for these two institutions, based on an imagina- tive approach, the underlying premises would be the following. First, putting national and international resources into building private match-making mechanisms that would be self-supporting in the medium-term would be more efficient than putting the same resources into public match-making mechanisms. Second, since export-oriented foreign/domestic enterprise collaboration would generate export earnings, (i) there would be an incentive for paying the full costs of private match-making and export-oriented foreign collaborators' risk coverage in the medium-term; and (ii) there would be an incentive for private match-makers to emerge if there were enough potential volume in the medium- term. But without a visionary initiative by national and international authorities, such institution-building would rarely occur. There is an urgency in bringing such new breeds of outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign enterprises for African manufacturing export, because time may be running out quickly as the potential stock of such foreign enterprises seeking relocation has been rapidly diminishing. I. INTRODUCTION 1.01 This paper reports the Phase I findings of a World Bank-U.S. AID joint research project on foreign export catalysts in Sub-Saharan African countries.- 1.02 The objective of the research (Phase I) was two-fold: analytical and operational. The analytical objective was to improve our understanding of the critical factors needed for the initiation of an outward-oriented indus- trial development strategy in the Sub-Saharan African countries. Our conclu- sions are based on exporters' and potential exporters' direct views. The most critical factor is collaboration between foreign and domestic enterprises in a country's export activities. The next important factor is effective implemen- tation of export policy instruments (including regulatory reforms related to the inflow or know-how). And the third important factor is adequate physical trade infrastructure. 1.03 Our operational objective was to suggest action-oriented pilot research to demonstrate imaginative and innovative common means to (i) identify export-oriented potential foreign collaborators and (ii) bring them to the Sub-Saharan African countries. Another component of the future research will be designed to find feasible common means for improving imple- mentation of the export policy instruments in many Sub-Saharan African countries. - The research team was composed of Warren Weinstein (Research Coordinator: Director, AFR/ONI, U.S.A.I.D), Yung Whee Rhee (Research Task Manager: Principal Economist, World Bank), Katharine Katterbach (Consultant, World Bank), Therese Belot (Consultant), and Christine Soulier (Consultant). Word processing support was provided by Wilson Peiris and Zai Fanai. Editorial assistance was provided by Stephanie Gerard. An earlier draft of the paper was discussed in a World Bank seminar on December 17, 1991. The views presented in this draft are the researchers' and do not reflect the views of the World Bank or USAID. - 2 - 1.04 A cross-country methodology based on data from interviews with firms in 16 Sub-Saharan African countries was employed. This was not so much for cross-country comparison as for identifying the critical issues common to many Sub-Saharan African countries. It was hoped that the research could provide an analytical and empirical basis for a common strategy to deal with the issues. For that matter, the paper does not focus on country-specific issues. 1.05 Chapter II provides a perspective on a low-income country's development strategy in terms of foreign/domestic enterprise collaboration in industrial export activities. Chapter III defines the various modes of foreign enterprise and personnel collaboration for export activities. Chapter IV explains the sample selection and characteristics as well as field inter- views. Chapter V summarizes the interview findings about the contribution that foreign/domestic collaborative efforts have made to Sub-Saharan African development. Chapter VI disaggregates the findings in Chapter V to distin- guish inward-oriented from outward-oriented foreign collaborators. Chapter VII summarizes the sample firms' views on major factors constraining Sub- Saharan African countries' export expansion, and Chapter VIII analyzes the sample firms' wants in terms of new or additional foreign collaboration for export initiation or expansion. Chapter IX analyzes the imperfect information gap between potential foreign and domestic collaborators. The purpose is to suggest feasible strategies to deal with the gap between demand and supply of foreign collaborators. Chapter X reviews the sample firms' comments on the effectiveness of export policy implementation, and Chapter XI summarizes sample firms' views on physical trade infrastructure in their countries. Finally, Chapter XII suggests the direction of future work. II. DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY AND FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC ENTERPRISE COILABORATION FOR EXPORT ACTIVITIES A. Outward-Orientation and Foreign/Domestic EnterRrise Collaboration 1. Development Lessons 2.01 The most profound economic development lessons of the last four decades derive from the superb performance of outward-oriented development strategies such as in East Asia. However, the intricacies of initiating the industrial development process in an outward-direction in low-income develop- ing countries have yet to be explored and articulated. Particularly for Sub- Saharan African developing countries, finding the practical means to initiate an outward-oriented development strategy is the most challenging task of the 1990s. 2.02 Such pioneers of development economics as Prebish I/ and Nurkse,A/ who viewed exports for developing countries pessimistically after World War II, never anticipated the development success of the East Asian newly industrializing economies (NIEs) based on outward-oriented strategies. The major reason for this might have been the economists' inability to anticipate the micro-level dynamism and efficiency gains associated with outward-oriented industrial development. 2.03 By the same token, contemporary development economists have yet to learn enough from the development practitioners who have f'.rst-hand knowledge of the depth of the NIEs' development process, which occurred on the factory floor and in export sales rooms. They need to learn more if they want to explore fully the more intricate lessons of the industrial development process 2/ Prebish (1952). ]/ Nurkse (1959). inside the 'black-box". Even the existence of a "black-box" appears to have been concealed by preconceived models and aggregated data. Somehow key development actors have been lost in the development discussions. 2.04 Specifically, the intricacies of the East Asian development lessons have yet to be learned fully in the following critical area: the East Asians could not have had the capacity to export their industrial goods in the early 1960s (when they initiated their outward-oriented strategies by imple- menting egual- footing exRort policy instruments) without their cumulative experience of acquiring such capacity on the factory floors of foreign firms with whom they had been collaborating over several decades.Al 2. Capacity to Exnort 2.05 The lack of industrial export supply responses to export policy reform in most low-income developing countries, including the Sub-Saharan African countries, stems from these countries' basic lack of capacity to export. The four key elements of such capacity are: (a) technical, marketing, and managerial know-how, critical for starting up manufactured exports; (b) access to the established world market network; (c) capacity to "package" (i.e., put together) the first two elements with local and external capital and with local labor and entrepre- neurial resources; and i/ See Rhee, Ross-Larson, and Pursell (1984) and Rhee (1989a). - 5 - (d) financial resources for investment capital (needed to purchase capital equipment and factory buildings) and working capital (needed to pay for raw materials and intermediate inputs, wages, rents, etc.). 2.06 In the short-run, (d) financial resources can be obtained through internal or external borrowing, but (a) technical, marketing, and managerial know-how, (b) access to the world market, and (c) the capacity to package can come into a country only by means of collaboration between foreign and domestic enterprises (as well as with individual experts). Furthermore, (a) export know-how, (b) access to the world market, and (c) the capacity to package can be acquired by firms in low-income countries only through on-the- job training and learning-by-doing on factory floors. This must occur in export sales rooms both inside and outside the low-income countries and also in managers' offices, at least for the medium term.A' 2.07 Therefore, for low-income developir.g countries the primary element of an outward-oriented development strategy is early collaboration between their domestic enterprises and foreign firms in industrial export activities. (The various modes of foreign/domestic enterprise and personnel collaboration are discussed in Chapter III.) 3. Equal Footing Export Policies 2.08 Key constraints to potential foreign collaborators' interest in low-income developing countries in Africa are: ,/ See Rhee (1990), Rhee and Belot (1990) and Rhee, Katterbach and White (1990). -6- (a) policy and business environments that fail to ensure local firms equal footing in the world market with foreign competitors who operate under free trade and free market mechanisms; (b) lack of information on potential collaborators--whether countries or enterprises--as well as negative images about Africa; (c) poor physical trade infrastructure that fails to provide equal footing with foreign competitors in the world market; and (d) lack of political and social stability, which means unfavorable living conditions, among other things. In particular, the failure by developing country governments to implement equal-footing export policies not only discourages the inflow of foreign collaborators for export activities but also prevents export activities from being competitive in the world market. 2.09 Thus, the second most important element for an outward-oriented development strategy is for governments to implement equal-footing export policies. The key components of equal-footing export policies are: (a) realistic exchange rates; (b) free trade status; (c) easy access to trade financing; (d) automatic investment licensing, easy access to investment financ- ing, and freedom from other restrictive regulatory regimes; and (e) competitive primary input pricef.I Chapter X discusses the detailed instruments for these policies. B. Human Resource Development and Foreign/Domesti Enterrise ogllaboration 2.10 Recently the importance of human resource development in the development strategies of low-income countries has been emphasized.Z' Howev- er, priorities targeted as various instruments of human resource development (such as on-the-job training, primary education, etc.) have yet to be defined based on micro-level development experiences over the last several decades. This lack of priority and definition is a crucial ,ap if one considers such instruments as practical ani immediately necessary for the outward-oriented industrial development process in low-income countries that lack financial resources to support all the instruments at the same time. 2.11 It would seem that in low-income developing countries nothing should receive higher priority than human resource development geared toward acquiring the key elements of the capacity to export (listed in paragraph 2.05). For the immediate future the feasible and the most effective instru- ment to do this is not training through formal school eduation, or in training institutes or research centers, but on-the-job training and learning- L/ See Rhee (1985), Rhee (1989a), Rhee (1991a). 2/ A World Bank report on Africa states that: "A central theme of the report is that although sound macroeconomic policies and an efficient infrastruc- ture are essential to provide an enabling environment for the productive use of resources, they alone are not sufficient to transform the structure of African economies. At the same time, major efforts are needed to build African capacities to produce a better trained, more healthy population and to greatly strengthen the institutional framework within which development can take place. This is why the report strongly supports the call for a human-centered development strategy made by the ECA and UNICEF" (World Bank (1989), p. xii). See also World Development Report, 1991 (World Bank, 1991). - 8 - by-doing on factory floors and in the sales rooms of foreign factories that produce and sell industrial export commodities.11 2.12 It should be noted that as much as outward-oriented development has benefited from human resource developient occurring on-the-job and in learning-by-doing on factory floors and in sales rooms, human resource development itself has benefited from the outward-oriented development process, which is characterized by international competition and exposure. C. ~jPrivate Sector Development and Foreign/Domestic Enterpris Cgollaboration 2.13 In many low-income countries, transformation from inefficient public sector-dominated industrial practices to private sector industrial development guided by market mechanisms requires more than a mere privatiza- tion effort. It requires efficient industrial develoDment strategies. For example, East Asia's unprecedented private sector development has occurred as the natural consequence of effective industrial development strategies, and not so much as a result of particular strategies to develop the private sector. 2.14 Since private foreign firms play a catalytic role in outward- oriented industrial development of low-income developing countries, for- eign/domestic enterprise collaboration in industrial export activities should be one of the centerpieces of private sector development strategies in low- income countries. .j/ See Koike (1987), Koike and Inoki (1989), Rhee (1990), Rhee and Belot (1990), and Rhee, Katterbach and White (1990). The emerging view on multinational companies (MNCs) is to recognize their critical role in the transfer of technical, marketing, and managerial know-how and skills to developing countries--a role probably more important than the conventional direct transfer of financial resources (UN Center on TNC, 1988). - 9 - III. MODES OF FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC ENTERPRISE AND PERSONNEL COLLABORATION FOR EXPORT ACTIVITIES A. Foreign and Domestic Collaboratign for Export Activities-_-Broadly D2fined 3.01 Within two groups, there are 13 types of collaboration, broadly- defined, between foreign and domestic enterprises and personnel (see Table 3.1) for export activities.9/ This study covers only those export activities that involve mainly industrial and primary resource-based (non-traditional) exports. 3.02 Capacity to export. No matter what the mode of collaboration (see below), the foreign partner brings to the host country and enterprise the four key elements of the capacity to export (see para. 2.05), briefly: (a) technical, marketing, and managerial know-how; (b) access to international markets; (c) capacity to put the above together with local labor and entrepre- neurial resources a- well as capital, and (d) financial resources (in the form of equity). 1 3.03 At the outset, it must be stressed that the gualih y and depth of these resources are what matters, not that the partner is a foreign company or individual. Foreign collaboration's ultimate contribution to development, i/ An increasing trend toward diversified foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration has been recognized. See, for example, Oman (1989). 1.Q/ Hereafter, we use the abbreviated expression: (a) know-how; (b) access to world market; (c) capacity to "package;" and (d) capital. - 10 - therefore, is judged by the quality and depth of the above elements and whether these elements make an impact on the implementation of an outward- oriented industrial development strategy. Note that (b) access to market and (c) capacity to package all the elements can be provided only by foreign companies that have built a reputation in the world market through long experience and that enjoy name recognition, while part of (a) know-how or (d) financial resources can be provided by individual foreigners. Table 31: MODES OF FORE!GNIDOMESTIC BNTERPRISB COLLABORATION FOR INDUSRILAL AND NON-TRADITIONAL EXORT ACTIVTIS iN SU8-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES OROUP I ORUPI n Foredgn collaboration with foreign partner's risk.taking in Foreign coolaboisatIon whknforeign artner's risk-taking in imnnF of (a) equity, (byroyalies (fees or profits) tbat are orn of ta) equlty, (b) tieprofisa) that are intermediation, or (d3 loan guarantee tion, or (d) loant guarantee (i) Foren direct intent (FDI) () Joint ventures (TV) if (iii) T_ l~. tagreements (rAQMIdt Ag) W i,v) Sub-contctng agements (SC) A (v) Fofe:w trd agents export sles ilnternedla- tbon (PTA) (vi) Forei tuding compan aport sales interme- diatio (FM) (vii) Foreign company original establishment (FO) (viii) Foreig company's oan guwantee (L) X) Localicd foreigners family Iegy (LF) (O) Brand-name liensing (BL) W (0i) Teacaa, o mtit consultIng (aT ce '$Lor M )b (Xii) Fogn-educated or foreoncowpsay. educated owna (FE) (xl) Panal asffliton with fore4ig compay (PFA) g watny dened h/domestic entapepse coliabotation an hod Fe wit bt king them to the Ami's par pertfoma attributable to particur ultg input or brand name. 3.04 We distinguish two groups of foreign/domestic collaboration modes, Group I and Group II, as shown in Table 3.1. In Group I, the foreign partner takes risks in terms of equity; royalties (fees) or profits proportional to - 11 - export volume; export sales ii.termediation; or loan guarantees. In Group II, the foreign partner does not run these same risks. Group I 3.05 FDI and ioint ventures. Foreign direct investment (FDI) can be considered a special-case joint venture (OV) in that the foreign equity share in FDI is 100% while that in a JV is leas than 100%. The foreign partner brings in the entire package of export capacity elements. 3.06 Techniral/marketingEMageM= Agreements. In technical/marketing/manageLent agreements (T/M/1t Ag), the foreign partner also brings in the entire package of the capacity to export except for- financial resources (equity). The foreign partner receives royalty payments that are proportional to the export volume during the contract period. It is also possible to have just a technical agreement (T Ag), marketing agreement (H Ag), or management agreement (itt Ag). Even in this case--where the fareign part-ter brings in only part of (a) know-how, and/or (b) access to world market, and/or (c) capacity to package--royalty payments are in proportion to the export volume during the contract period. Note that the entire package of the various elements that make up the capacity to export cannot be easily provided by foreign individuals--it has to come from a foreign company with long experience in the exporting business in a particular sector. 3.07 Subcontracting agreements. The foreign partner in subcontracting agreements (SC) brings its (b) access to the world market and some part of (a) know-how. Normally the foreign partner provides imported raw materials and intermediate inputs as well and pays the domestic partner export manufacturing fees in proportion to export quantity. Therefore, the foreign partner's profit is in proportie.s to export volume. (The domestic partner usually does not even know the per unit profit margin of the foreign partner.) - 12 - 3.08 Foreign trade agents and foreign trading comoanies. A foreign trade agent (FTA) or a foreign trading company (FTC) brings access to the world market. An PTA charges export sales intermediation fees in proportion to a coloany's export sales volume without taking title to the goods being exported by that company. In contrast, an FTC takes title to the goods by purchasing them from the local partner. Its profit comes from export volume, the profit margin being the difference between how much it pays for the goods locally and the selling the selling price in the world market. 3.09 Foreign company's original establishment. While we focused on current foreign/domestic enterprise and personnel collaboration at the time of our interviews, the effects of collaboration in the distant past cannot be ignored. To that end, it is necessary to identify the original creator of a company and whether any foreign company contributed earlier to establishing and starting up the company (FO). The foreign partner at an earlier time would likely have brought in the four elements cited above. Even if the original firm was producing strictly for the domestic market, the foreign partner might still have brought in elements similar to (a), (b), (c), and (d) but more closely related to the capacity to sell goods in the local market. 3.10 Loan guarantees. The foreign partner providing a loan guarantee (LG) for the domestic partner brings capital only and only indirectly at that. 3.11 Localized foreiGner's family legacv. Foreign influence on the capacity to export often comes from a family legacy with origins abroad, even though the current owner of the company may be a local citizen. Such a family legacy of know-how, access to the world market, capacity to package, and capital may vary greatly, depending on specific cases, but should not be overlooked. - 13 QLO1 II 3.12 Arand-name licensing. To maintain the reputation of a brand name, the foreign partner often provides partial know-how. Certainly, the foreign partner in a brand-name licensing (BL) arrangement opens access to the world market, although indirectly through implicit product quality. BL fees are fixed, regardless of a firm's export performance attributable to a particular brand name. In our survey we included other types of brand-name agreements for which fees are paid in proportion to export volume in marketing agreements (M Ag). A brand name represents the reputation and track record of a company, and, therefore, only a company, not an individual, can provide BL. 3.13 2echnical. marketing. or management consulting. The foreign partner in technical, marketing, or management consulting or assistance (TA, MA,, or Kt A) arrangem,ents brings in partial know-how. However, unlike technical, marketing, or management agreements, fees are fixed without being linked to the firms' export performance attributable to a particular consulting input. TA, MA, or Mt A usually is provided by foreign individuals, not by foreign companies. 3.14 Foreign education and Rartial affiliation with foreign comnies. The degree of influence of an owner's foreign education (FE) or partial affiliation with a foreign company (PFA) in terms of the four elements cited at the outset may be difficult to evaluate. We cannot completely ignore such influences, which may be construed as modes of collaboration. B. Foreign and Domestic Enterprise Collaboration for Export Activities--- Narrowly Defined 3.15 The criterion for narrowly defining foreign/domestic collaboration is the foreign partner's responsibility for the entire scope of (a) know-how and (b) world market access and for the entire scope or part of (c) the - 14 - capacity to package (para 3.02). Therefore, narrowly-defined foreign and domestic collaboration that meets this criterion would include FDI, joint ventures (JV), technical/marketing/management agreements (T/M/Mt Ag), and subcontracting agreements (SC). The foreign partners in these types of collaboration are usually foreign companies. 3.16 Narrowly-defined foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration in terms of the role of a recipient firm would include JV, T/M/Mt Ag, and SC, but would exclude FDI. In this paper, we use both a narrow and broad definition of foreign and domestic collaboration, depending on the focus of the discussion. C. Risk-Taking bv Foreign and Domestic Partners 3.17 As indicated in para 3.04, the distinction between Group I and Group II modes of collaboration mainly involves risk, or degree of risk. In Group I the foreign partner takes risks, in Group II the risks are reduced or non-existent. 3.18 In particular, a careful comparison of technical agreements (T Ag), marketing agreements (M Ag), or management agreements (Mt Ag) with technical consulting (TA), marketing consulting (MA), or management consulting (Mt A) is important for understanding the relative risk-taking by the foreign and domestic partners--and thus for designing a proper strategy for foreign collaboration. 3.19 In T Ag, M Ag, or Mt Ag, the foreign partner takes risks in terms of (i) relying on royalty payments that are proportional to export volume and (ii) relying on the domestic partner's compliance with contract terms, including contract duration; the domestic partner does not take risks as far as royalty payments are concerned. On the other hand, in TA, MA, or Mt A, the domestic partner takes risks in terms of having to pay fixed consulting fees - 15 - that may not be fully recovered through increased export sales; the foreign partner takes no risks since its consulting fees are fixed. Note that the foreign partner in T Ag, M Ag, or Mt Ag Is usually a foreign company, and the foreign partner in TA, MA., or Mt A is usually a foreign individual (consultant). 3.20 Within Group 1, the difference in the degree of risk-taking between a foreign trade agent (FTA) and a foreign trading company (FTC) should be noted as well. Since an FTC takes a greater risk than an FTA by taking possession of the export commodities from the local partner, an FTC can be much more aggressive about providing (a) know-how to the local partner and/or (b) access to the world market than an PTA would be. By the same token, FTC- type collaboration is much more difficult to arrange than PTA collaboration. D. Medium-to Long-Term Commitment by Foreign Partners 3.21 Since the rewards for risk-taking are royalty payments, fees, or profits proportional to export performance, there is a strong incentive on the part of the foreign partner to commit itself to best performance. Such commitment from the foreign partner is precisely what the domestic partner is looking for in certain types of foreign/domestic collaborations. However, the timeframe as well as the scope of risk-taking and the associated degree of commitment by the foreign partner vary greatly among Group I collaboration modes. 3.22 In a subcontracting agreement, the durability of the foreign partner's commitment is generally untested because these agreements usually do not last long. Unless there is a long-term contract or unless foreign partners' demands for subcontracting arrangements within a country or with a particular enterprise are extremely strong, a local partner would likely be extremely nervous about the continuity of its subcontract. This is especially - 16 - true in low-income developing countries at the early stages of their export development. 3.23 When foreign trading agents or foreign trading companies are involved, their commitment to an agreement ends as each transaction is completed; this suggests that there is no guarantee that the "access to market" intermediated by such agents is going to repeat in the next series of transactions. It is up to them to continue or discontinue their intermediation services with particular local exporters. 3.24 Compared to subcontracting agreements or agreements with foreign trading agents or trading companies, a technical/marketing/management agreement (T/M/Mt Ag) guarantees a firmer commitment by foreign partners during contract periods, which are necessarily medium term. Even though a foreign partner's overall commitment in a T/M/Mt Ag might not be as strong as in a joint venture--since there is a lack of equity--its commitment to export performance would be almost identical. Because of this necFssary commitment, as well as the associated risks that the foreign partner takes, a local firm's obtaining a T/M/Mt Ag agreement is more difficult than obtaining a SC arrangement or a transaction with an FTA or FTC. 3.25 Compared to T/M/Mt Ag (which is usually provided by a foreign company), the degree of commitment associated with technical, marketing, or management consulting (T/M/Mt A) (which is usually provided by a foreign individual) is weak, precisely because the foreign partner does not gain any extra fees nor does it take risks. 3.26 In short, once a foreign partner has decided on FDI, JV or T/M/Kt Ag, it is difficult for it to pull out of the arrangement because of the high costs entailed. Therefore, a foreign partner is more likely to be careful in making a decision to collaborate under these modes than under other modes, although local partners prefer them over all the others. Consequently, the - 17 - host country must have a well-coordinated strategy to attract and hold FDI, JV or T/M/Mt Ag arrangements. E. Gag Between Demand for. and SupplX of. Various Modes of Foreign Collaboration 3.27 In a low-income developing country, an enterprise that lacks the capacity to package as well as know-how and access to the world market would demand FDI, joint venture (JV), or technical/marketing/management agreements (T/M/Mt Ag) with reputable foreign companies. Sometimes technical agreements (T Ag), marketing agreements (M Ag) or management agreements (Mt Ag) may substitute for T/M/Mt Ag. In turn, a foreign enterprise willing to take an equity investment risk would likely supply FDI or JV, while an enterprise unwilling to take su,.h a risk would prefer T/M/Mt Ag. Although a foreign enterprise that prefers not to work with a local partner might choose FDI, a local partner is essential for T/M/Mt Ag. As indicated above, T/M/Mt Ag is not risk-free, and therefore, supplying T/M/Mt Ag would depend on the potential supplier's risk evaluation. 3.28 A local enterprise that has the capacity to package can choose a mode of foreign collaboration that will meet its demand for the "unpackaged" elements of the capacity to export as well. * If the company lacks only know-how, it might want T Ag, Mt Ag, TA, MA, or Mt A. * If it lacks only access to the world market, it might want M Ag, SC, FTA, FTC, or BL. 3.29 As indicated above, and other things being equal, an enterprise in a low-income developing country would prefer T Ag, M Ag, and Mt Ag to TA, MA and Mt A, because royalty payments for the former are what bind the foreign - 18 - partner. In fact, a foreign partner's commitment to export performance is much stronger in T Ag, M Ag, or Mt Ag arrangements. Royalty payments are self-liquidating as well. This is in the sense that the export performance (to be) generated by the service agreements would in turn pay for the service, in contrast to a firm's payments for TA, MA, or Mt A, which are unrelated to the (uncertain) export performance. 3.30 Another important element is that T Ag, M Ag, or Mt Ag agreements are usually provided by a foreign company with reputable experience and track records, but TA, MA, or Mt A can be provided by a foreign individual. This person may know a certain field well but might lack the kind of integrated expertise and experience that can be offered only by a company. 3.31 On the other hand, firms from developed countries usually prefer to supply TA, MA, and Mt A because the rewards are guaranteed no matter what the export performance of the company the consultant services. In contrast, a foreign company's rewards from supplying T Ag, N Ag, or Mt Ag are uncertain, to the extent that export performance is uncertain and the domestic partner's compliance with the contract terms is uncertain as well. Resolving these discrepancies between low-income developing country enterprises' demand preferences for specific modes of foreign collaboration, and developed country enterprises' supply preferences is the biggest challenge for designing an effective strategy for foreign collaboration. - 19 - IV. INTERVIEWS WITH EXPORTERS IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES A. Interviews With Firms 4.01 Rational&. As indicated in Chapter II, for four decades the most important development lesson has been that the dynamic externality occurring on factory floors and in firms' export sales rooms is the most important factor contributing to the superiority of an outward-oriented development strategy over an inward-oriented strategy. Therefore, quantitative and qualitative firm-level data are essential for studying the role of foreign and domestic enterprise and personal collaboration in the outward-oriented strategies of Sub-Saharan African countries. 4.02 Confidentiality. In our survey we were able to collect reasonably unbiased information (including firms' views on the difficulties they face with export policy implementation) through our promise of absolute confiden- tiality. Therefore, in this paper we have no choice but to maintain the anonymity of individual companies in our discussions of the survey results. It is also necessary to keep the individual countries unidentified whenever the discussion relates to a particular firm. B. Sample Selection 4.03 Country selection. Sample countries were chosen on the basis of whether they have manufacturing activities (i.e., predominantly agrarian countries were excluded) and whether the political situation allowed the interviewers to travel freely. The 16 countries selected were: Botswana, Burundi, C6te d'Ivoire, Ghana, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mozambique, Nigeria, Senegal, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. 4.04 Random selection of sag=le firms. The sample firms were selected randomly with respect to type of foreign/domestic collaboration (and included - 20 - firms that do not collaborate at all), the specific product coverage, firm size, export- or domestic-market orientation, and geographic/market destina- tion. An attempt was made to include both current and likely exporters of manufactured and primary resource-based (non-traditional) products. 4.05 Sample firm composition. Tables 4.1 and 4.2 show the number of sample manufacturing and primary resource-based firms selected in the 16 countries, respectively. About two-thirds (121) of the sample firms are manufacturers (including two trading companies and one maintenance company). Approximately one-third (56) of the firms are producers of non-traditional, primary resource-based goods (such as processed agriculture, processed fish, canned fruit, etc.). While more than one-tenth of the sample manufactured firms are potential exporters (i.e., those firms whose current export share in total production is zero), less than one-twentieth of the sample primary resource-based firms are potential exporters. About one-third of the total sample firms are major exporters (defined as firms that export more than half their total production to hard-currency markets). Less than two-thirds of the total firms export some of their output to regional or other soft-currency markets. C. Ouestionnaire DesiMn 4.06 The firm-level questionnaire used in the study was carefully designed, and earlier versions were tested in two previous studies, on the impact of foreign collaboration on export capacity-building in the Dominican Republic and in Mauritius during 1990. Table 4.1 AN OVERVIEW OF TYPES OF FOREIGN COLLABORATION REPORTED BY SAMPLE MANUFACTURINJ FIRMS IN 16 SU8-SMIARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES Number of Sample Firms Exporting Manuactured Produ under Given Type of Foreign CoDlaboration / Country FDI T/M/Mt Ag SC FrA/ FO LG LF DL TA/MA/MtA FE PFA NONE Total Total No.of No. of Coflabo- SUampl rationa Finn A 1 = 2 2 B 3 4 1+1' 4 1 1 7+2' 1 4 I 26+40 14+3 C 1+1 t 1 1 1 1 1 6+1' 4+2 - - - - - --- - -= = -= -- D 1I I E 1 1 3 3 1 9 6 F S 3 1 4 1+1* 1 2 1 1' 17+1* 11+2 G 3 1 _ 4 4+1* H 2 2 1 3 1 1 10 5 I 7+1 __ 2 1+2_ 9+1' 10+3'* _ 4 _1 = 5 K I 1 1 1 4 4 L 8 1 3 _ 14 12 M I 1 1 N 3 _ 2 1 3 9 5 O 8 3+1' 1 2 7 1 2 24+1B 18+10 P 1 1 1 S 2+1' 10+1 6+1' Total 39+1' 24+2' 9+1* 10 3 10 1 26+3* 3 21+10 5+1 1 1+5* 153+9' 108+13' (24%) (16%) (6%) (6%) (2%) (6%) (1%) (18%) (2%) (13%) (4%) (1%) (4%) 154+14 _ # ~~~~ - -= -j - (0) Notnelude trdh g agetts or compnies end mainftnance sauice companies. NOte: Frms Wit asteisk represet potenti alepotice (i.e, curren mpr adate=0) A AN OVBRtV1WOF1V OF FICON COLLAORAftRBPORW! BY SAL PRMAARY Re2OURCB4SD FDtS tN I6SAMANAAFRICAPCOUNntW N.mbff(S..pbFIrm Em*gPa*yOaad4nd NuaTmdblal Froaus amw Gb.,l~pa ~om(p Cla0GRANDGR ONRARAD ca, m Nv TOO As SC FrAAmc P ro w LI DL TAiAMAiA Fe WPA NONE TcA Tod 0i Ibiud PAM at "at NM. at A d l. . .c ! P ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~adoe Fkm Sdom Fao(lldaXIUZ> A I 1 1 2 3 4 S a 1 2 1 1 5 3 X14# 57+30 - _ - - - - - -= - - - - - = = = - -t C 2 2 7 4 U12.1 842' D _ 3 1 4 2 5 G 212 _ _ _ = = 2 = 1 = = a- a -- - - - -- _ - --- - - - - P S 1+2' 1+1' 12 8.2 .1'1 262 2+6. o 0 0 4 4.2'2 4 1M I 3m 3 t7St N 2 1 3 5 46 1 -N I 2 _' 3 3 23 8 a __ - _- --- -- _ - - ab z 3 1 2 2 70+ 7 a - a - -a- - - - - - - -6--- TOW 16 20+0 3 2 4 3+r O 3 O 3 8 2 O +I r7+P 54#2 2bU 1U* L )(S (2) 0+3 S f5 =*ft a - -- - 23 - 4.07 Both quantitative and qualitative information was collected through personal interviews based on the questionnaire. Eleven thematic sections comprehensively covered topics such as the contribution made by a foreign collaboration to a company's export development; human resource development; private sector development; firms' views on, and experience with, a country's export policy implementatio"; firms' desire for future foreign collaboration; and their views on the demand and supply-side constraints limiting export growth, etc. 4.08 The questionnaire was further designed to capture dynamic process- es. For instance, one section contained questions on the origin and evolution of a company's foreign/domestic collaboration, to assess whether any learning occurred within the company during the time of collaboration. Similarly, along with the collection of qualitative data, micro-level time series data were obtained as well. For instance, questions about a firm's total annual labor productivity focused on both the first year of a company's operation as well as on its current level of labor productivity. D. Carrying Out Field Interyiews 4.09 Four interviewers conducted the field interviews in the sample countries during July, August and September (1991) based on the question- naires.I' Due to limited resources for the field interviews, each inter- viewer spent about a week or 10 days in each assigned country. J Therese Belot interviewed the firms in Burundi, Madagascar, Malawi, Mozambique, and Tanzania. Katharina Katterbach interviewed the firms in Malawi, Swaziland, Uganda, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. Yung Whee Rhee interviewed the firms in Kenya. Christine Soulier interviewed the firms in Cote d'Ivore, Ghana, Nigeria, Senegal, and Togo. - 24 - E. Sapl=e Characteristics 1. Product Snecialization 4.10 Table 4.3 is a breakdown of firms' product categories. The Garments and Textiles sub-sectors together represent almost 30% of the total sample and 43% of the manufacturing sub-sample. Footwear and Leather goods is the second category in importance in manufacturing, accounting for 12% of the sample. The other manufactured goods are Household Consumer Goods, Metal Products, Packaging Materials, Machinery, etc. In the Primary Resource-Based category, Agroprocessing is the most important activity in the sample (24% of the sub-sample), followed by Fish Processing and Horticulture (8% each). The other primary resource-based (non-traditional) goods are Furniture, Fish Processing, Leather, etc. 2. Size distribution 4.11 Sample firms' size in terms of the number of employees is distrib- uted as in Table 4.4. In both the Manufacturing and the Primary Resource- Based categories, the smaller firms (1-99 and 100-199 workers) are the most represented, with 50% and 53% (combined brackets), respectively. However, about one-fifth of the manufacturing firms are very large, with their employ- ment size ranging from 1,000 to 4,400 workers. And about one-tenth of the primary resource-based firms are very large, with their employment size ranging from 1,000 to 6,000 workers. The rest of the firms are medium sized, with their employment size ranging from 200 to 1,000 verkers. Therefore, the sample is well-balanced in its composition in terms of firm size. -25- Tabe 43: PRODUCT SPECIALIZATION OF SAMPLE FiRMS Mamflnaetn,wt e~onh E(afd iradiny and mnitenanee _________________ 14. Fond imeusin@ _ 3 4 Footer and 1 pather flod t4 * (tj) 14nmktl (inmr God! ________ Maehinerv S. 4 Metal Pnductt * - Partmoing Mmmigiac Rubhnr and Plaat.c Gooeda S 4 nther Manunfachring 7 M^.aintenaneo ti Tntal Manufacturnng 1..21. 6R% Primmy rea n nn,radl iontmrn d al - - Agfunlte _6 Agm-Pmees nf 13 .24. itLh Pne R 1nn it Wkheit.y, ____i Fatbar 47. Othe otPriman, Resourcebaed_tnmductn 5 * _ Tot'al nrmrnv tureesann,-aed nrodueta _ ~ nen%. Grand Toal| 177 _____ 3. Foreign/domestic collaboration status 4.12 The types of foreign and domestic collaboration engaged in, as reported by the sample enterprises, are summarized in Annex I. Again, Tables 4.1 and 4.2 provide an overview of the types of foreign and domestic collabo- ration (including "no collaboration") for the 177 enterprises. - 26 - TabM:le sm D=STunTON OF SAML FRUMS Employment wat to of m (9r 100040 18 (18% 00- 999 is 01) 200- 499 18 (18%) 10O 199 2 1 % 1-99 29 ) TOWal 101 (100%) Pmy ReouraA ____ _ 1000-400 S IM SOO- 99 6 (14%) 200- 49 9 1*) 1'i00- 49 _1_ (29s, 1 99 1 _ __ _ _ __ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ 22 (51%) | TOWal 43 100%* SE_ no_ a_ _l _ 33 LG=nd toW ~~~~~177 4.13 Our firms reported 218 cases of various types of collaboration, suggesting on average 1.2 foreign collaboration arrangements per sample firm (see Total in Table 4.2). Among the manufacturing firms, 121 reported a total of 162 cases of foreign collaboration, indicating 1.3 on average per sample firm. In turn, 56 exporters of primary resource-based (non-traditional) products reported 57 examples of foreign collaboration, showing 1 on average for each firm. 4.14 The five most important types of foreign collaboration for manufactured exports (including for potential export) were reported (in order of importance) to be: (i) FDI; (ii) "localized" foreigners' family legacy (LF); (iii) joint venture (JV); (iv) technical consulting/marketing consult- ing/management consulting (TA/NA/Mt A); (v) sub-contracting (SC), technical/- - 27 - marketing/management agreements (T/I/Mt Ag), or a foreign company's orlginal establishment (FO). In comparlson, the five most lmportant types of foreign collaboratlon for primary resource-based (non-traditional) export (including po ential export) activities were reported, in order of importance, as: (i) joint ventures (JV); (ii) FDI; (iii) "no collaboration"; (iv) foreign trade agents/foreign trading companies (FTA/FTC); (v) a foreign company"s original establishment (PO). 4. Origin of Foreign/Domestic Collaboration 4.15 As Table 9.1 in Chapter IX shows, France and the U.K.--the former major colonial countries in West Africa and in East and Southern Africa, respectively--are the most important source countries for the different modes of collaboration in Sub-Saharan Africa. For instance, France accounts for 250 of the total FDI and JV, and the U.K. for 20%. For all modes of collabo- ration, France provides 20% and the U.K. 15%. The other important source countries are, first, India, then Lebanon. For these two, the most important collaboration mode is that of "localized foreigner" (defined in Chapter III). The U.S., Japan, and Germany account for a total of only 10% of all for- eign/domestic collaboration in Sub-Saharan Africa. Three Esst Asian coun- tries, namely, Hong Kong, Taiwan and Korea, together account for a share of 4a. - 28 - V. CONTRIBUTION OF FOREIGN/DOMESTIC EXPORT COLLABORATION TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN DEVELOPMENT A. Contribution to Export Development 1. Foreign Cgollaboration as Necessayl Condition 5.01 Manufactuaed egtorts. All 108 of our sample export manufacturers (except for one) reported at least one engagement in foreign collaboration, as shown in Table 4.1. This confirms that even some sort of broadly-defined foreign collaboration is a necessary condition for manufactured-export activity in Sub-Saharan African countries. Furthermore, five of the six manufacturing firms that did not engage in any foreign collaboration were unable to export their products, again as seen from Table 4.1, thus rein- forcing the above inference. (However, foreign collaboration alone is not a sufficient condition for successful manufactured-exports activity, as evident in the fact that eight of the sample manufacturing firms were unable to export their products even when they were partners in some type of foreign collabo- ration.) 5.02 Primary resource-based (non-traditional) exports. The case for these exporters is somewhat different from that of the manufacturing export- ers. Eight firms out of 54 (i.e., about 15%) were able to export without needing any foreign collaboration, while the other 46 exported under some type of broadly-defined foreign collaboration (Table 4.2). This suggests that even though foreign collaboration is not necessarily an absolute essential for certain primary resource-based (non-traditional) export activities or enter- prises, its role is significant in these activities nonetheless. - 29 2. Fims Exort Performance and Foreign Collaboration 5.03 To infer a rough relationship between foreign collaboration and export performance, we employ a four-way classification of manufacturing and primary resource-based firms in Table 5.1 and Table 5.2, respectively. The classifications are: (a) firms exporting 50% or more of their products * (i) established before 1985 * (ii) established in or after 1985; (b) firms exporting less than 50% of their products * (i) established before 1985 * (ii) established in or after 1985. (a) Aerage Number of Broadly-Defined Foreign Collaboration Cases 5.04 Potential extorters. On the one hand, the number of broadly- defined foreign collaboration cases per non-exnorting firm (i.e., potential exporters) is nearly zero for both manufactured and primary resource-based (non-traditional) export industries (the exceptions are one manufacturing firm and one primary resource-based firm). See bracketed figures with single asterisks in Table 5.1 and Table 5.2. 5.05 Aial *xDorters. On the other hand, the number of broadly- defined foreign collaboration cases per exDorting sample firm is much higher than one, is one, or is very close to one, whatever percentage of their products the firms export. Tdb * RELAIiON ElWIVBT 1OFUFOREIPO COtUBOION AND D1OU OP WCORT4)ROEIAION IN tNACIUrlt EXPORT FDI JY WA SC FTAIIC PO I4 LI 1IL TAMV fE PP A N01ON Td Ta d AdIN A$ Egm soW Wm or am ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ Et N.d Wa ..d m - " 4 2 - 2 , - -t - - MOsmbZ E i sh1INS 4 t 7 t 2 4 1 32 2S U Ll (") (29 (") On ()(2") (.") (PO) (23") (139 019 W ~ - - - - - - -_ i buim" bdaU 1 7 a2 3 I I 2 13 8 2 0 i 4 LI .___________________ ._____ _ (1r) ( ) (t) (2) _ _ ) ( ) e) (V) (IV) (0P) 0.3) (0) Bam k b oraer S M 2 3 3 4 7 2 3 1 #4 17 L S ._________________ (F) _F) (F) (10') (t2) O Toed 14g 23 . t 2 S t 22 3 19 4 3 * U44 206s Ui t7_ Todn N.br n_t bi t d _ _d to65 a Ii "am aw0do4 asudbdob. r* W1amkdmmWOimIas..uiqatb Nr ib.mdiadqs _qnmabab Ill ha-_d_ is 16am _a bpel * amba m cpe madw l [ X S- *--3 - - iI A.|w - Z 3- -' a IiSI 9- _~ __ __ _ ifg t~~ w _-" ! in_ __i ___}l et _ _ - - i _ __ _il ; _ _3 35 _______ I - - - 4 - 32 - 5.06 Manufacturing vs. Primar= resource-based sxnorts. While the average number of broadly-defined foreign collaboration arrangements for manufacturing export industries is 1.3 (Table 5.1), for primary resource-based (non-traditional) export industries the average number is 1.0 (Table 5.2). (b) Average Number of Narrowlv-Defined Foreign Collaboration Cases 5.07 Exporting (manufacturing) more than 50% vs. less than 50%. Under the concept of narrowly-defined foreign collaboration, the impact of foreign collaboration on export performance appears more notable for manufactured exports. While the number of such collaboration cases per sample manufactur- ing firm exporting 50% or more of its products is close to one, the number per firm exporting less than 50% of its products is just 0.5 (Table 5.1). The main reason for not finding a similar t.ifference for primary resource-based firms (Table 5.2) appears to be that jost of them export 100% of their products. 5.08 ExDorting 100% vs. less than 100%. Furthermore, the number of narrowly-defined collaboration arrangements per sample firm that exports 100% of its products (whether manufacturing or primary resource-based) is consis- tently higher than the number for firms that export less than 100% of their products, as shown in Table 5.1 and Table 5.2. (see bracketed figures with double asterisks.) 5.09 Manufacturing vs. _rimarv resource-based. Note.that the average number of cases of narrowly-defined foreign collaboration for export manufac- turing industries (0.7 in Table 5.1) is identical to that for primary re- source-based industries (Table 5.2), in contrast to the respective numbers for broadly-defined foreign collaboration (see para 5.06). 5.10 In fact, the differences between the manufacturing and primary resource-based export industries--in the gap between the average number of - 33 - broadly-defined collaborations and the average number of narrowly-defined collaborations (Table 5.1 and 5.2)--merely confirm that manufacturing firms unable to participate in narrowly-defined foreign collaboration have depended on the other types of foreign collaboration more extensively than have primary resource-based firms. 5.11 Although only 44% of our sample manufacturing firms exported more than half of their products, 84% of the primary resource-based firms did so. In fact, most of these primary resource-based firms are 100%-exporters, while less than a third of the manufacturing firms that export 50% or more of their output are 100%-exporters. This confirms the stronger export orientation of the primary resource-based industries. 5.12 Only 35% of the sample manufacturing firms that were established before 1985 exported 50% or more of their products, but 60% of those set up since 1985 did so. For primary resource-based firms established before 1985, 83% exported at least half their output, and 93% of those established in or after 1985 exported at least half their products. This underscores that firms established post-1985 are more export oriented than the older firms. 5.13 The impact of a firm's age appears to be concealed by the broad aggregation employed for discerning the relationship between foreign collabo- ration and export performance. However, for manufacturers established from 1985 onwards and exporting less than 50% of their products, the average number of broadly-defined foreign collaboration arrangements is higher than the number for firms established before 1985. This suggests that younger firms tend to promote more broadly-defined collaboration. Furthermore, for 100%- export-oriented manufacturing firms set up since 1985, the average number of both broadly-defined and narrowly-defined collaborative arrangements is considerably higher than for firms established before 1985. Again this suggests that the younger firms are more eager to exploit the potential gains from both narrowly- and broadly-defined foreign collaboration. 34- - 3. A Few Illustrations 5.14 Country J. Six out of the seven sample firms (which are FDI or joint-venture firms established in the latter half of the 1980s) have pio- neered exports of their respective products by bringing into Country J all the elements of the capacity to export (para. 4.02). A welding electrode manufac- turer, a medium-sized family enterprise, for instance, had 40 years of experience in South Africa before starting operations in Country J. Most of the other sample firms had similarly solid track records in their other production locations and brought this experience to country J. 5.15 The following example illustrates the catalytic role of foreign collaborators in Country J. The former production manager of a pioneering furniture exporter recently established a new furniture-for-export manufac- turing unit in a very depressed rural area. This company is now providing employment for 180 workers who would otherwise have been unemployed. The firm uses timber from an adjacent sawmill and is thus an example of successful vertical integration and foreign-exchange generation based on local resources. The value-added of exporting furniture rather than timber is 100% per cubic meter in this case. Foreign managers remarked that in the mid-1980s Country J's entrepreneurial initiative and experience in manufacturing and non- traditional exporting virtually did not exist. Thus, the most important elements that the foreign investors brought to their new operation in the country were, first, the capacity to package managerial, technical and marketing know-how with local factors of production, and, second, access to the external market network. Financial resources were perceived as of secondary importance in building this capacity to export. 5.16 Country G. Another example can be found in Country G. Only three companies (established in the late 1970s or in the 1980s through FDI) out of the five firms interviewed in Country G were able to export 80-90% of their manufactured products from the country. Their exports of garments, plastics, - 35 - and pump parts could never have been initiated without the whole package of elements for the capacity to export (para. 4.02), which is wbat the three parent companies brought into the country. B. Contribution to Human Resource Develogment 1. On-the-job training and learning-by-doing 5.17 Virtually all workers we interviewed in export manufacturing firms were recruited by their companies from the unskilled worker pools. All the sample firms invested in on-the-job training for their indigenous workers; and after on-the-job training, workers acquire further skills through learning-by- doing. For example, a tool manufacturer in Country J apprentices welders for one year; welders then spend up to two years in learning-by-doing before they move to the next skill level. 5.18 The average on-the-job training period in export sanufacturing companies was three months; the average minimum learning-by-doing period (to become a semi-skilled worker) was six months for such skills as tack welding or cutting, stitching, and making of shoes. Of course, learning-by-doing continues after workers become semi-skilled, if only to enable them to become skilled workers and then supervisors. Supervisors (indigenous staff) in the sample firms had an average of four to seven years of experience with their firms. Four of the seven sample firms in Country J reported that they send workers at the supervisory level abroad for training: e.g., four-week machine training at a German factory that manufactures for the European market; three- week training with an affiliated shoe manufacturer in Zimbabwe and in the main plant in South Africa for employees to learn complementary production process- es and quality control at each site, respectively. - 36 - 2. Labor Productivity and Real Wage Changes 5.19 Exporters interviewed in Country J stated that during the five years (on average) since start-up, their labor productivity had increased from a base of 50% of the average level of productivity in comparable South African export enterprises to the current level of 70%. This confirms the impressive aggregate impact of human resource development on industrial efficiency through on-the-job training and learning-by-doing in foreign collaborator- operated factories. Another indication of human resource development on the factory floors of firms engaged in foreign collaboration is the superior level of their wages. In the sample firms in Country J, wages are about 60% higher than the minimum wage. 5.20 The two exporters (operating with FDI) interviewed in Country G were also able to compare the level of labor productivity in their companies favorably with that in industrialized countries. In each case, productivity had increased quite significantly through on-the-job training and learning-by- doing. While initially labor productivity was between 30-40% of that in Europe, it was now estimated to be between 60-70%. This showed that the labor productivity improvements during the five years of learning-by-doing and on- the-job training with the foreign-collaboration companies in Country J, as noted above, were not isolated cases. 5.21 One 100%-export-oriented garment manufacturing firm in Country B (with FDI from Sri Lanka) reported that the impact on labor productivity of the well organized on-the-job training and learning-by-doing, under the guidance of the Sri Lankan textile manager and engineer, had been more than impressive. The labor productivity level of this factory had even surpassed that of the best performing garment export manufacturing factory in Sri Lanka after just one year of operation. (Sri Lanka has built a reputation as one of the major competitors in the world market.) This is evidence of the untapped - 37 - potential of Africa's export manufacturing, a potential that can be plumbed only by collaborative efforts with first-rate foreign companies. C. Contribution to Private Sector Development 1. Private vs. Public Ownersgh ogf Eport Businesses 5.22, Table 5.3 shows that the ownership of less than one-tenth of the 165 surveyed enterprises (those that reported the ownership status of their domestic partners) is 100% public or partly public (i.e., public corporations have joint-venture agreements with foreign private companies). This suggests that in 1991 the manufacturing and primary resource-based export businesses in most Sub-Saharan African countries are dominated by foreign and domestic private enterprises. (In several countries that have pursued state enter- prise-dominated industrial strategies, efforts are underway to restructure public export enterprises as part of the countries' privatization programs, which are supported by the World Bank.) 2. Comnetitive Edge: Key for Private Sector Develogment 5.23 As discussed above, Sub-Saharan African countries would not have been able to build even their meager capacity to compete in the world market without their local companies' collaboration with foreign private companies and personnel--even though foreign collaboration alone has not been a suffi- cient condition for achieving a competitive edge in some African countries (as further elaborated in Chapter VI). Tse S3 PRIVATE v& PUBLIC OWNERSHIP OF SAMPLE ENTERPRISES (Number of fim) COUnuty 100% domestic Joiolt maehip between 10 feiCO 3oint ownership betwee 100% domestc Ownenbip stat Tottd pdiwae domestc pdvate sad pdvaft owanhip fxoeip prate and public of domestn pner oNXWershp forei prte (mW) (PDI) dometi puwb (V) Owneip no known _ A 0 0 0 0 3 2# S a0 1 4 4 2 0 0 C 6 0 4 0 0 0 10 o S 0 0 0 0 0 5 E 6 1 1 0 0 0 8 F 3 10 2 0 1 23 O 2 0 3 0 0 0 S H 3 2 4 1 0 0 10 1 6 1 1 0 0 9 17 c 3 0 2 S 0 0 0 1 . IK S 2 0 0 0 0 7 L 3 2 9 0 1 0 iS M 1 1 3 0 0 0 S N 1 0 4 1 2 0 8 7 5 9 3 0 0 2l P 6 1 0 0 0 0 7 TOel 70 24 S6 9 6 12 177 (42%) (15%) (34%) (5%) (4%) 163 (100%) o Joint ownerhp Wi forein prae pte 0) - 39 - 5.24 By the same token, any effort to develop the private sector in the Sub-Saharan African countries would not be effective without continuing the change toward outward-oriented development strategies. To that end, the agent for a country's outward-oriented strategy is an individual firm that is acquiring the capacity to compete in the world market. Therefore, foreign/- domestic enterprise collaboration in export activities plays a catalytic role in the private sector development of Sub-Saharan African countries. 3. Labor Mobility and Inter-Firm SkiLl Transer, 5.25 Skill transfer among firms in an industry occurs if the inward and outward mobility of workers who have acquired skills in companies with foreign collaboration is extensive. One company in Country J reported that two of its most skilled workers--who had worked under the guidance of expatriate manag- ers--left the company and started a successful fence-making operation for the local market. 5.26 However, most sample firms reported very little outward mobility of skilled workers from their factories (the labor turnover rate is extremely low, not more than 2-5% a year). With very high unemployment, workers may not want to leave their current jobs unless forced to do so. Such limited mobility appears to limit inter-firm skill transfer in the industrial activi- ties of the Sub-Saharan African countries. - 40 - VI. THE LEGACY FROM INWARD-ORIENTED FOREIGN COLLABORATORS vs. THE NEW BREED OF OUTWARD-ORIENTED FOREIGN COLLABORATORS 6.01 Chapter V examined the contribution of foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration to Sub-Saharan African development in general, without distinguishing among the different types and qualities of foreign collaborators. Even if all foreign collaborators made positive contributions by merely being involved in some export activities, the contributions here not of uniform quality. Especially in designing an effective strategy for future foreign collaboration, one must be able to sort out the superior foreign collaborators from the less effective ones. Therefore, this chapter attempts to draw lessons from past experience with various types of foreign collabora- tors. A. Distinction Between Outward-Oriented and Inward-Oriented Foreign Collaborators 6.02 Access to the world market. At the outset (para. 3.03) we stressed that the ultimate contribution of foreign collaboration to develop- ment should be judged by the quality and depth of elements (know-how, access to the world market, capacity to package, and capital) that a foreign partner brings in to a country. We should also judge these elements' impact on the implementation of an outward-oriented industrial development strategy. The most critical element here is access to the world market, without which a foreign partner barely contributes at all to outward-oriented development. 6.03 Access to the domestic market. Although a foreign partner brings know-how and capital to the collaboration, if it is primarily interested in having access to the domestic market in a targeted country, it will neglect to bring in the other critical elements. Consequently, its contribution to the country's outward-oriented development strategy will be insignificant. (This does not imply that efficient import substitution is not as important as - 41 - efficient exporting. Instead, the development lesson of the last four decades suggests that outward-orientation is the way to make import substitution efficient.) 6.04 ELrm s.I1. In distinguishing between outward-oriented and inward- oriented foreign collaborators, based on their market-orientation, the size of a firm cannot be overlooked. Therefore, we classified sample firms in both the manufactured and primary resource-based (non-traditional) export indus- tries into five sizes, according to their number of employees: (i) large (employ more than 1,000); (ii) medium size II (employ between 500 and 999); (iii) medium size I (employ between 200 and 499); (iv) small size II (employ between 100 and 199); (v) small size I (employ fewer than 100). B. Survey Results of Manufacturing Exoorters 6.05 Table 6.1. The share of exports (in the total production of each firm) in two separate external markets (non-regional hard-currency market and regional or non-hard-currency market) is shown for manufacturing enterprises in the five categories. Table 6.1 also shows the external market destination, share of exports (in total production), and types of foreign collaboration. 6.06 TabLe 6.2. The export-share data in Table 6.1 are aggregated in this table to classify the market orientation of the sample manufacturing firms in the five categories: TW4 SBOUFOS8NONUA3OA11OFO MAMIAcIIiRINFO W%1 ~M4SILW .saiagd4 inkqdmp N cpNo ed Prm Ma t I el Pm0 u aC s" t"-Ct I Ci( I M wdFtsapNo n- ul Ne*6d lmw Nod ft(S) N&_ _ _ he mica hanp cob. hao eoagbo, ha eagle. leep eoglo, lea gge,o ha rode,w ha- melon -p- Cobe* QC l U S I IN I# _ 4I. I 2__86 3 _ FDI 0 0 0 1 IN _ SIN a (US) 440 1U 1__ TA A11 _ IMiA IL? FTAk 2F0 . o) __ _-) 1*) _ _-o) ____ _ ___ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~(C) =1 __ (M) (US) M1%) (W*) (0) (0_ ) () ) - b Medkm du 588499 2 LIV) a I TOM 0 0 3 IfDI 2 I POL 3 1JlI 0 3 SlY; Is (*45) 11)1 I? I SV) 21mg 118 11V6 Fo AS I1.% ISC. isc AS; IL? I1'- IIU 2 TA; I 2L? T"K _ U _ 4 s _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ "4 {}~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~irsAP (US) o(wS) (0) _ ) _ % (S __ ) _ 0) ) _ ) # ~ - - -- _ d _ _ _____ - - a Mom= du 0049 0 1 IL? I 1Pm 0 7 SF60; 1 2PFM 0 4 2 DL. s 291 19 CM8) I TA; It# STA- 211 ______ (0~ ~ ~~~~) (IS) M55 O)(1)_ _(%) (0))(21) (20)(25 A Sinelef go a 23 3 2 I 1Mm 0 0 8 410% I I FIX I 2911 3 1906 S I Fat 21 (M%) IL? 1SC~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 1 ITA; AS I TA, IpFA 134 (255) aIs)() (0*) (US)_0(5) (M0) (155) (1)(0 .6SIiNaO 249I S I I Fs 2 1106 0 s 3160 4 SUF 4 1FV6 1 1Pm S IPDm 3 (US) Mere IF INV I M. IM. IFOL IS4 tA- - (175) - ~~~~(15 ()() (US5) on5) (1to) - (5 1% 1 (III) ~~~(OS) (4)(% 1% %) ) (0 (,)(2)(0) 'l. .im~et nu0gdfi.mtmudebn11.%7bwftva*ommmtntdskIe C eOqtm - 43 - (i) super outward-oriented firms (export more than 75% of their products to the non-regional hard currency markets); (ii) highly outward-oriented firms (export more than 75% of their products); (iii) outward-oriented firms (export more than 50% of their products); (iv) inward-oriented firms (export less than 50% of their products); and (v) highly inward-oriented firms (sell more than 75% of their products to the domestic market). The average number of "narrowly-defined" foreign collaborations and the average year of establishment for firms in these categories firms are present- ed in Table 6.2 as well. T" PSMrBWAMOSUOt'AWZMA1ACIIJRIO l'RhSKOIG 1703 FWDMrMAIIFRWWA1NCA1EGOU l.9ff &u~delgd HIbb.~ Omi.wd.dieci &W .ow bd bms I w Phaik Safftwomfff %d e 6 * d Av_ __ A_ _ %o Aw.pn Awig %ctmaI. am *a 5 d "chtfW &M d=ma* Per flu dwra* cti lt4oman prod to ac4ei Oc tbn dd*Wtr. at*sb ddeWd Orm a_bU- 75% dp*od 1bad annaA. 755 c9 etishb- mRut m4 cdwao (t) LUg sze 0% _3% 0.7 1962 84% LO 1u (b) Mdiio asi U 20% 53% 53% 13 1971 47% 67 196 40* (c) Mdi.eLi am I 7 42% 42% Lo0 TM6 so% Os5 197 1% (|) sow do a 30* 3D% 45 . 8" % 7 4% (.) sd gIb I 10% 30% 43% Lo0 196 57% @3193 3 6.07 In the sample, although almost half the medium- and small-size manufacturing enterprises are outward-oriented, far less than one-fifth of the large-size enterprises are outward-oriented, again as shown in Table 6.2. Furthermore, there is no single large-size firm in our sample that can be classified as "super" or "highly outward-oriented", even though, on average, e44- about one-fourth or one-third of the small- or medium-size manufacturing firms are classified as "super" or "highly outward-oriented", as shown in Table 6.2. 1. High Inward-Orientation of Large Manufacturing Enterprises with Foreign Collaboration 6.08 In our sample, about three-quarters of the largest manufacturing firms are highly inward-oriented (Table 6.2). However, more notable than the relatively higher share of such firms compared to small- or medium-size firms is the heavier involvement of foreign collaborators in the larger firms than in the small- or medium-size firms. The average number of "narrowly-defined" foreign collaboration arrangements for the large firms classified as inward- oriented is one, whereas the corresponding figure for small- and medium-size firms is 0.5. 6.09 It is apparent that the inward-orientation of part of the small- and medium-size manufacturing firms may be due to their lack of capacity to export, as reflected by their insufficient foreign collaboration status. However, the majority of the sample's large-size manufacturing firms are highly inward-oriented as well, despite their extensive foreign collaboration. Thus, the inward-orientation of the large firms is not due to lack of foreign collaboration but results from their intention to stay mainly in the domestic market. 6.10 The year of establishment for each of the large manufacturing firms was generally in the early 1960s. This suggests a need to examine the historical background of foreign companies' involvement with manufacturing industries in Sub-Saharan African countries. This would help us understand the characteristics of the highly inward-oriented large-size manufacturing enterprises that nonetheless engage in extensive foreign collaboration. - 45 - 6.11 For example, in Country F, Company No. 20 (established originally in 1929) has 2,000 workers; and in Country B, Company No. 7 has 1,500 workers. Both companies were set up by European MNCs as JVs with state companies. They have produced detergents, cosmetics, and processed food items (such as cereals and cooking oils) primarily for the local market. Currently they are export- ing a small fraction of their production to the regional market. These countriss do not appear to have a comparative advantage in the hard-currency world market in these products, even though their MNC partners are leading producers of those consumer items. 6.12 Another example of inward-oriented MNCs is Company No. 20 in Country B (set up by a leading MNC in 1946 through FDI) with 1,900 workers producing shoes strictly for the local market. The company has no incentive to export even to the regional market, because the MNC has factories in many African countries and around the world. 6.13 One more example of the legacy of inward-oriented MNCs is Company No. 2 in Country F (established as a French firm's JV with the state company in 1922), with 1,000 workers producing textiles for the domestic market. Only recently has the company exported a small fraction of its product, starting with the regional market. Many FDI and JV companies from the former colonial powers and from other European countries (see Table 9.1) belong in this category. The lesson they impart is that future African development strate- gies cannot rely on inward-oriented MNCs' initiatives. In fact, it does not appear that large size MNCs will be newly interested in most African manufac- turing activities (whether export-oriented or domestic market-oriented) in a near future, because they may have the better alternative locations around the world. In turn, no one can deny that the high inward-orientation of the large size manufacturing MNCs has contributed to African policy makers' negative perception on them. However, such negative perception on the inward-oriented MNCs should never lead to wrong inference that most Sub-Saharan African countries can and should build their capacity to export without foreign - 46 - collaboration. Rather, the perception reinforces the need to bring a new breed of outward-oriented foreign collaborators. 2. Significant Outward-Orientation of the New Breed of Small-I and Medium-Size Manufacturing Enterprises with Foreign Collaboration 6.14 It is remarkable that about half the small- and medium-size manufacturing firms surveyed are outward-oriented (see Table 6.2). It is clear that this significant outward-orientation could not be possible without extensive foreign collaboration; this is indicated by the average number of "narrowly-defined" foreign collaboration arrangements, which is larger than one. This inference is reinforced by the fact that the average number of "narrowly-defined" foreign collaboration cases for inward-oriented small- and medium-size manufacturing firms is 0.5--just half that for similar-size but outward-oriented firms. 6.15 It also should be noted that the average year of establishment of the outward-oriented small- and medium-size manufacturing firms is consistent- ly more recent (1970s-early 1980s) than for their inward-oriented counter- parts. This suggests that the recentness of their establishment is a factor that contributes to these firms' outlook--important information that will be critical in designing an effective strategy to promote the inflow of new foreign collaborators. 6.16 For example, Company No. 11 in Country L, established in 1990 under FDI from Hong Kong, and now with 100 workers producing garments, reported that it will soon be 10OS-exporting to the U.S. market. Similarly, the three 100%-export-oriented garment firms in Country B were established around 1989-90 with FDI from Sri Lanka or with technical consulting from Sri Lanka and sub-contracting agreements with U.S. buyers. Their number of workers ranges from 220 to 350. This new breed of small- and medium-size firm that collaborates and is "super export-oriented" should be the model on - 47 which to base a future strategy to foster foreign collaboration for export development in Africa. C. Survey -Results. of PriMary Regource-EAaeg1 (Ngj3-TrAditiona1) C. _L*XA 9;SRortIrI 6.17 Table 6.. The share of exports (in the total production of each firm) in two separate external markets (non-regional hard-currency market and regional or non-hard-currency market) is shown for primary resource-based enterprises in the five firm-size categories. The table also shows the external market destination, share of exports (in total production), and types of foreign collaboration. Ltal 4* SRCBNAOESOPSAMUPBRIMAAY RUOURCS.SAS5WFIMS TBOEIO�O FMV DIFFERET MARXff ROBjlAI1OCNCA1GOMSI Saer 9umd4demd HVaaL. O _=u. _Aftdaged DM HW&*- &a wd-aeSme SDM * i mapodum WM. t 30* dl eit nheu %c at&uqS4POM *at&= %at Awrpam Av*W SO AN.pua Ame_ *ot&=ad. mom tdu 79 at cmfu &M ctmawl yiot am etmt yea dlag mm ds _uan toaoe.paa more she. datas flar inFl ddm0d61F hr. ua*b 5* dpe_m I__ . _ , _ ae _ . F"" &C- -mm WW O -t& 'R - -W *b W p* (a) Lrpe a an 80* I100* LO M. 9 0* * * (b)me&= I0* 50 7 0 4* to _7 us (p) Mosam ala 1 67* 6* 3 0. 194 11% Oa7 VsU 11 I(d) Sal alsI 0* 190 1X0 1.0 39 0* * (.)Saialwl ~73 am* 91* V. 10 9 0.5 197 9* = -�sd - r - - ms -1 ---. _ _ . 6.18 table 6.4. The export-share data in Table 6.3 are here aggregated to classify the market orientation of the sample primary resource-based firms in five categories, Just as was done in Table 6.2 for manufacturing firms. Also, the average number of "narrowly-defined" foreign collaborations and the average year of establishment for firms in the five categories are presented. Tahik ss oSE OPFoREIG aOU ORAIiOI FOR PRMAaRY RPSOUtCS-MASED (NOt.hVIRAlOtAL) EXFOR. nls 1 m f iward-od u a eaMOIpth 8Ron la's b Shm far m tpo amqdeo*ml hu x mdnaqutak I cin W ACD (I) Shutofe*m toi reslou or oaobvd a mq mutca m acidesu (%) 5ea ou pj y a Md " S(4) _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ __TOW _ 1.2$ _6.so 51-75 76S0 -00.76 1 50-26 2_ .1 Ntoi FOaOP No,d a Fordgo Mooroi5 NMo t Forep oaot Fornp Hot ForIp N&o t F_od "oo pomp Not d Ftrclp No Fd (S) camp* agebi* co"a eato ompmn *Wbo woom ci&gbo co .pam i cm ocoysa m0w oaw oot Comm 4d ocm al*e ,XtO t 0 0 0 1 4 4 2 FDk 0 0 0 0 � (11%) 2 N bMeiamadoeM s00W I lIW. I IN I I M_ 3 1 M 0 J 0 0 6 (U4) I FO ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~IMAP - % (u) __ (17%) _ ) ) - ($_ ) (OS) (0a) , (0*) (OS) (100%) oMoiua A I 2009 0 M FDI 0 0 1 N 6 I N; t I INOA 0 a 0 9 (1%) 3 MV; 2 FOM 2 M,A IFF _________ (0%) ____ 211$) I0sO (11%) (6OS) - (11%) %) %) (0%) (1) % a Smadaf 100160mi 0 0 0 0 I 1 FDI 0 0 0 0 I (% ._____ (OS) ___ "(0) (/) (0%) (_00%) () (O (OS) ("M) SWA AN1 t 10 I I NHim I I P OS 0 2 1 FM 16 4P01; 2 I PDN 0 22 (510) 102 4 M. I N AS; t TA I PTA; .LP. mNw ______ (5%) (5%) - (0%) - (9%) - (71%) (9%) (0%0 ___ (0%) _0) _ 1%3 _ IUFAL 2 3 0 5 30 3 0 0 0 a (0% ______~ __ (5%) (7%) = % (12%) (0) (7%) (0%) = =(0%) _ s ....................) (l00t) # ~~ - =* = = = -= -= -= = = = - - = * = - = -ade= - 49 - 6.19 The primary resource-based firms in all size categories are consistently more outward-oriented than are the manufacturing firms. In particular, the large-size primary resource-based firms are "highly outward- oriented". While African countries do not have much comparative advantage in those manufactured products that the large-size highly inward-oriented foreign collaboration firms specialize in, most of the primary resource-based products show Africa's comparative advantage, no matter what the size of the firms. 6.20 Even though the average year of establishment for the large primary resource-based firms (those with extensive foreign collaboration) was in the 1960s, there does not appear to be a legacy of inward-orientation such as is found among the large manufacturing firms. This again confirms the comparative advantage of primary resource-based (non-traditional) exporr items. 6.21 In general, "narrowly-defined" foreign collaboration appears to be more common for the outward-oriented primary resource-based firms than for the small segment of inward-oriented firms. Note also that the average year of establishment for the outward-oriented firms is more recent than for the inward-oriented firms. As with their manufacturing counterparts, the recent- ness of their establishment probably contributes to these firms' outward orientation. Again, this information will be critical in designing an effective strategy to promote the inflow of foreign collaborators. 6.22 In any event, while the comparative advantages of primary re- source-based non-traditional export items are being exploited, opportunities for exploiting Africa's comparative advantages in manufactured goods based on primary resources (such as leather garment exports rather than raw leather exports) should not be lost. For the transformation from mere primary processing to more value-added manufacturing for certain products, foreign collaboration, is of course, critical. Furthermore, the critical elements (for the capacity to export) that local partners in manufacturing industries 50 - seek from foreign partners are: the whole package of know-how, access to the world market, and capacity to package (along with financLal resources); those that local partners in the primary resource-based industries seek from foreign partners are primarily access to the world market and financial resources. - 51 - VII. MAJOR FACTORS CONSTRAINING SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN COUNTRIES' EXPORT EXPANSION 7.01 In the previous chapters, we reviewed the current status of foreign and domestic collaboration in manufactured and primary resourc3-based export industries in Sub-Saharan Africa. Based on the firm-level interview results, our review provides an analytical and emnirical underpinning for an effective future strategy for foreign collaboration in export activities. 7.02 To examine the overall issues related to future strategies for export development in these countries, the interview questionnaires asked about the major factors constraining export growth. Table 7.1 summarizes the sample firms' evaluation of these factors. Table 7.1: SAMPLE FIRMS' EVALUATION OF MAJOR FACTORS CONSTRAINING SUB-AHARAN APRICAN COUNTRIS' EKPORT GROWTH COUNTRY MAJOR SUPPLY SIDE CONSTRAINTS MAJOR DEMAND SIDE CONST- I________ (in order of Importance) RAIS (in order of Imptance) 1. Botwn (i) Lack of marketing capacity (especally European market) on (i) DiMcuhy in apoxs to South Afri- the part of edating apore (u) lack of capacity to packge all ca due to their compeioa () diic- the elemets needed to enter the word market on the part of aity In aprt to Zimbabwe due to the potential ;poras; (iu) Inadequate ac0C to trade and Iest- se foreigp ace sht ment finance; (iv) worker inefUden, (v) high feight cosla 2 Burundl (i) Lack of ia re capacity; (ii) lack of ernal (i) Other LDC cmpetlo (II) fc- market link; (Hi) inadequate trade Infastructure; (iv) diffcu- rading taiff and non4ariff baies Ities in having access to finance; (v) ising wage coss witthi the PTA and COEL3 trade 3. Cote d'hoire (i) High poducon cost caued by higb energ, water, labor, (I) Lac of sb.eolaa n atbuti intennediate inputs, harbor, and administrative cost, (ii) fal- (U) snuggog; (iU) compee edge Of utre to compeate for curency overvalution, failure to ensurm other LDCa froe trade status, failure to esure compeithv labor costs, and faidlure to ensure acos to financing (IH) lack of maketing capaciy; (v) inconsistnt policies and implementation Ailur 4. Ghana () Lak of capacty to aport; (i) non-eay access to financing; ompettive edge of other LDCa (ili) lack of commitment to induce foreign coaborafin; (lv)- lack of efective match-making medhanms (v) lack of equal footing apon poiWs S. Kea (i) LAck of capacty to apart; (Ii) no effectei match-making Competitive edge of other LDCa mechaim to locate foreign collaborteto; (1i) Ineffecttiv I_pnetatio of apart policies ( ulal =som rd tape and delays); (Fv) lack of commlentbyoafidL 52 - 6. Madasar (i) LACk of te apacitr, (i) lack of information While garment exponers face few con. about eamer markets; (Ui) not easy acess to trade and inves- straint, tetile exporters concemn Asian meat finance; (iv) inadequate trade infrstmrtureu (v) laCk of competition. Some agroindustries fear management capacity. Latin American competition in the Eu- ropean market. 7. Maladi (i) Lack of techcicslfting capacity, (U) lack of market (i) Regonal tade bait witoin the link; (ill) high trnsport costs; (iv) diMculty in having access to PTA ountries (such as Zimbabwe) finance. (i Asisq competition in gar- menVtatile exportI Moambique (i) Unstable poltial enwironment; (U) lack of capacity to (i) CompUtive edge of other LDCs; apout; (ill) difficulty in having somss to financing; (nv) failure (i) trade barrien witin PTA cu- to bave timely supply of imported inputs; (v) over ation tries (such as Zimbabwe) and bureaucratic red tapes; (vi) inadequate trade ifastructure 9. Nigeria Q) Lack of marketi capacity, (ii) btek of external market Competitive edge of other LDC. links; (iii inability to collaborate ith foreig trading agents or companies; (iv) inemective implementation of export poicy irstaments (including failure to ensure access to free trade status, foreign elchange, and inance); (v) inadequate trade infmstructur 10. Senegal (i) igh production costs stemming fom high lat-, port, (i) Limited size of West Afria's mar- transpot, energ, water, mw material, intermediate input, ket; (ii) Atica's imwap in term of Inventory, tax and administrative delay cats; (ii) overvlued product qualit; (iH) import restric- echange rate and failure to compensate; (ii) tack of commit- tions in subregional market (depite ment by authorities for competitivene; (iv) lack of marketing CEAO); (iv) competitive edge of other capacdty (v) difficulty in havig access to finance LDCO 11. Swaziland (i) Not easy acCess to investment and trade finance; (i) inadeq- (i) Competition from South A&ica; uate trade infrastructure; (iii) obstacles in getting expariates' (B) competition from Zimbabwe. rese and werk pni (iv) inflatioa imponed from South 22. Tanzania O) Lack of capacty to export stemming from lack of expei- Competve edge of other LDCL cnce; (ii) inefeti ve implenrentation of exon policies due to red tape and bureaucracies; (iii) not casy access to trade and imedment finance; (iv) inadequate trade inframrocturc 13. Togo 0) Lack of capacity to export; (U) dfficulty in hvig access to Competitive edge of other LDCL trade financ; (ii) lack of effective match-making mechnisms 14. Uanda (i) Lack of capaciy to expU; (it) dimiultie in having a*ess Other LDCs' competitive edge to free trade status (iii) difficulties in havin access to trade and invemt financing; (iv) inadequate trade Infrastructum IS. Zambia (i) Difty in having accs to free trade status; (ii) diffculty (i) Otber DCs competitive edge; in having aces to foreign exange; (iii) lack of teCh&ncaV- (ii) declining regional demand for marketing capacity; (iv) inadequate trade infrastructure; Zambia's export (v) inadequate access to trade and investment financ 16. Zimbabwe (i) Lack of i capac (it) difficulty of hiring (i) Competition frm South Africa; expatdate; (iin) outdated capital equipment; (iv) poor infra- (ii) Zimbabwes trade surplus witb stucwe and high transport coats; (v) delays and complexity of PTA counties customs and dutyfrme import procedures. - 53 - A. Major Demand-Side Constraints 7.03 Firms consider the competitive edge held bv other developing countries in the non-regional hard-currency world market the most notable demand-side constraint. Despite Sub-Saharan African exporters' non-quota and tariff-free advantage in the European and U.S. markets, they are strongly aware of their lack of competitive edge in these markets. This lack is mainly due to the supply-side constraint3 summarized below. 7.04 In the regional market, the sample firms cite the limited size of the market and its low purchasing power; import restrictions; smuggling; and competition with South Africa as the most important constraints. B. Major SupDly-Side Constraints 7.05 The sample firms in the 16 Sub-Saharan countries consistently stressed their lack of capacity to egort as the most important supply-side constraint. The most often mentioned elements they lack are: access to the world market network, capacity to "package', and technical, marketing, and managerial know-how. As we have stressed throughout the paper, a stepped-up effort to induce foreign collaboration is the only way to resolve this lack of capacity to export; and a necessary strategy for it is discussed in Chapters VIII and IX. 7.06 The second most important constraint cited by the firms is their governments' failure to im2lement export policy instruments effectively. The most often-mentioned instruments are the various tools to ensure free-trade status, access to trade finance, and other regulatory regimes for foreign collaboration. The most disastrous aspect of the ineffective implementation of export policy instruments is the difficulty in bringing in foreign collabo- rators, the very element so critical to resolving the lack of capacity to export. This aspect is even more damaging than the lack of a competitive 54 - edge, which hampers current exporters with existing foreign collaboration. More detailed comments by the sample firms on the ineffectiveness of export policy instruments are reviewed in Chapter X. 7.07 The third most important constraint indicated by the sample firms is inadequate physical trade infrastructgte, which leads to very high trans- portation, communication, and utility costs as well as inventory costs and delay costs. This subject is further discussed in Chapter XI. - 55 - VIII. SUB-SAHARAN AFRICAN FIRNS' DESIRE FOR NEW OR ADDITIONAL OREIGN COLLABORATION FOR EXPORT INITIATION OR EXPANSION 8.01 As reviewed in Chapter VII, African exporters and potential exporters strongly recognize their lack of capacity to export as the most serious constraint to export expansion. Also, they realize that the only way to acquire a capacity to export is to bring in foreign collaborators. This chapter analyzes sample firms' desires for additional or nLew foreign collaboration. A. Survey Results for Manufacturing Exporters 1. Firms' Desire for New or Additional Foreign Collaboration. 8.02 Summary. Our field interview included the question: "Is your company seeking (or interested in) new or additional foreign collaboration?' The sample firms' responses are reported in Annex I. The following and Figure 1 are a summary of the responses: Mi) Yes: 60 firms (56%) (ii) No: 48 firms (44%) Total response: 108 firms (100%) (iii) No answer: 13 firms Total sample: 121 firms Even though on average each firm had 1.3 cases of foreign collaboration, as shown in Table 1.2, almost three-fifths of the firms expressed a desire for additional or new foreign collaboration. However, most of the new breed of outward-oriented small- and medium-size firms did not know of any specific channels through which to search for potential (see Chapter IX for more on this) nor did they knew of any potential foreign collaborators seeking local - 56 - partners. There is huge excess demand for foreign collaboration for manufactured export activities. 8.03 Tble 8.1. The Yes or No responses to the above question are presented, together with an enumeration of firms' current foreign collaboration modes. 8.04 Table-8.2. Sample firms' intentions regarding new or additional foreign collaboration are aggregated (based on the inward vs. outward- orientation classification defined in (iii) and (v) of para 6.06). The average number of narrowly-defined foreign collaboration cases is presented as well, to facilitate our understanding of the relationship between firms' future intentions and their current market orientation/foreign collaboration status. 8.05 Sample firms not seeking new or additional foreign collaboration show an average number of narrowly-defined foreign collaborations consistently larger than, or equal to, one. This suggests that they are satisfied with the current status of their foreign collaboration, whatever their market orientation. 8.06 All the inward-looking manufacturing firms that seek new or additional foreign collaboration show an average number of narrowly-defined foreign collaborations consistently lower than one or at zero. This suggests that their inward-orientation is due to their lack of capacity to export, not to their desire to remain in the local market. They want to switch from inward to outward-orientation by building their capacity to export with foreign collaboration. FIGURE t Manufacturing Firms' Desire for New or Additional Collaboration Yes 56% No4l No 44% f Td M AWSAMf*MA4ACIMM5 wXuur MnMumW mirnmis RtODARDSM 14WOR ANNMO4AL r4OaOsE COU~AowAo Siw4mv kda am S,ra1.vma w i bm*auumw msf a 5 t6d NW (b) o"V_a0) T"d 0 1~~~~.21 21.10 $11.2$ M.10o WX-i 21.1 10.26 2S1- I"on cc ___ t P at P lW "*,atj tad Paw NdPdp to.* _ ~ ~~~ _ _ _~b __ - _ m - ~ a __ses_ ad alSe. _ asd _ __ -S}f" aLxS. a9 N. I TlY S S e 1 tiAN N 2IN 0 0 0I 0 4 1 PDIt (OS) lb.~ n 4^1 _ RMIMLS .livS _ ..- YZ e _ 2 tTt: _ _ 2 8228g 2 2|@~~~~1 w 1 _ 1N _ 1 To. 0 A * a i 0 0 0 fi 0 2 A 4 4 Ms) Ye a 2 N;;r; ~(l I t I M% 92 tom ( t 0 2t ------- - - - - __ -_ - I ~~ p~~.m as. a S3~~~4A *0 t tN siv *Nv 0 a ma 4 (23w) ILF~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~f~ L 9"11~~~~y 14 1X O TAu I I PO I ) I S 4PDt; I AI TAM I F I2 I N a (OS) IJV ~ ~ ~ tf~ __ _ - a _t 11F 8imi (ml _{ oMdlum 23049S lb 0 0 0 0 . 2 I I PDI 0 1 M S a 2 A) ikol~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~c _ ~~~~ __ - _~I - _ ye S I I? I I91 0 4 1 Rum 0 0 _ 2 it (as) g�i Sol" H. 0 0 0 I 190 FD 5 g 0 0 0 2 2 901 6 (i2m) Ta S 2 Nag; I 11a. 0 0 2 SPO I ItuIX I IP1 2 lE a31 4 .. l -o No 0 o aImm sm s 4PD Xum aum 2 u S (4 Ta S IPUIt 1 1113 9 0 0 a turn ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I inx I Am IS (143) * _ -~~~~I I - I m = - -. m~~~~~~20.- -L (ml - M t$% t Tabke: RHAT1ONtSHIP BETWEEN FUTURE FOREIGN COLLABORATION INENTIONS AND MARKEr ORMENTATZONI CURRENT COLLABORATION STAIUS OF SAMPLE MANUFACrURED FIRMS I Outwar-oret GM Iuwaoafkated finms Seeking new or (aport 50% or more of products) (expon lss thn SO% of prodcts) Finn size addltboal foreign No. of firms collab B"tkxw foreip aOt Of arms Avg. no, of narrowly Av no. of narrowly No. o finrs defined forign No. of fins (%) defined foeip collaboration collaboration (a) Lt Ade No 11(73%) 2(18%) 1.0 9 (2%) 1.0 Yes 4(27%) 1(25%) 0 3(75%) 0 (b) Medium size 11 NO 4(33%) 2 (50%) 1.0 2(50%) 0 Yes 8(67%) 5(63%) 1.6 3(37%) 0.7 (c) Medum sae I No 6(35%) 3(S0%) 1.0 3 (50%) 1.0 Yes 11 (6%) 4 (36%) 1.3 7 (64%) 03 (d) Small Wi 11 No 6(32%) 4 (67%) 1.3 2(33%) 1.0 Yes 13 (68%) 4 (30%) 13 9 (70%) 0 (e) Small siso I No 13(46%) 9 (69%) 1.0 4(31%) 1.0 yes 1S(54%) 4(27%) 0.8 11 (73%) 0.1 TOW No 40 (44%) 20 (50%) 1.1 20 (50%) 1.0 Yes Si (56%) 19(37%) 1.0 32(63%) 0.2 - 60 - 8.07 Another significant finding is that more than one-third of the firms that desire future foreign collaboration are already outward-oriented and show an average number of narrowly-defined foreign cpllaborations larger than, or equal to, one. This suggests that to maintain their outward- orientation and further penetrate the diversified world market with diversified products, they are continuously searching for foreign collaboration. This new breed of outward-oriented enterprise is entirely in the small- or medium-size category. 8.08 At the same time, most of the large inward-oriented firms do not appear to want additional foreign collaboration. This is mainly because they started with an inward-orientation and intend to stay that way. 8.09 In short, the two factors--(i) current status of foreign collaboration and (ii) firms' desire to switch from inward to outward- orientation or to maintain/expand their outward-orientation--influence firms' decisions to seek new or additional foreign collaboration. Therefore, it is not surprising that although only about one-quarter of the inward-oriented large manufacturing enterprises would seek foreign collaboration in the future, there are more firms in the small- and medium-size export manufacturing industries that seek foreign collaboration. These firms are already more outward-oriented than are the large firms. 2. Firms' Desire for Particular Modes of Foreign Collaboration 8.10 We asked the firms that expressed a desire for new or additional foreign collaboration: "What types of foreign collaboration are your company seeking (or interested in)?" The sample firms' responses are reported in Annex I. The following is a summary of the responses from manufacturing exporters: - 61 - (i) Technical/marketing/management agreement (T/M/Mt Ag) or Tecinical agreement (TAg), marketing agreement (MAg) or management agreement (MtAg) (19 firms (29%) (ii) Sub-contracting agreement (SC) : 7 firms (11%) (iii) Joint venture (JV) : 5 firms (8%) (iv) Foreign trade agent/foreign trading company (FTA/FTC) : 1 firm (28) (v) Preference types not specified : 33 firms (50%) TOTAL : 66 firms W (100%) 8.11 About half the firms failed to provide answers about the specific types of foreign collaboration they would seek (or are interested in). However, many indicated specifically that they seek foreign collaboration primarily for acces6 to the international market network. This suggests that many of the non-responsive firms would have chosen category (i) as well. In any event, under the assumption that the preference of these firms would be similar to the relative choices of the firms that responded or by simply relying on the revealed preference, we infer the following: (i) T/M/Mt Ag: 58% (ii) SC: 22% (iii) JV: 16% (iv) FTA/FTC: 4% TOTAL: 100% 8.12 The fact that the most preferred type of collaboration is techni- cal/marketing/management agreement (T/M/Mt Ag) is consistent with our discussion in Chapter III. This type of collaboration is preferred because: (i) the foreign partner brings in know-how, access to the world market, and the capacity to package, all of which the domestic partner lacks; (ii) the 2/ The total number of manufacturing firms that expressed a desire for future foreign collaboration is 60, but some firms indicated more than one type of foreign collaboration. - 62 - domestic partner does not take much risk; (iii) the domestic partner can count on the foreign partner's strong commitment; (iv) the domestic partner has equity and does not want the uncertainty that can stem from disputes associated with shared ownership with a foreign partner. 8.12 The firms' next preferred mode is sub-contracting (SC). Even though SC does not provide the entire package--know-how, access to the world market, and the capacity to package--it takes care of access to the world market, and it is easier to have an SC agreement than to arrange T/M/Mt Ag, because the foreign partner takes much less risk under SC. 8.13 The fact that a joint venture (JV) is only the third choice in the sample may be because existing firms have capital facilities that have to be used fully. Also, this choice reflects their uncertainty about harmonious relationships with foreign shareholders. 3. Relative Weights Attached to Modes of Foreign Collaboration. Current and Future 8.14 For the sample manufacturing firms, the following relative weights for current modes of narrowly-defined foreign collaboration are derived from Table 4.1: Joint ventures (JV) : 39% Technical/marketing/management consulting (TA/MA/Mt A): 31% Technical/marketing/management agreement (T/M/Kt Ag) : 15% Subcontracting agreements (SC) : :5% TOTAL : 100% - 63 - 8.15 We exclude FDI in the weighting because we wish to compare the weighting attached to the current modes with what the sample firms would prefer in future collaboration. For our sample firms, FDI is not an alternative mode of foreign collaboration. In turn, we have included technical/marketing/management consulting (TA/NA/Nt A) even though it is not a narrowly-defined foreign collaboration mode, because many sample firms indicated that they use TA/HAMNt A in the absence of T/M/Mt Ag, even though they prefer the latter. 8.16 For current purposes, we leave out the foreign trade agent/foreign trading company mode (FTA/FTC) (para 8.11), because it is not a narrowly- defined foreign collaboration mode. Thus Table 8.3 and Figure 2 show the differences between the weights for desired and current collaboration modes for manufacturing enterprises. Table 83 DIFFERENCE BETWEEN DESIRED WEIGHTS AfTACHED BY SAMPLE MANUFACIURED FIRMS AND CURRENT WEIGS ON MODES OF NARROWLY DINED FOREIGN COLLABORATION Modes of narrowly ddeind foreign collaboratimo Desired weight Cimt weight | (i) Te _nlmting~nanaunet agrelaent (T/M/Mt Ag) 60% 15% (U) Subontract agement (SC) 23% 15% Q (q Joint venture (j) 17% 39% (tv) Technica consulting (TAMA/A) 0 % 31% |Total Il| * 100% 100% 8.17 The differences in the weights must be understood carefully. For example, the results do not imply that JV or TA/NA/Kt A would be less important in the future. Rather, the results suggest that the sample manufacturing firms are extremely eager to have more T/M/Mt Ag and SC (rather than JV or TA/NA/Mt A) and that an effective national and lnternational strategy is needed to support this effort (see next chapter). Also, since the results are based on the preferences of existing firms seeking foreign - 64 - collaboration, they exclude the importance of FDI and may underestimate foreign collaborators' role in providing investment capital for new enterprises. B. Survey Results for Primary Resource-Based (on-Traditional) Exporters 1. Firms' Desire for New or Additional Foreign Collaboration 8.18 Summary. Responses from primary resource-based (non-traditional) exporters' to the question on their intentions about new or additional foreign collaboration are as follows (see also Figure 3): (i) Yes: 31 firms (60%) (ii) No: 21 firms (40%) Total response: 52 firms (100%) (iii) No answer: 4 firms Total sample: 56 firms As with manufacturing exporters, about three-fifths of the firms expressed a desire to engage in additional or new collaboration with foreign enterprises, confirming that there is similar excess demand for foreign collaboration in primary resource-based export industries. 8.19 Note that the primary resource-based firms are generally more outward-oriented than are manufacturing firms. Again, results suggest that the more outward-oriented the firm, the more--not less--it must seek foreign collaboration to maintain its competitive edge in the world market. 2. Firms' Desired Modes of Foreign Collaboration 8.20 In our sample, primary resource-based exporters' expressed their preferences for particular types of foreign collaboration as follows: FIGURE 2 Current vs. Desired Modes of Foreign/Domestic Collaboration Percent 70 60- 30 20* 10 0 T/M/Mt Agreement Joint Venture Subcontract TA/MA/Mt Consulting Collaboration Mode Desired Mode Actual Mode Manufacturing Firms J~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ FIGURE 3 - Primary- Resource Based Firms' Desire for New or Additional Collaboration Y 6 _ Yes 60% w ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1' I~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ - 67 - (i) Technical/marketing/management agreements (T/M/14t Ag) : 11 firms (31%) (ii) Joint venture (JV) : 3 firms (9%) (iii) Subcontracting (SC) : 2 firms (6%) (iv) Foreign trade agent/foreign trade company (FTA/FTC) : 1 firm (3%) (v) Preference types not specified : 18 firms (51%) TOTAL 35 firmsW (100%) 8.21 Under the assumption that the choices of firms that did not specify a preference for a particular type of foreign collaboration would be similar to the relative preferences of the other firms or by simply relying on the revealed preference, we may infer the following: (i) T,M/Mt Ag 63% (ii) JV 19% (iii) SC . 12% (iv) FTA/FTC : 6% TOTAL : 100% 8.22 The results for primary resource-based firms are similar to those for manufacturing firms in that the most preferred type of future foreign collaboration is the technical/marketing/management agreement (T/M/Mt Ag). J/ The total number of primary resource-based firms that expressed their desire for future collaboration are 31, bu_ some firms indicated more than one desired types of foreign collaboration. - 68 - 8.23 Firms' next preferred mode is Joint venture (JV), whereas the second choice of manufacturing firms is the subcontracting agreement. 3. Relative Weights Attached to Modes of Foreign Collaboration. Current and Future 8.24 For sample primary resource-based firms the relative weights for current modes of narrowly-defined foreign collaboration are obtained from Table 4.2: Joint ventures (JV) 71% Technical/marketing/management agreements (T/M/Mt Ag) 11t Technical/marketing/management consulting (TA/MA/Mt A) : 11% Subcontracting agreements (SC) : 7% TOTAL 100% 8.25 Table 8.4 and Figure 4 show the differences between the weights, for current and desired, narrowly-defined foreign collaboration modes. Table 8.: DIFFERENCE BETWEEN DESIRED WBIGQS ATTACHED BY SAWLE PRIMARY RESOURCE-BASED FIWMS AND CURRENT WEIGHIS ON MODES OF NARROWLY DEFINED FOREIGN COLLABORATION Mode of nrw defind faoeign coiaboation Deired wdeht Cmment we4gtl ( ) Telmlg t agt (TlM/Mt Ag) 67% 11% (ii) Joint venture (JV) 20% 71% Qii) Subcontract agremnt (SC) 13% 7% | (F) Teftka _ taWWkn~t citl (TA/MAlMt A) 0% 11% TOa 100% 100% fIGURE 4 Current vs. Desired Modes of Foreign/Domestic Collaborat,on Percent 80 60 40 - 20 - 0 T/M/Mt Agreement Joint Venture Subcontract TA/MA/Mt Consulting Collaboration Mode Desired Mode Actual Mode Primary-Resource Based Firms *70 - 8.26 The results shown in Table 8.4 are similar to those in Table 8.3: the primary resource-based firms are as eager as manufacturing firms to expand T/M/Mt Ag and to have more SC in the future. However, in light of African countries' proven comparative advantage in certain primary resource-based (non-traditional) export items, attracting foreign collaboration into these areas would be relatively less difficult than for manufactured export items in which African countries have yet to demonstrate convincingly a competitive edge. Furthermore, while access to the world market (and financial resources) may be primarily what local partners in the primary resource-based industries are looking for the whole package of know-how, access to the world market, and capacity to package (and financial resources) is what most local partners in the manufacturing industries are looking for from foreign collaborators. - 71 - IX. IMPERFECT INFORMATION BETWEEN POTENTIAL FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC COLLABORATORS A. Malor Factors Constraining Foreign Collaborators' Involvement in Sub- Saharan African Export Activities 9.01 This chapter discusses issues related to the imperfect information ga between foreign and domestic collaborators, particularly in manufacturing for export, as well as issues related to negative images about Africa. 9.02 As reviewed in Chapter VII, the exporters in our sample stated that the three major supply-side factors constraining export expansion in Sub- Saharan Africa are: (a) lack of capacity to export; (b) governments' ineffec- tive implementation of export policies; and (c) the region's inadequate trade infrastructure. And as indicated in Chapter VIII, exporters expressed a desire for additional or new foreign collaboration in order to acquire, improve, or expand their capacity to export. Furthermore, as seen in Chapter VII.,, there is also a large gap between the types of foreign collaboration demanded by African firms and the types that foreign suppliers are willing to provide. Most of these demands by African exporters (or potential exporters) for foreign collaboration in general and for particular types have not been met by firms in the OECD countries or from the NIEs. This lack of response has resulted in the huge excess demand for foreign collaboration overall and for particular types. 9.03 The interview questionnaires also asked about the major factors constraining foreign involvement in Africa's manufactured-export activities particularly. Our sample firms cited the same major factors as constrain the African countries' export expansion: (a) ineffective implementation of export policies (and the consequent- ly unfavorable business environment); and - 72 - (b) inadequate trade infrastructure In addition: (c) extremely negative image of Africa; (d) potential collaborators' imperfect information on potential partner countries and enterprises; (e) lack of political and social stability in Africa. Only elements that may appeal to some potential foreign collaborators for Sub- Saharan export activities appear to be the tariff-free or quota-free access to the European or U.S. market and relatively low nominal wages in certain countries. However, because the above constraints normally far outweighed these small advantages, potential foreign collaborators were reluctant to involve in most of the Sub-Saharan African export activities. 9.04 Chapters X and XI review export policy implementation (including policies that influence the business environment) and trade infrastructure issues, respectively. Chapter X defines the internal gM between the high demand by the new breed of local entrepreneurs and the restricted government desire (i.e., policies) for (export-oriented) foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration (as clearly seen from the restrictive expatriate-worker and other policies). 9.05 In Africa the issue of imperfect information (i.e., information gS) appears to be more serious than the issue of export policy implementation (i.e., internal gap) and the issues of physical trade infrastructure, in the sense that even if export policy implementation and physical trade infrastruc- ture improved significantly, most potential foreign collaborators would not change their extremely negative perception about Africa. They would still need to know African countries and enterprises better. Therefore, mechanisms through which (i) foreign collaborators can learn about African policies, physical trade infrastructure and individual firms more intimately, for the consideration of potential collaboration with them, and (ii) local partners - 73 - can search for potential foreign collaborators in the OECD countries or NIEs seem critical.141 Also, mechanisms that would reduce potential foreign collaborators uncertainty about export-related collaboration in general, and about particular types of collaboration, are equally necessary. The extraor- dinary circumstances of the Sub-Saharan African countries necessitate narrow- ing the enormous external gap between the high demand for, ar.d negligible potential supply of, manufactured export-related foreign collaboration. This would appear to be one of the biggest development policy challenges in the 1990s. Although narrowing the external gap (supply and demand) requires narrowing both the internal (policy) gap and the information gap (as well as improving physical trade infrastructure), negligible attention has been given efforts to reduce the information gap in particular, compared to ongoing efforts to reduce the internal gap (i.e., the policy constraints) to create an "enabling environment." B. Collaborators' Access to Information on Potential Partners for ManufAc- tured Exports 9.06 Table 9.1 lists the sources of supply in the past for foreign collaboration in exporting. Several patterns for obtaining information on potential foreign collaborators and potential partners (which led to African involvement) were identified through our field interviews and are summarized below. 4/ 1Lt has been argued that a root cause of underdevelopment in low-income developing countries has been the ineffectiveness of micro agents in dealing with imperfect, and therefore costly, information (Arrow, 1974; Stiglitz, 1989). Further, it has been suggested that a focus of the microeconomic of development in low-income countries should be on effective ways to accelerate the learning process (Stiglitz, 1989). - 74 - a W- I =:~~ 3 I If -# - - - - T- i 83 X�~~~~~~~ - IIfl lt~~~~~~ - - - a - I III --��� F A XRJ1 X _ __ _ ___ _+-_ _ __ __ __ _ ___ ii 21 : -- - . ,1 El~~ if -- .if +__w___ LI~~~~~~ - - - - - - - - - - 75 - 1. Large MNCs8 Initiatives (for Inward-Oriented Foreign Collabora- tign) in Manfacturing Industries 9.07 In the 1960s and even before, most large multinational companies (MNCs) in manufacturing industries invested (through FDI or JVs) in Sub- Saharan African countries based on their careful plans to monopolize Africa's domestic markets. In such cases there was no such element as "imperfect information" that might limit the foreign collaborators' involvement. As indicated (see paras. 6.08-6.10), about three-quarters of our sample large- size manufacturing firms, those with extensive foreign collaboration and with employment size ranging from 1,000 to 4,400 workers, have always been highly inward-oriented. They have collaborated with local firms for monopoly of the protected domestic market, not for entry into the world market. Only recently have these large inward-oriented MNCs begun exporting a fraction of their products, mainly to regional markets and, marginally, to non-regional hard- currency markets. 9.08 For example, Company No. 20 in Country F, with 2,000 workers (established originally in 1929), and Company No. 7 in Country B, with 1,500 workers (established in 1963), were set up by European MNCs as JVs with state companies for local sale of household consumer items (paragraph 6.11). They were nor restricted by imperfect information because they had resources to prepare careful plans based on relevant information. Similarly, Company No. 20 in Country B, producing shoes (with 1,900 workers) for the local market (paragraph 6.12), and Company No. 2 in Country F, producing textiles (with 1,000 workers) for the local market (paragraph 6.13), were established in 1946 and 1922, respectively, by European MNCs. The MNCs' had careful strategies and therefore were not impeded by imperfect information. By the same token, if large MNCs are genuinely interested in becoming involved in African export activities, the imperfect information issue would not exist because these companies have enough resources to collect relevant information. The fact is, - 76 - large MNCs may not be interested in Africa's export activities because they have better alternatives in other parts of the world. 2. Unolanned Access to Information 9.09 According to the results of our survey, key information on a potential target country or enterprise that led to a foreign collaborator's decision to invest in Africa often came as a result of mere accident. Several of our sample companies gained information this way. However, relying on serendipity as a viable means to foster foreign collaboration for Africa's exporting would be folly, because of the urgency of African development. 9.10 For example, in 1973 a medium-size German garment manufacturer decided to establish a company (Company No. 5) through FDI in Country M. This was for domestic market-oriented garment production. The decision to set up the company came after two years' of exporting to Country M--but that business had been initiated as a result of the German executives' safari trip to the country several years previously. After the domestic market in Country M collapsed in the early 1980s, the company exploited a niche in the regional market first, and recently the company has been exporting to the European market as well (1,000 workers in 1991). 3. Experience-Based Access to Information on African Industry by New Breed of Small-and Medium-Size Foreign and Domestic Collaborators. for Outward-Oriented Manufacturing (a) Previous Experience in Sub-Saharan African Manufacturing 9.11 One of the bright spots in Africa's development is the emergence of a new breed of local entrepreneurs including localized foreigners (LF), who are determined to pursue outward-orientation with foreign collaboration. For example, Companies No. 1 and No. 2 in Country B are "super outward-oriented" 77 - small- and medium-size manufacturing exporters who had previous experience in Africa. In turn, the new breed of foreign collaborators with previous experience in African manufacturing has matched up well with the new breed of local entrepreneurs or managers. For example, Company No. 11 (producing garments for 100% export to the U.S. market, with 100 workers) in Country L was taken over by a Hong Kong investor (FDI) in 1990. This Hong Kong busi- nessman had long business experience in another Sub-Saharan African country before deciding to be involved in Country L. (b) Previous Experience in Home Country Exporting to the Sub- Saharan African Market 9.12 It is fortunate that new small- and medium-size foreign collabora- tors emerged in the 1980s as catalysts for Africa's outward-orientation, based on their previous experience in African manufacturing and trade. Several of the sample companies in Table 18 belong to this category. For example, Companies No. 5 and No. 6 in Country 0 (small-size regional exporters of human hair) had obtained the information needed to decide on their collaboration (JV and FDI, respectively) in 1983 while exporting to Country 0 from Korea. 9.13 However, how much further milage will Sub-Saharan African coun- tries be able to get from their outward-orientation based purely on foreign companies with previous experience in Africa? Table 9.1 shows that for the sample companies, only 8 out of a total of 122 cases of narrowly-defined foreign collaboration came from five East Asian countries, primarily based on their previous experience in African manufacturing and trade. A new effective strategy is called for to bring in more outward-oriented foreign collabora- tors, the ones that have had no previous experience in African manufacturing or trade, by resolving the severe imperfect information issues. - 78 - 4. Information Intermediaries for Foreign/Domestic Enterprise Collab- oration in Industrial Export Production and Sales (a) International Assistance Schemes 9.14 Several of the sample firms reported that they received investment financing, equity, or other financial support from various international schemes, including those of IFC and USAID. However, only one primary re- source-based (non-traditional) export enterprise, out of total of 177 sample firms, cited an international scheme's intermediary role in locating a foreign enterprise collaborator (i.e., for narrowly-defined collaboration). In Country D, Company No. 5 (established in 1989) reported that it entered into a technical/marketing agreement (T/M Ag) with a leading U.S. spice manufacturer, for 100%-export-oriented vanilla bean processing, after intermediation by the African Project Development Facility (APDF) of IFC. 9.15 Our sample firms indicated that most of the international assis- tance schemes designed to foster partnership between African and European enterprises (such as the Industrial Partnership Program of the Center for Development of Industry (CDI) created under the Lome Convention) focused on financial assistance for feasibility and diagnostic studies and on technical assistance (TA). This was instead of intermediating foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration (such as FDI, JV, T/M/Mt Ag) in industrial export areas. Partly because of European firms' interest in other locations than Africa for narrowly-defined enterprise collaboration, these assistance schemes appear to have fallen back on finding foreign consultants for African firms. Most of these consultants' experience is not necessarily industrial export- oriented, however. It is unclear whether the match-making mechanisms of the external assistance schemes include searching deliberately for potential European enterprise partners from among small- and medium-size firms that might not be part of a regular network. In any case, the survey results reveal that the types of foreign collaboration supported by the international - 79 - assistance schemes are not necessarily the types of export-oriented for- eign/domestic enterprise collaboration that African exporters are looking for. (b) National Agencies 9.16 None of the sample firms cited any specific intermediary role by African public agencies for locating particular foreign or domestic partners for export production and sale. However, many African governments have established investment promotion centers with the objective of promoting FDI or JV. The centers' role in publicizing FDI or JV incentive policies, responding to active potential investors' requests for information on the legal framework and on potential collaborators, issuing investment permits, and organizing foreign missions to lobby foreign investors has been important. The centers have never played, nor will they ever play, a role in the search for specific foreign export partners, however. This is simply because the centers have neither financial resources nor skills and connections to do so, according to our sample firms. 9.17 Many African governments also have export promotion agencies to facilitate their exporters' access to foreign technical, marketing, and managerial know-how, as well as access to the established international export market network. However, it does not appear that the agencies have been effective beyond organizing overseas fairs and foreign missions, negotiating trade agreements, or collecting aggregate or government-level data. Again, these public agencies have neither financial resources nor skills and connec- tions to intermediate foreign collaboration or provide direct assistance (TA/NA/Mt A), according to our sample firms' opinions. Rather, their efforts can be more effective if they focus on eliminating legal and information barriers that prevent private agents from being intermediaries for foreign collaboration (such as T/M/Kt Ag, JV or FDI). - 80 - (c) Private Agents (i) Foreign Private Agents 9.18 A 100%-export-oriented garment firm in Co-intry B reported its experience with a foreign private agent who was intermediating to obtain a subcontract agreement (SC) with the firm on behalf of a foreign buyer. In 1989, a Hong Kong buying agent's office in Bangladesh introduced this company to a Hong Kong agent who intermediated an agreement with a U.S. buyer and brought in a technical consultant (TA) from Sri Lanka. 9.19 The extremely unstable nature of this type of SC as a means for foreign collaboration at an early stage of a country's export development was clearly demonstrated when the above company in Country B had to stop its factory operation from March to September 1991. This was because the U.S. buyer and the Hong Kong agent did not renew the SC, and the company was unable to find another foreign agent to broker an SC with another foreign buyer. 9.20 In our interview with the company, its managers indicated their desperation for a technical/marketing/management agreement (T/H/Mt Ag) with a small- or medium-size foreign company that has a good track record in the international market. The company had been unable to locate any foreign private agent that could arrange T/M/Mt Ag. By the same token, it does not appea. that there are foreign or international private agents who act for potential T/M/Nt Ag suppliers in finding potential partners in Africa. 9.21 During our interview, another 100%-export-oriented garment company in Country B described the following. A private foreign agent proposed intermediating a technical consulting contract (TA) for the company (and other garment factories in Country B) to upgrade its product quality for the export market. The agent apparently indicated that once product quality had im- proved, based on the TA he proposed to intermediate, he would be willing to - 81 - intermediate SC with foreign suppliers. However, there is no guarantee that he will in fact do so or will succeed. Because of the uncertainty of the potential pay-offs that might be linked directly to the proposed TA, the company was not willing to commit money for the TA fees without parallel support from an aid agency. Here again, the company expressed its preference for T/M/Mt Ag (rather than TA) because of the former's built-in guarantee of royalty payment recovery (through likely increased export sales). However, the company does not know where to find a private intermediary who can carry its case for a T/M/Mt Ag to potential suppliers. If an external aid agency financed the proposed TA, the company would receive it as a free service. However, in light of the company's preference for T/M/Mt Ag, the more effec- tive way of using the aid resources would be to support intermediation for T/M/Mt Ag. 9.22 The interview results from the above two companies confirm our overall findings on the differences between the desired and curren preferenc- es for narrowly-defined foreign collaboration modes for manufacturing enter- prises, as summarized in Table 8.3 of Chapter VIII. (ii) Domestic Agents 9.23 The aforementioned experience of being unable to locate foreign agents to broker T/M/Ht Ag or SC applies equally to domestic agents. In the case of domestic agents, the issue is not how to locate them; the problem is that there is no domestic agent in our sample Sub-Saharan African countries that can play the kind of intermediary role called for above. Usually, domestic trading companies with extensive international contacts would be an ideal starting point in building a local intermediary. However, it does not appear that there are such trading companies in the sample countries. 9.24 Even the role of foreign or international trading companies in exporting manufactured or primary resource-based (non-traditional) products - 82 - from the sample countries is negligible. This inference derives from the fact that there were only three cases of foreign trade agent/foreign trading company (FTA/FTC) collaboration pertaining to our sample manufactured exports, and four cases of FTA/FTC pertaining to the primary resource-based (non- traditional) exports, as shown in Table 4.1 and 4.2. C. Potential Foreign Collaborators' Access to Collaboration Risk Coverafe 9.25 Our interviews with export-oriented foreign collaborators did not reveal any instance in which export-oriented foreign collaborators' risk- taking in African FDI, joint ventures, or technical/marketing/management agreements was directly covered by risk coverage schemes. Nor did the sample exporters cite any export credit insurance/guarantee coverage for their activities. This apparent lack of access to coverage for risk-taking in export-oriented foreign collaborative agreements or in export activities must be seen as an important negative factor that has limited the involvement of export-oriented foreign collaborators in Africa. 9.26 In contrast to the lack of such mechanisms in Africa, industrial country suppliers of machinery and plants to Sub-Saharan African countries have easy access to risk coverage for their exports through their countries' P-cn export credit schemes. In 1970-88, the share of private export credits that was officially insured or guaranteed in relation to total private export credits to Sub-Saharan Africa was significantly higher than the corresponding share relative to other developing countries.AI/ 1j/ See Demirguc-Kunt and Erzan (1991). - 83 - D. Stratelies to Narrow the Information Gap Between Potential Foreign and Domestic Collaborators 9.27 The survey results confirmed that there is a huge external gAu between African firms' extremely high level of demand for foreign collabora- tion and the negligible level of potential collaborator supply for Africa's export activities. Also, the argument in Chapter III that resolving the external discrepancies between developing country enterprises' demand prefer- ences for specific modes of foreign collaboration (such as T/M/Mt Ag) and developed country enterprises' supply preferences (such as TA, MhA, Mt A) may be one of the biggest challenge in designing an effective strategy for foreign collaboration was confirmed empirically in Chapter VIII. 9.28 However, as this chapter points out, existing public, private, and international intermediation mechanisms are virtually incapable of narrowing the information gag. The information gap and the internal (goligYX SaU between private enterprises' high demand and government agencies' restrictive policies for (export oriented) foreign collaboration (discussed in Chapter X) are the two critical factors for the huge external gap between high demand and negligible potential supply. Also, the existing foreign collaboration risk- coverage schemes for African export activities do not appear to support any attempt to attract export-oriented foreign collaborators by reducing their uncertainty about Africa. 9.29 As indicated (para 9.11) the bright spot in this disappointing situation appears to be the emergence of a new breed of outward-minded small- and medium-size African entrepreneur. However, their momentum may be lost unless matched soon by a stepped-up inflow of their counterpart enterprises collaborators from the OECD countries or NIEs. Time may be running out quickly for many of the Sub-Saharan African countries to capture outward- oriented foreign collaboration because the potential stock of new breeds of outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign enterprises seeking relocation - 84 - from the OECD countries or NIEs has been rapidly diminishing. This is because they have already been rapidly moving to other locations around the world where the information gap is smaller and the internal gap is narrowing (Asia, Caribbean, Latin America, or Eastern Europe). It appears that by the mid- l990s there will be no substantial stock of such foreign firms left. There- fore, locating and bringing these new foreign collaborators into Africa's export activities (i.e., by resolving information and policy gaps) to match them up with the new breed of local entrepreneur, is one of the biggest development challenges for the first half of the 1990s. 9.30 In meeting this challenge by narrowing the information gap, the following two new institutional mechanisms can play a catalytic role: (i) private match-making mechanisms; and (ii) foreign collaboration risk-coverage schemes. These mechanisms and schemes would be exclusively for Sub-Saharan African export activities. These would be designed to attract the new breed of small- and medium-size foreign enterprises whose strong negative image of Africa has so far led them to exclude Africa as a potential collaboration site. Imaginative and innovative approaches would be key for the success of such mechanisms and schemes. 9.31 The basic premises that underlie these two institutional consider- ation are the following: (a) Putting public or international resources into developing private match-making mechanisms is far more effective than putting resources into public mechanisms which have been not very effective; (b) Even though both the local and foreign firms know that collabora- tion can benefit them through increased export earnings, they cannot bring about collaboration because: (i) no one is willin.g to locate potential partners for match-making; and (i) no scheme - 85 - is available to cover the export-oriented foreign partners' risk- taking. (c) If local and foreign partners were willing to pay private match- making fees and risk-coverage premiums as part of their export earnings, private match-makers and a risk coverage scheme might emerge to the extent that there are enough transactions that will more than break even. (d) However, (c) will not happen naturally; thus, public and interna- tional initiatives are called for to lead the way to make it happen. - 86 X. IMiPLNMTATION OF EXPORT POLICY INSTRUMEUNI A. Free Trade Status 10.01 Free trade is achieved by completely liberating goods markets from government policy restrictions (i.e., QRs and foreign exchange restrictions) and tariffs (and indirect taxes) throughout the whole economy. But most low- income developing countries cannot achieve free trade in the short run, because of their balance of payments, among other reasons, and therefore they attempt to provide such status for their export activities first, before extending the regime to non-export activities. 1. Instruments for Frea Trade Status (a) Duty (and Indirect Tax)-Free Import Schemes 10.02 For developing countries that lack a free-trade regime, the following duty-free (and indirect tax-free) import schemes are alternatives: (i) export processing zone (EPZ); (ii) bonded manufacturing warehouse (BMW or in-bond factory) with around-the-clock customs monitoring; (iii) BMW with customs spot-checks; (iv) common BMW; (v) duty exemption system; (vi) individual drawback system; and (vii) fixed drawback system. 10.03 E. An EPZ is: (i) an industrial estate (surrounded by fences) with factory buildings for rent; (ii) that offers free trade (and other liberalized regulatory regimes) for 100%-export manufacturing; (iii) that relies on the simplest "physical checking mechanisms' of material inflows and - 87 - goods outflows; and (iv) that primarily aims to draw in FDI and stimulate the creation of joint ventures with local firms. 10.04 BMW with around-the-clock customs monitoring. This type of BMW, for 100%-export-oriented manufacturing firms with the required warehouse facilities, relies on the physical checking of goods to and from the BMW, just as in an EPZ. 10.05 BMW with customs sRot-checks. This type of BMW, for 100%-export- oriented manufacturing firms with the required warehouse facilities, relies on documentation requirements and frequent customs spot checks of inventories. This type is a hybrid of the conventional BMW and the duty-exemption systems. 10.06 Common BMW. A licensed common BMW serves as a private or semi- public agent for small- and medium-scale exporters who lack direct access to individual BMWs. 10.07 Duty-exemgtion system. This system exempts firms from paying duties (and indirect taxes) on imports (and capital goods) used for (direct and indirect) export production. The exemption is determined based on expected direct and indirect export activities and associated actual import activities. The main documentary requirements for the duty exemption system are: an approved standard imported input-output coefficient; documents showing expected direct and indirect export quantity; and a payment guarantee of duty liability associated with an approved import quantity. 10.08 Individual-drawback system. This system refunds the duties actually paid by direct and indirect exporters, as determined and based on completed export and associated import activity. The main documentary requirements for the individual drawback system are: an approved standard imported input-output coefficient; documents showing completed direct and - 88 - indirect export quantity and value; and documents showing completed import quantity and value of inputs with actual duty payments. 10.09 Fixed-drawback system. This system estimates the duties in the overall cost if producing export commodities and refunds them to the final-use exporters according to a predetermined schedule. The main documentary requirements for the fixed-drawback system are a standard fixed drawback rate set by the government for a given export item, and documents showing final export vtlue. (b) Import Licenses and Foreign Exchange 10.10 To operate under free trade status, exporters must be guaranteed speedy and automatic access to import licenses and foreign exchange. These are necessary for importing the raw materials needed for export production. (c) Firance 10.11 Even if the various duty-free import schemes are in place and access to import licenses and foreign exchange is ensured, exporters still might not enjoy speedy access to imported inputs. This might be because access to finance is limited, due to physical collateral requirements or credit ceilings imposed on commercial bank loans. Therefore, failure to provide easy access to trade finance can indirectly limit exporters' free trade status. (Interview results on access to finance and its implications for providing free trade status are discussed below.) 2. Interview Results: Firms Evaluate Free-Trade Status 10.12 Our sample exporters' comments on implementation of the various instruments of free trade in the 16 Sub-Saharan African countries are summa- rized in Annex II. - 89 - (a) Availability of Instruments 10.13 Free trade. Two of the sample countries, Swaziland and Botswana, depend on free trade under the Southern African Customs Union (SACU) for most of their imports for export production. 10.14 M. Senegal has operated an EPZ (Dakar EPZ) since 1975. Kenya, Togo, and Madagascar have enacted EPZ laws recently. Only the private EPZ in Kenya was in operation at the time of our survey. Togo and Madagascar allow the ZPZ regime for individual factory sites. In this report, such individual EPZs are grouped with BMYs. 10.15 BHW. Several countries operate iaostly the conventional BMWs (with around-the-clock customs monitoring), but apparently only a limited number of large-scale exporters can have access to this scheme. (For example, only two firms in Zimbabwe and only large state companies in Zambia and Tanzania appear to have BMW licenses.) Kenya introduced its BMW system in 1989, an, Malawi operates pilot BMWs. In turn, the so-called individual EPZ systems '" Togo and Madagascar, introduced recently, can be considered BMW systems. Proposals for BMW systems are under review in several of our sample countries (such as Nigeria and Mozambique), while several others (such as Uganda and Ghana) have not yet reached even a review stage. All the BMW systems in operation are individual BMWs, and there is no single common BMW system (similar to the one being operated in the Philippines) in place in the African countries. 10.16 Duty-exemption system. This appears to be new in many of the Sub- Saharan African countries, as evident in Kenya, which introduced the duty exemption system only this year. Many of the sample countries are reviewing proposals to institute duty-exemption systems. 10.17 Duty-drawback system. This is the most common system allowed by the customs regulations in most African countries. A few countries appear to - 90 - rely on some variants of a fixed-drawback system. For example, Kenya's Export Compensation scheme is a fixed-drawback system with a flat 20% drawback rate applied on all the listed products and companies. 10.18 Access to imnort licenses and foreign exgh&Me. In several of the sample countries (such as Swaziland, Botswana, Nalawi, etc.), access to import licenses and foreign exchange is not a problem. Also, considerable progress has been made in many countries through import liberalization and foreign exchange auctioning for both exporters and non-exporters. Free trade and full convertibility of local currency are the ultimate goas of all developing countries, and general import liberalization and foreign exchange auctioning would move them closer to those goals, even though the goals may be long-term. Several sample countries rely also on an export-earning retention scheme for granting export incentives and for helping exporters access loreign exchange to import goods for export production. However, it does not appear that built-in mechanisms to guarantee exporters' access to import licenses and foreign exchange (even during foreign exchange shortages and for new export- ers) have been instituted in any of the sample countries. (b) Implementation by Governments as Seen by Firms 10.19 Evaluation criteria. The following are basic to the effective design and implementation of the various instruments summarized above. W (i) speedy processing; (ii) guaranteed free trade status; (iii) compliance with the GATT rules on export subsidies; (iv) transparency; (v) automaticity; (vi) prevention of misuse of duty-free imports; IV Rhee (1991b). - 91 - (vii) equal treatment for all activities that generate export value- added; and (viii) minimum red tape. 10.20 Soeedv urocesslng of nroced aes. The first two are the most critical factors for firms that wish to compete in the world market because exporters otherwise fail to meet export orders on time, incur huge inventory costs, or suffer costly production disruption. Without guaranteed free trade, exporters cannot compete in the world market on an equal footing with foreign competitors who operate under free trade, with full convertibility of local currency and easy access to finance. However, our sample firms" eomments reveal that in most Sub-Saharan African countries (except for Swaziland and Botswana, which enjoy partial free trade with neighboring countries) these two criteria are not effectively met; thus many firms do not bother to use the available duty-drawback schemes because the costs from delays and paperwork outweigh the reductions in duty. 10.21 gATZ.rules. Compliance with the GATT rules on export subsidies that mandate no excess exemptions or rebates does not appear to be a problem because most exporters in the Sub-Saharan African countries are not even operating under free trade status--mainly due to the ineffective implementa- tion of the duty-exemption and drawback systems. 10.22 Transpareny and automaticity. Without transparency and automa- ticity it is difficult. to maintain the other elements. Furthermore, without transparency and automaticity, a system cannot guarantee equal treatment for all export value-added activities or prevent misuse of duty-free imports, because discretionary elements would result in special favors and corruption. It appears that much work and effort are needed for most Sub-Saharan African countries to have a transparent and automatic free trade administration. * 92 - 10.23 Minimum red-taRe. The major reason for governments' failure to guarantee speedy processing is the red tape involved in administrative procedures in most African countries. If red tape were the minimum necessary evil to achieve-transparency and automaticity, at least one could appreciate the effort; instead, red tape has ruined the whole objective of free trade status system. In fact, in most African countries, administrative procedures fail unless they are very simple. Therefore, simple mechanisms and speedy access are absolute requirements, even though strict insistence on them may compromise the other elements of free trade status somewhat. This is because there is no system that could satisfy all the above criteria, especially in the African context. (c) Major Causee for Ineffective Imilementation 10.24 Three major causes for the ineffective implementation of the instruments for free trade are: (i) lack of commitment; (ii) lack of know-how and administrative capability; and (iii) lack of inter-agency coordination. 10.25 Commitment. Senegal's EPZ policy regime and Kenya's BMW system are just two examples where ineffective implementation suggests a lack of commitment to guarantee true free-trade status for 100 export-oriented foreign and domestic companies. The EPZ companies in Dakar pay a COSEC tax at the seaport (0.3% of total export value), and Kenya's BMW companies must put up expensive and separate bonds for ports, container shipments, and factories. This means high bonding fees, high port charges, and customs officials' overtime fees, etc. These bonding requirements for BMWs stem from the government's mistrust of both exporters and the customs officials who super- vise the BMWs around-the-clock. Such mistrust again originates from a lack of official commitment to manufactured exports. 10.26 Mistrust of exporters is even more notable in the administration of the economy-wide duty-free import schemes (duty exemption and drawback - 93 - systems) because these schemes, mainly used by less than 100l-export-oriented firms, are administered through documentation. Officials assume that export- ers cheat to gain excessive exemptions or refunds (above what is allowed under free trade status). Such mistrust leads to even more red tape and bureau- cratic discretion, resulting in more corruption. 10.27 Know-how. Even government commitment does not translate into concrete action to improve free trade status because government bureaucracies lack the technical nuts-and-bolts knowledge to improve the various instru- merts, nor do they have administrative capability to implement the nuts and bolts. For example, effective implementation of duty-exemption and duty- drawback systems depends critically on the manner in which the imported input- output coefficients are handled.171 In most developing countries, the process of approving the coefficient starts only after the (direct or indirect) exporter makes an application for the drawback or exemption and submits estimates of the input-output coefficients. This ad hoe approach results in time-conswuaing approval procedures and arbitrary decisions. 10.28 The most efficient way to satisfy all the basic principles, including free trade status, GATT rules, and equal treatment, is to let exporters rely on the standard input-output coefficients as pre-tabulated and published by the government. The administrative costs of publishing the input-output coefficients would be much smaller than the time and resources currently wasted by both firms and the government. However, lack of expertise in adminiatering input-output coefficients in Sub-Saharan Africa has prevented the move from the ad hgc approach to a more systematic approach. A common V/ Imported input-output coefficients ensure that duty-free imports: (i) provide free trade status for direct and indirect export activities; (ii) prevent misuse of the systems; and (iii) meet the GATT rules on export subsidies. Annex to Article 9 of the Subsidy Code of the GATT, "Illustra- tive List of Export Subsidies" includes: "The remission or drawback of import charges in excess of those levied on imported goods that are nhysically incorDorated (making normal allowance for waste) in the export product" as one element of export subsidies. See GATT, The Texts of the Tokvo Round Agreements. Geneva, August 1986, p. 79. - 94 - strategy for most of the Sub-Saharan African countries on input-output coefficient estimates may have to be considered (see chapter XII). 10.29 Coordination. Particularly in the Sub-Saharan developing coun- tries that have suffered chronic foreign exchange shortages, free trade status cannot be guaranteed by customs services alone. Without the consent of the foreign exchange authorities for automatic access to foreign exchange--giving the highest priori to exporters' import needs- -free trade status for exporters cannot oe assured. Exporters in several countries (such as Tanzania and Zambia) cited this problem 'Similar barriers to free trade were experi- enced by sample firms in relation to import licensing or trade finance (see below on trade finance). 3. Future StrateAies 10.30 As indicated above, no single system can meet all the aforemen- tioned principles. Given the urgency of providing free trade status for both foreign and local exporters, and with a minimum of red tape, despite the current lack of administrative capability, the following two-stage approach may be a feasible strategy. 10.31 Stage 1. The physical-checking mechanisms of EPZs and BMWs might be the only instruments to offer to 100%-export-oriented foreign companies (and domestic companies). This is because the lack of administrative capabil- ity hampers the document-checking mechanisms of the duty-exemption and drawback systems in the short term, On the other hand, a well-managed fixed- drawback system can be applied quickly for local exporters who are not neces- sarily 100%-export-oriented. Even this simpler scheme may fail unless governments show their commitment in terms of: (i) a guaranteed annual budget allocation for full refunds of the duties collected from exporters; (ii) targeted periods for drawbick payments (say two weeks); (iii) drawback payments based on shipping documents rather than on foreign exchange receipts; - 95 - (iv) estimation of realistic fixed-drawback schedules that reflect products' different duty and indirect tax-contents. In turn, without the built-in mechanisms that guarantee exporters access to import licenses and foreign exchange, the above systems may not be able to ensure free trade status. 10.32 Stag2 2. The preparatory work to deal with 'mported input-output coefficients may have to start immediately, in Stage 1. Also, the legal framework for the duty-exemption and Individual-drawback schemes (and the common BMW system) should be instituted as soon as possible in Stage 1. But the full implementation of these economy-wide systems may not be possible until Stage 2 when the necessary standard imported input-output coefficients for major export items are available. Sub-Saharan African countries might have to aim at offering all the alternative duty-free import systems so as to let foreign and domestic enterprises choose among them based on their compara- tive advantages. Each system offers different trade-offs in terms of the principles listed in para 10.19. For example, Kenya may have to offer an individual drawback system so that exporters who do not qualify for the current duty-exemption, BMW, EPZ, or fixed drawback systems can be given a feasible instrument to get refunds for duties paid after export completion. An additional system would not place more administrative burdens on the government, because once standard imported input-output coefficients are available for the duty-exemption system, they can be used directly for the individual duty-drawback system as well. B. Trade Finance 1. Instruments for Trade Finance 10.33 Trade finance markets. Unlike the provision of free trade status, easy access to trade finance for all export value-added activities cannot be assured by simply liberalizing the trade financing market. Such a market does not exist in most low-income developing countries. Trade finance market - 96 . itnstruments and mechanisms have to be developed through deliberate government efforts. While the development of full-blown trade finance mechanisms would have to be a long-term objective, interim measures have to be implerented immediately to ensure access to trade finance for export activities. In fact, these interim measures become the first step toward developing trade finance market mechanisms 1/ 10.34 Modern trade finance systems. The modern trade finance system was most innovatively designed and successfully implemented in the East Asian NIEs. It consists of: (i) bank credit instruments, such as letter of credit (L/C), domestic L/C, and bankers' acceptance (BA); (ii) export and associated import and domestic purchase transaction- base self-liquidating trade loan disbursement/liquidation mechanisms (designed by the central bank and handled by commercial banks); (iii) lender-of-last-resort rediscount facilities in the central bankilt; (iv) institutions that deal with the risk of exporters' non-performance (i.e., pre-shipment export finance guarantee schemas); and (v) institutions that deal with the risk of overseas buyers' non- payment (i.e., export credit insurance/guarantee schemes). 10.35 In developing countries, banks lack the capacity to internalize risk-taking. Developing countries must start with "loan-based" trade financ- ing rather than "credit-based" trade financing that reflects trade finance 18/ Rhee (1989b). 12/ Developing (i), (ii), and (iii) in the East Asian NIEs in the early 1960s was not so different from the British government's efforts in the nineteenth century (in establishing bill of exchange rediscounting by the Bank of England and enacting the Bill of Exchange Act of 1882) and the BA rediscounting of the U.S. Federal Reserve System in early 1900s. - 97 - market mechanisms.W However, also due to the lack of capacity to internalize the risks from loan-based export financing based on (i) and (iii), physical collateral substitutes created internally, based on (ii) and supple- mented by a pre-shipment export finance guarantee scheme (iv) and an export credit insurance/guarantee system (v), are needed. Based on these instru- ments, the East Asian NIEs' export financing systems have ensured speedy and undisrupted access to pre-shipment and post-shipment export loans for all direct and indirect exporters with confirmed export L/Cs and other export orders. 10.36 Foreign currency loan schemes. The East Asian NIEs have used foreign currency loan schemes most effectively to ensure access to foreign exchange and trade finance for importing inputs related to export production. This is a typical integrated approach to dealing with the rational import, foreign exchange, and finance regimes for exporters. In developing countries in Africa the domestic financial market is segmented, and the foreign exchange rate does not always reflect opportunity costs; furthermore, external borrow- ing plays a large role in financing development. An effective way to ensure efficient management of foreign exchange in a low-income developing country would be to denominate all loans (including import loans for exporters) tied to the use of exchange reserves and foreign borrowing in foreign currency and to charge an international-market interest rate. 2Q/ When a bank provides a "loan," it lends actual money. When it creates a BA- -its unconditional promise to pay a certair. sum of money at a definite date to the bearer--it lends "credit." The BA discount market which is part of the money market is the trade finance market. - 98 - 2. Interview Results (a) Availability of Instruments 10.37 Overdraft facilities. Many Sub-Saharan African countries do not have modern trade finance systems. Overdraft facilities in commercial banks and self-financing are the two major instruments for exporters even in such countries as Botswana, which appears to have implemented the other export policy instruments effectively. For example, Mozambique has only one commer- cial bank, and Malawi has ouly two commercial banks, suggesting the limited availability of overdraft facilities. 10.38 Rediscount facilities. A few of our sample countries (such as Uganda and Nigeria) have recently introduced pre-shipment and short-term post- shipment rediscount facilities for non-traditional exporters. However, we were unable to collect detailed aggregate data on the use of these facilities. 10.39 Pre-shipment exgort finance guarans ees (PEFG) and export credit insurance/guarantees (ECI/G). A few sample countries (Uganda and Nigeria) have recently introduced the PEFG (which deals with exporters' non-performance risk) and ECI/G (that deals with foreign buyers' non-payment risk) schemes. Usually, building these types of institution takes a long time. 10.40 Foreign currenc loan schemes. A few sample countries (Uganda and Nigeria) have operated foreign currency working capital loan schemes. However, we were unable to collect data on the extent of the schemes' use. (b) Major Issue 10.41 Assess Difficulties. Exporters in all the sample countries stressed that their difficulties with trade finance are one of the major factors limiting their export expansion, as reviewed in Chapter 7 (Table 7.1). 99 - Such difficulties also were noted In sample countries that otherwise indicated no major problems generally in their free trade status or in accessing foreign exchange. But in those countries, difficulties with trade finance indirectly contributed to the failure to ensure a true free trade status, because exporters who had difficulty getting finance could not import inputs for timely export production. 10.42 Collateral requirement. Difficulties in accessing trade finance stem from the general practice of relying on collateral-based overdraft facilities (no matter whether a goverrment-supported trade finance rediscount scheme is available) rather than L/C-based trade finance facilities. For example, one exporter indicated that the collateral requirements sometimes reached 200-300% of the loan amount. Large-size foreign companies might not be affected by these requirements as much, but the new breed of small- and medium-size local firms that collaborate with foreign partners might have greater difficulties. In fact, a few 100%-export-oriented garment firms in Country B indicated that a major reason they rely on SC-based importing and exporting--even though they prefer L/C-based activity--is that it is too difficult to qualify for trade finance to import inputs based on L/Cs. 10.43 Trade transaction-based. self-liquidating mechanisms. It does not appear that even countries that have introduced trade finance rediscount schemes and/or PEFG and ECI/G schemes have instituted the trade transaction- based, self-liquidating trade loan disbursement/liquidation mechanisms ((ii) in para 10.32) that would substantially reduce commercial banks' risk-taking and, therefore, the collateral burden imposed on borrowers. Such mechanisms are also critical in making PEFG and ECI/G schemes workable. Sub-Saharan African countries should give a high priority to developing such mechanisms. 10.44 Credit ceilinMs. The availability of collateral for individual exporters determines their specific credit ceilings. Also, the credit ceilings imposed on individual commercial banks by the monetary authorities - 100 - frequently limit export loans available to exporters--that is if export loans are included under such ceilings. For example, Kenya's export finance rediscount facility, reactivated in 1990, has not been used by exporters. One of the major reasons is that the central bank has a policy to include trade finance granted by commercial banks in the credit ceilings imposed on export- ers.U/ C. Investment Finance 10.45 Adequate access to investment financing for exporters at market interest rates is also important in providing equal footing with foreign competitors. In many of the sample countries, however, access to long term financing is problematic. Reasons for this include underdeveloped domestic capital markets where long term financing does not exist, risk aversions of commercial banks which imposes collateral requirements few firms can meet and reluctance to borrow on the part of exporters due to uncertainty about government fiscal and monetary policies. Foreign firms often are faced with ceilings for domestic borrowing; they are expected to complement financing requirements with funds from abroad. Some of the countries that were visited during our study have instituted schemes designed to provide access to investment financing for exporters. The schemes' effectiveness as judged by exporters in the sample are summarized in the following. 10.46 In Ghana, as a result of financial sector restructuring efforts banks have become more liquid and have restored sound portfolios. However, the banking sector has also become overly risk-averse; credit has become scarce and interest rates have skyrocketed, to the detriment of manufacturers with short- and long-term borrowing needs. Industrialists increasingly have to turn to bi- and multi-lateral sources of funding or to foreign equity 2I1/ The real bills doctrine has implied historically the different treatments of trade finance based on bills of exchange from other finance in controlling liquidity. - 101 - participation. In a situation where new and small exporters are faced with bankers' general attitude of distrust, large collateral is required that few new/small exporters can meet. In Botswana, acceptable collateral is Immovable property such as land, or real estata. However, land is a communal resource in Botswana, and communal ownership often prevents land as being useable collateral. Smaller and less well established firms thus have to rely mostly on self financing. 10.47 In addition to excessive risk aversions on the part of lending institutions, crowding out is a characteristic that applies to many of the countries visited as part of this study. For instance, in Tanzania, the banking sector is faced with excessive borrowing requirements from agricultur- al and other parastatals, effectively crowding out other borrowers. In Mozambique, where crowding out by the public sector is a problem as well, firms' self-financing of investment needs is almost the rule. This lack of financing in the economy was Considered to seriously threaten the firms' operation by a majority of those interviewed in Mozambique. 10.48 Lack of competition in the banking sector is a reason which was often given by exporters to explain the shortage of long-term loans. In Burundi, the sample exporters commented that the two largest commercial banks were well established and were not interested in accommodating exporters' investment financing needs. In contrast, a new comer in the banking sector in Burundi, together with Meridian Bank is setting up an investment banking arm that will provide equity investment as well as leasing. In Madagascar, where exporters face similar problems as were mentioned above, credit lines provided by multilateral and bilateral agentcies provide additional financing sources. However, a number of firms complained about the ciifficulty and considerable red tape (required by commercial banks) that exporters encounter in attempting to get access to investment financing. Several firms remarked that investment funds seem to be allocated to a few large and well connected firms. A few financial institutions have recently appeared on the lending scene to provide - 102 - venture capital, but their capacity falls far short of Madagascar's private sector start-up and expansion capital needs. 10.49 Firms with foreign equity participation above a certain percentage and fully-foreign owned firms often encounter ceilings in their access to the borrowing facilities of the host country. In Swaziland, for instance, foreign-controlled firms (in Swaziland defined as firms with more than 25 percent foreign equity participation), are expected to raise a substantial amount of their long-term investment needs abroad. In Uganda, uncertainty on the part of manufacturers about the future course of macroeconomic policy seems to prevent firms to seek long-term financing which is theoretically available from different development banks. Those manufacturers interviewed sated repeatedly their own reluctance to take the hard-currency risk involved in foreign currency investment loans from these institutions. D. Investment and Regulatory Regimes for Foreign Collaborators 10.50 This section summarizes interview results on the investment and regulatory regimes for foreign collaborators. 1. Sgecial EPZ Regime for Foreign Investors 10.51 In Chapter X (paras 10.02 to 10.04), an EPZ and BMW were defined as instruments for ensuring free trade status for 100%-export-oriented foreign (and domestic) investors. "EPZ policy regimes" is defined more broadly than as a free trade status instrument: the EPZ policy regime allows not only free trade but also the most liberal investment and other regulatory policy regime (FDI or JV) for 100%-export-oriented foreign investors. The EPZ policy regime extends to the 100 export-oriented foreign investors who have EPZ licenses. In certain countries, EPZ license holders do not have to be located in EPZ-- they can rely on BMWs for their free-trade status and other liberalized regulatory regimes. - 103 - 10.52 As stated in para 10.13, Senegal has operated the Dakar EPZ since 1975. Kenya, Togo, and Madagascar have enacted their EPZ laws move recently. (Only one private EPZ in Kenya was in operation at the time of our inter- views.) Togo and Madagascar allow the EPZ regime to cover individual factory sites with BMWs, while Senegal and Kenya allow the EPZ regime only inside EPZs. 10.53 If the legal provisions are effectively implemented, the EPZ regime is the most ideal policy regime for export-oriented foreign collabora- tors. This is because it ensures very-close-to-fres regulatory regimes for repatriation of profits, foreign exchange, investment licensing, expatriate worker permits, local worker employment, etc., as well as customs procedures, duties, indirect taxes (and reduced or exempted income taxes). This is all under a special law that allows an exemption from the normal regulatory regimes applied to local and foreign firms that do not have EPZ licenses. 10.54 As indicated above, effective implementation of the EPZ regime may not be achieved automatically (even if the legal framework has been enacted) without continuous and concerted efforts by the government agencies in charge of the various policy jurisdictions. For example, it does not appear ttl.t the "one-step service" characteristics of the Dakar EPZ adminis- tration have been effectively implemented. Sample firms stated that they had to visit separate government agencies (far away from the EPZ site) for certaia paperwork. In the case of Madagascar's EPZ regime, it does not appear that potential applicants have had a clear understanding of the various implementa- tion provisions so far, according to some sample firms' comments. 2. Investment Codes 10.55 N4any of the countries in the sample have recently reformed or are reforming their codes on foreign investment in a much more liberal direction. For example, Tanzania enacted a National Investment Promotion and Protection - 104 - Act that encourages export-orientation and allows 100% foreign ownership, etc. in 1990. Malawi adopted a new Investment Policy Statement to streamline PDI administration, abolish industrial licensing, etc. in 1990 under the guieance of Foreign Investment Advisory Service (FIAS) of IFC/MIGA. In turn, the investment codes in Zambia and Burundi are being revised to establish "one- stop-service" for new investors, streamline the duty-drawback scheme, liberal- ize profit remittances, and streamline FDI approval procedures, etc. While significant progress has been riade, however, the following major issues still remain. These have to be solved for the urgently needed rationalization of the regulatory regimes for export-oriented foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration. (a) Restrictions on Know-How Inflow 10.56 Restrictions on royalty pauments. In several of the sample countries, such foreign and domestic enterprise or personnel collaboration agreements as technical/marketing/management agreements (T/M/Mt Ag), techni- cal/marketing/management consulting (TA, MA, Mt A), and brand name licensing (BL) are regulated tightly, mainly due to foreign exchange shortages. For example, a sample firm in Kenya stated that both formal approval from the Ministry of Science and Technology and foreign exchange allocation from the Central Bank are required in order to make any collaboration agreements that specify royalty payments to foreigners. 10.57 Restrictions on expatriate workers. The above-types of foreign and domestic enterprise and personnel collaboration, plus FDI and JV, are indirectly restricted in most of our sample countries through the rigid control of expatriate work permits. For example, the sample firms suggested that Nigeria implements a policy of promoting its indigenous workforce by imposing an expatriate quota, even though Nigeria needs the expertise of foreigners. The most critical constraints on export expansion are reportedly the Nigerians' lack of capacity to export--lack of know-how--and barriers to - 105 - the world market network. Only one sample comnany in Zimbabwe reported that it had expatriate technicians from the mother .smpany at its factory. The reason that no companies have expatriate staff is that expatriate work permits are difficult to obtain, despite a severe shortage of local professional skills. If a work permit can be obtained, it is for only a two-year period and rarely renewable; firms considered this period too short for much skill transfer. 10.58 In addition, it is difficult to attract expatriate staff because they cannot be paid 'on expatriate terms,' meaning that foreign exchange regulations prohibit remuneration in foreign currency. Our inference that the major reason for the restrictive expatriate work perm-ts is not necessarily foreign exchange shortages is based on the following examples. While the trade and payments system is very liberal in Botswana, expatriate work permits appear to be very difficult to obtain in practice, due to bureaucratic slowness; despite the recognized shortage of skilled manpower at all levels. Once obtained, a permit is difficult to renew for sufficient time. This public policy stance in Africa (which might stem from Africans' fear of foreigners' economic domination) is in direct contradiction with the high demand by the private sector for foreign collaboration. 10.59 Restrictions on profit reoatriatijo. Considerable progress has been made on reducing restrictions on profit repatriation by foreigners. However, still more reforms are needed in many of the sample countries. For example, a new investment code (1989) has replaced the earlier code in Zimbabwe; the limitation on repatriation of capital and profits has been de- creased but still exists. For export-oriented investments the new code allows, in principle, 100% repatriation of profits, but the actual implementa- tion of this principle appears to be on a case-by-case basis rather than automatically. - 106 - (b) Strategies to Narrow tho Internal G8a BeteenL Government Agencies' Restrictive Behavior and Local Znterpriges' High Demand for Foreign Collaboratio 10.60 Demand for Foreign Collaboratiio. Any attempt to meet the most important development challenge in the first half of the 1990s by narrowing the external gap between the local enterprises' demand for foreign collabo- rators in African export activities and the actual supply will be futile if the African countries fail to narrow, first, the internal gap between the public agencies' restrictive desires (as reflected by their failu e to reform the regulatory regimes for foreign collaboration and other export policy implementation) and enterprises' greot demand for foreign collaboration. To tiarrow the internal gap, a comprehensive approach (rather than the current piecemeal approaches) to reform the regulatory regimes is called for. The establishment of the EPZ regimes in a few sample countries is an important beginning. However, this is just a beginning, because much potential foreign collaboration in export activities can, and should be, achieved also for domestic and foreign firms who do not have EPZ licenses. In principle, all foreign collaboration activities generating export earnings should be allowed to enjoy almost-free regulatory regimes similar to the EPZ regime. An encouraging beginning has been made in this regard, under the guidance of FIAS (para 10.49). For example, the on-going discussions on Kenya's Sessional Paper on Investment Policy appear aimed at producing a comprehensive policy statement extending such almost-free regulatory regimes (including "one-stop- service') to all types of foreign/domestic collaboration in export activities. 10.61 To convince public agencies in most of the Sub-Saharan African countries that it is critically important to speed acting on narrowing the internal gap between the government agencies' restrictive behavior and local enterprises' high demand for foreign collaboration, it is important to stress the following two points. Pl=, one must be able to distinguish between the two brands of foreign collaboration--the inward-oriented large-size foreign - 107 - collaboration firms and the new broed of outward-oriented small- and medium- size foreign collaborators. Under the right policies, the role of the former will gradually diminish. Furthermore, a negative perception on the inward- oriented MNCs should never lead to a wrong inference that most Sub-Saharan African countries can and should build their capacity to export without foreign collaboration. Seon, one must recognize the connection between the slowness with which the internal gap narrows--if at all--and the speed with which the external gap might widen. As potential foreign collaborators move quickly to other regions of the world where there is less internal gap and information gap, any hope of narrowing the external gap in most of the Sub- Saharan African countries may quickly disappear. 3. Excbange Rste 10.62 Without a realistic real exchange rate, any attempt to adopt an outward-oriented strategy wi'l hardly succeed. Until recently, exchange rates in uan' of the sample countries were overvalued, thus undermining the competi- tiveness of Africa's exports. Two separate approaches were adopted to deal with the overvalued real exchange rate: (i) nominal exchange rate adjustment; and (ii) compensation of overvaluation through cash grants. Based on the sample firms' comments, the experiences from these two approtches are sketched below. 1. Nominal Exchange Rata Adjuatment 10.63 In the context of structural adjustment programs supported by the IMF and the World Bank, a significant number of the 16 sample countries have devalued their currencies. Even though many-of these countries have a mixed record in their commitment to maintaining realistic real exchange rates through their continuing adjustment of the nominal exchange rates (shown below by a few examples), there is no better alternative than to continuing adjust- ment. - 108 - 10.64 Ghana appears to have maintained a realistic real exchange rate. All exporters in the sample also acknowledged that the cedi had become virtually convertible since access to foreign exchange was no longer problem- atic. The auction system is still in place, but the differential between the auction rate and the foreign exchange bureau rate has become negligible. 10.65 In Uganda, the new government engaged in a program of economic reform, supported by the IMF and the World Bank, in mid-1987. A' the time the reform program started, inflation was rampant and the exchange rate was significantly overvalued. At present, the exchange rate for non-coffee exports appears to reflect a realistic real exchange rate through the parallel market. In Zimbabwe the national currency has been rapidly depreciating in real terms since 1985 (18.4% between 1985 and 1988; 8% during 1989, and 12% during 1990). 10.66 On the other hand, Zambia abandoned several attempts to reach a realistic exchange rate. During the 1970s the country maintained a signifi- cantly overvalued exchange rate. Throughout the 1980s attempts were made to bring the exchange rate closer to a realistic level. In 1983, for instance, the kwacha was devalued by 35%. In 1985 a foreign exchange auction was introduced in a move to reflect market forces, but it was abandoned in 1987. Most recently Zambia has embarked again on an Economic Recovery Program and is targeted for exchange rate reform (a dual exchange system was implemented in 1990; it was unified recently). 2. ComDensation for Overvaluation 10.67 To compensate for the overvalued exchange rate stevming from the fixed exchange rate system, C6te d'lvoire introduced its export premium scheme (which also included a sort of fixed drawback) in 1986. Since the scheme was implemented, roughly 40 billion FCFA were paid out. Our interview results revealed, however, that even though all firms sampled were eligible for the - 109 - premium and had filed the required paperwork, no payments had been made since 1988. Also, as indicated in Annex II, the export premium system lacked transparency and automaticity. Most companies interviewed reported that their firms' investment and pricing policies had taken into account the export premium, and the scheme's failure had serious adverse effects on their international competitiveness. However, surprisingly, exporters appear to support the export premium system. 10.68 The Senegal's exchange rate compensation scheme--a flat 15% of value-added--maintains at least some transparency. But the scheme exists only on paper now because all payments have been interrupted since the summer of 1990, due to budget mismanagement. It is not surprising to see that most exporters support the nominal exchange rate adjustment approach. 10.69 The experience of the two countries shows the inferiority of the compensation approach, compared to the continuing adjustment approach, for maintaining international competitiveness. P. Primary Ingut Prices 10.70 Haintaining competitive primary input prices is one of the elements of the export policies. In several instances, firms in the different so-mple countries complained about distorted prices of primary inputs such as labor or agricultural inputs for manufactured goods. This section provides a few examples of non-competitive primary input prices that undermined African exporters' competitiveness, based on the firm interviews. 10.71 In Cote d'Ivoire, manufacturers interviewed in the textile and garment sectors were unanimous in their complaint that the price at which they had to buy locally giown cotton was the main obstacle to their international competitiveness. One garment manufacturer reported that , while on outside markets domestic cotton could be bought at CFAF900/kg, on the Ivoirien market, - 110 - its price would not go below CFAF1,800. Similarly, in Senegal, spun cotton is sold in the local market at a price exceeding the world market price for spun cotton by 17.5 percent. As tariffs imposed on this product average 30 percent, azd the duty-free import administration iF ineffective, exporters still buy cotton locally. Anothor example is the price of sugar in Senegal. A biscuit manufacturer reported that the firm could not compete in the international market unless he could buy sugar at the international market price, i.e., at CFAF120/kg. The administered price in the local market is CFAF1350. In theory, the 'Caisse de Pe:tequation' compensates manufacturers for the extra cost they incur, however, the scheme does not function properly. There is also a quota set up, entitling manufacturers to buy sugar at a discounted price. However, the quota is allocated on a discretionary basis, and was not sufficient for the manufacturer interviewed. The ratio of world market to local price for flour is similar to that for sugar. 10.72 The price of packaging materials is also higher in Cote d'Ivoire than that which would prevail under competition. Empty metal boxes used in canning are reported to be 20% to 40% higher than in France and Bangkok, respectively. the price of polystyrene boxes used for the export of fish is five times as high in cote d'Ivoire than in Tunisia. Note that the production of metal packaging materials is a virtual monopoly in the country, shielded behind high tariff barriers. In order to break this monopoly, some users of packaging materials have contemplated setting up their own production unit. 10.73 If the labor market is not competitive, then the resulting wages do not reflect the market prices undermining exporters' competitiveness. Labor costs which do not reflect underlying conditions of supply and demand but rather the strong position of labor unions in the country are causing a serious problem for Senegal's exporters. In mid-July 1991, the monthly minimum wage in Senegal was CFAF34,000. However, the actual monthly wage for semi-skilled workers.was in the CFAF60,000-100,000 bracket. Labor costs in Senegal compare unfavorably to those in neighboring countries. In Cote - 111 - d'lvoire for instance, the average monthly rate for an unskilled worker is similar as that in Senegal, but productivity is higher (about 208 in the fishing industry for instance, according to industry managers in Senegal. Similarly, in the plastics industry, one worker is responsible for four machines in Cote d'Ivoire, while in Senegal, one worker per machine is necessary). - 112 - XI. PHYSICAL TRADE INFRASTRUCTURE 11.01 Adequate physical trade infrastructure is a critical component for providing local firms equal-footing conditions with their foreign competitors. In many developing countries, physical trade infrastructure, such as port and transport facilities, roads, telecommunications, and utilities, are not comparable to the infrastructure in more industrialized countries. Shortcom- ings in physical trade infrastructure often add significantly to production costs, for instance by causing additional inventory costs that in turn are incurred because of inadequate access to transportation, or the high cost of operating an electricity generator because the public electricity services are unreliable. Inefficient operation of infrastructure services by public agencies or private monopolies result in high costs. Such additional produc- tion costs make exports from developing countries less competitive in world markets. A. Survey Results 11.02 As reviewed in Chapter VII, the sample firms indicated that poor physical trade infrastructure is one of the major supply-side constraints on Africa's export growth. Also the questionnaires included specific questions related to physical trade infrastructure and sample firms' assessment of its adequacy. In one such question, interviewees were asked for their overall assessment of physical trade infrastructure. The remainder of this chapter will summarize the responses garnered from this question. Examples from sample countries will illustrate the trade infrastructure problems affecting many of them. 1. Air Transport. 11.03 Timely access to air transport is of particular importauce to manufacturers with orders specifying short delivery times or for perishable - 113 goods such as horticultural exports. Air access is also particularly impor- tant for island countries or countries that are landlocked. In Uganda, horticultural exporters complained about the lack of cargo-handling capacity and the high air cargo prices charged by the few carriers serving Entebbe airport. In addition, complaints were voiced about the monopoly that the national airline, Uganda Airlines, holds in cargo handling at Entebbe airport, which has led to serious inefficiency. Lack of cold-storage facilities at the airport were also cited as important barriers to exporting horticultural commodities. 2. Port Facilities/Services. 11.04 Exporters' complaints about ports were associated with port levies, freight handling, and frsight costs rather than with the actual physical condition of port facilities. For instance, in C6te d'Ivoire, interviewees criticized the excessive port tax. They also cited the Office Ivoirien des Chargeurs (OIC) for allocating all freight to various transport- ers, which creates bottlenecks, especially at peak times, and leads to high freight costs. For instance, the freight cost for a 20-foot container from Abidjan to Du:dkerque is more expensive than from Bangkok to Anvers, despite the distance being four times shorter, 11.05 In Senegal, port charges rank first among exporters' infrastruc- ture-related costs of production. In addition to high port taxes, compared to international standards, handling and forwarding operations are in the hands of highly unionized, oligopolistic powers. They set prices much higher than the prices that would prevail in a competitive situation. For instance, the cost of unloading a ton of fish costs FF100 in Dakar and FF60 in Abidjan. - 114 3. Road Transgort. 11.06 In several of the sample countries, civil wars have disrupted transport links. In Uganda, for example, feeder roads needed by non-tradi- tional agricultural exporters to move their produce, are in bad condition, although trunk roads are being rehabilitated. Inadeauate road conditions were cited by exporters in virtually all the sample countries. In C6te dl'voire again, the cost of road transport is almost prohibitive for exporters because transportation companies have managed to create an oligopolistic condition. One garment manufacturer reported that shipping a container from Hong Kong to Abidjan cost FCFA 780,000; the cost of transporting the container from the Abidjan port to his factory a short distance away (in the Coumassy Road area) cost FCFA 450,000. 4. Telecommunicati2ns. 11.07 Telecomunication services were judged inadequate by a majority of exporters. In Nigeria, these services are a major bottleneck for exporters. Internal as well as external communication by telephone, telefax or telex is unreliable and time consuming. In Tanzania, the telephone system is so unreliable that even making intra-city calls in the capital is extremely difficult. One exporter remarked that firm employees frequently have to commute long distances between two locations of the factory in order to handle administrative problems face to face rather than on the telephone. In fact, in Tanzania and Mozambique most exporters rely on telex or, more generally, on radio for communication outside of the capital. In Madagascar, international telecommunications--via satellite--were judged adequate; however, many exporters complained that internal telecommunications were often problematic. Also, difficulty in communicating with South Africa, a poten- tially important trading partner, was noted by several exporters as a serious disincentive to expanding trade with that country. Finally, in Swaziland insufficient telecommunication capacity is considered the result of underes- - 115 - timated demand for such services and of the growth of industrial areas in the country over the last few years. 5. EnerXy anA Water. 11.08 Unreliable energy services present a big problem for manufactur- ers. In Nigeria manufacturers reported that power service is so irregular that firms are forced to generate their own electricity, escalating their investment and operating costs significantly. Concerning water, many firms reported that they had to install their own wells and pay dwelling fees. 11.09 In C6te d Ivoire, three-quarters of the firms interviewed stated that the high energy costs are the major factor causing them to remain uncompetitive in world 2arkets. For instance, the price of a liter of fuel in Abidjan is FCFA108, while the world market price is FCFA55. In addition, the cost of water in the country is very high; the price of water is fixed at FCFA400/m3, which affect particular textile manufacturers and fish processors. In Senegal, the cost of electricity ranks second in exporters' estimates of infrastructural costs. The average rate for electricity is FCFA69/kw/hr, which is high compared to FCFA15 in Ghana and FCFAF16 in Tunisia. Note that in addition to pricing policy-issues, additional costs arise from the poor quality of the electricity services. As for water, its tariff stood at FCFA344/m3 in mid-1991. This also compares unfavorably with most neighboring countries. 11.10 Manufacturers in other sample countries reported similar problems. In Swaziland, the electricity system has become overburdened because of rapidly increased industrial demand; in Uganda, power outages are a common occurrence. In Botswana, water charges are very high. - 116 - B. Strateaies to Correct Poor Physical Trade Infrastructure Service 1. Reforms in Trade Infrastructurg Services 11.11 Port charges. Exporters in many sample countries stated that very high variov1s port charges (other than duties) levied by the government agencies undermine seriously their free trade status. Drastic reforms are needed either to remove these charges or to reduce them drastically. Such reforms would not be difficult if there is a strong commitment by the govern- ment on export development. 11.12 Service monopoly. Again, drastic actions are needed to bring competitive mechanisms in freight handling, transport, and public utility services by breaking inefficient monopolies. Private firms' entry into the trade infrastructure service needs to be liberalized. In particular, private generation of electricity for commercial purpose or own use needs to be allowed. For example, in Togo, the issue of firms' autonomous power supply is still pending. Some exporters who were interviewed stated that they thought they could lower the energy costs significantly by generating their own power. 2. Priority on Trade Infrastructure Building 11.13 Good physical trade infrastructure is a necessary condition for trade development. The immediate and most negative impact of poor trade infrastructure is the difficulty in bringing potential foreign enterprises for export collaboration into the African countries. The next critical impact is the difficulty in achieving competitiveness in the world market. 11.14 Because of the resources required for trade infrastructure building, a comprehensive medium to long-term planning is essential. If a developing country that lacks the basic trade infrastructure is planning to build an EPZ, then it is critical that the EPZ construction plan has to be a - 117 - part of a comprehensive plan to build trade infrastructure. An EPZ is just an industrial estate with factory buildings to rent, and the EPZ will not be successful in inducing foreign and domestic companies if it is not close to the preexisting good trade infrastructure. - 118 - XII. DIRECTION OF FUTURE WORK A. Priority in Building a Competitive Edee in Most Sub-Saharan African CourLe9 12.01 In setting a priority for building a competitive edge in most Sub- Saharan African countries, an unambiguous criterion that can guide national and international assistance policies has become apparent: the high demand by African private enterprises for foreign entergrise collaboration (particularly for specific types) for export activities. 12.02 Considering the increasing emphasis on private sector-initiated, market-oriented industrial development in Sub-Saharan African countries, it is gratifying to find high demand, as well as preferences for specific types of foreign enterprise collaboration, by the new breed of outward-minded African private entrepreneurs. There cannot be a better indicator than this on which to base national and international assistance schemes for private sector development. 12.03 Our paper has also revealed that the immediate priority in human resource development in most Sub-Saharan African countries may have to be for on-the-job training and learning-by-doing. This would take place on the factory floors and in sales rooms of export-oriented foreign collaboration enterprises. Thus, private firms' demand for foreign collaboration can be an effective guide for human resource development schemes as well. 12.04 Therefore, for private-sector and human resource-development objectives, meeting the demand for foreign collaboration should be an immedi- ate practical goal. This would apply as well as to outward-oriented develop- ment objective in most Sub-Saharan African countries. - 119 - B. Strategies to Narrow the External Gap Between High Demand for. and Negligible Supply of (Exnort-Oriented) Foreign Collaborators 12.05 This paper articulates the view that the'biggest -development challenge in most Sub-Saharan Africa countries may be how to devise imagina- tive strategies for narrowing the enormous extenal gap between the high demand for, and negligible potential supply of, export-oriented foreign (enterprise) collaborators. Such strategies must have three distinct compo- nents: (i) strategies to narrow the intrnal gaa between local private enterprises' and managers' high demand for (export-oriented) foreign collabo- ration, and the government agencies' restrictive policies; (ii) strategies to narrow the information goa between potential foreign and domestic collabo- rators; and (iii) strategies to improve physical trade infrastructure. 12.06 As stated at the outset, the purpose of this cross-country study was to find a common approach to common problems. This chapter, therefore, suggests the direction of future work for two of the components--designing common strategies to narrow the internal policy gap and the information gap. C. Strategies to Narrow the Internal Gap Between Private EnterRrises' High Demand for. and Government Agencies' Restrictive Policies on (Export- Qriented) Foreign Collaboration 12.07 Common strategies to narrow this internal gap would consist of three elements: (i) an awareness cam=aian on the critical importance of for- eign/domestic enterprise collaboration'for private sector and human resource development, as well as for outward-oriented development; (ii) the absolute necessity of goverrnent commitment (to implement export policy instruments effectively); and (iii) technical know-how to implement these policies and instruments. - 120 - 1. Awareness CamRaijn 12.08 For African policymakers who are uncertain about the impact of extensive foreign collaboration, and who are influenced by their negative images of inward-oriented large-size MNCs, the following two points need to be emphasized. First, as most of the African countries adopt outward-oriented policies, the influence of the MNCs will diminish, and the role of the new breed of outward-oriented small- and medium-size foreign and domestic enter- prises will increase. Furthermore, many large MNCs may not be interested in any new manufacturing activity in Sub-Saharan African countries (whether export-oriented or domestic market-oriented) in the near future because they have better locations around the world. Second, the debate on the negatives vs. the positives of foreign/domestic collaboration seems very much outdated in this rapidly changing world, in which all developing and developed coun- tries are pursuing outward-orientation through international enterprise collaboration. Particularly by novi, it should be realized that bringing in foreign collaboration is not a mere bilateral matter--most Sub-Saharan African countries have to compete with all the other developing countries that are attempting to collaborate with the limited number of potential foreign collaborators. For most Sub-Saharan African countries, the time for collabo- ration may be running out because the potential stock of new foreign collabo- rators in the OECD countries and NIEs has been shrinking drastically. African firms' potential partners have been relocating largely to other parts of the world. 2. Commitment 12.09 Even small changes in customs procedures can hardly be implemented effectively if front-line agencies fail to get a signal from the top level of government for absolute commitment to implementation of regulatory and other export policy reforms. - 121 - 12.10 It may be useful to note the special institutional mechanisms used by policymakers in the East Asian NIEs (such as Korea's Monthly Trade Promo- tion Meetings). These send repeated signals to the entire country about the unshakable commitment of the government to effective implementation of the policy instruments for an outward-oriented strategy. 3. Know-How 12.11 EfZective implementation of some export policy instruments requires a certain degree of technical expertise, which can only be provided by those who actually have had long institutional experience designing and implementing such schemes. Most Sub-Saharan African countries can barely handle institution-building to achieve the effective implementation of these schemes alone. This is an area where an integrated approach that would include many of the Sub-Saharan African countries would pay off. 12.12 For example, successful implementation of duty-exemption and duty- drawback systems depends on the manner in which the imported input-output coefficients are handled. If the ad hoc and piecemeal approach to these coefficients, which is currently the approach most African countries are using (and is one of the root causes of ineffectiveness), is replaced by a systems approach supported by a possible pool of resources that may be used by many Sub-Saharan African countries separately, and supported by the requisite expertise, then maximum common efficiency can be gained with minimum common resources. - 122 - D. Stratesies to Narrow the Information Gap Between Potential Foreign and Domestic Collaborators 1. Ineffectiveness of Cugrent Match-making Mechanisms 12.13 Our study confirmed the ineffectiveness of the existing public, international, and private mechanisms for match-making between potential small- and medium-size outward-oriented foreign collaborators in the OECD countries or in the NIKs (who may have had no previous involvement in Africa) and their counterpart entrepreneurs in Sub-Sahar&n Africa. This implies the ineffectiveness of these mechanisms to narrow the information gap between potential foreign and domestic collaborators who would likely be involved in export-oriented industrial activities in Africa. The information gap is further aggravated by foreigners' negative perceptions of Africa and the current internal (policy) gap (discussed above). Also, the fact that no effective mechanism has been used to cover the risks that potential export- oriented small- and medium-size foreign collaborators encounter does not help the already bad situation. 2. Preference for Foreign/Domestic Private "Enterprise Collaboration" As Onnosed to Technical Consulting or Technical Assistance-Tyne "Personnel Collaboration" 12.14 The study confirmed that the dominant preference of most Sub- Saharan African private enterprises is for "foreign private enterprise and domestic private enterprise collaboration." This would be in the form of technical/marketing/management agreements, joint ventures, or subcontracts that integrate know-how acquisition with access to the world market. 12.15 Past development objectives--in terms of African firms' need for foreign enterprise collaboration for export activities--were met primarily by alternatives. Such substitution was based on the premise that foreign firms' - 123 - reluctance to become involved in Africa was a private decision based on international market mechanisms, and therefore only alternative modes (such as technical consulting-type personnel collaboration rather than foreign private enterprise collaboration) were available, particularly for African firms. This approach seriously ignored the information gap and African firms' desperate need for foreign private enterprise collaboration. It appears that no serious consideration was given to the better alternative of putting the resources associated with personnel collaboration into mechanisms and schemes to reduce the information gap, thus to give a fair chance to foreign enter- Drise collaboration. 12.16 The main reservation about "domestic enterprise-foreign personnel collaboration (i.e., technical consulting or technical assistance)" from the point of view of most Sub-Saharan African private firms is that because of the infant stage of African industrial export development, there is no guarantee that resources spent for technical consulting or assistance not directly linked to external market access are going to result in proper returns. In most cases, only foreign firms that are currently players in the established world market network have the capability to link up with the external market. Most small- and medium-size exporters and potential exporters indicated that the most effective way to infiltrate the established external market network is to rely on the existing market networks of established firms. Careful re- evaluation of the current approach being taken by international assistance schemes primarily relying on foreign personnel collaboration for export development may be justified. 3. Imaginative Approaches 12.17 From the above evidence, it is obvious that it would require an extraordinary vision of development to devise imaginative common strategies for most Sub-Saharan African countries to overcome the information gap between potential foreign and domestic enterprise collaborators for export activities. - 124 - 12.18 As stated above, the immediate national and international develop- ment assistance goal for the private sector and human resource development, as well as for the export development of most Sub-Saharan African countries, should be to meet private firms' high demand for export-oriented foreign gntergrise collaboration. Along with efforts to narrow the internal policy gap, new initiatives by the national and international assistance authorities to narrow the information gap need a high priority as well. 12.19 In considering common strategies to narrow the information gap, two institutions might play a catalytic role: (i) private match-making mechanisms; and (ii) outward-oriented foreign/domestic enterprise collabora- tion risk-coverage schemes. These mechanisms and schemes would be exclusively for Sub-Saharan African export activities. They would be designed to attract a new breed of small- and medium-size foreign enterprises whose strong negative image of Africa prevented them for considering Africa as a viable export-oriented foreign collaboration site. 12.20 As for the detailed work to design the above mechanisms and schemes, that is the future task to be carried out, based on an imaginative approach. But the premises underlying this effort would be the following. Eirst, putting national and international resources into developing private match-making meehanism that would be self-supporting in the medium-term, would be more efficient than putting public and international resources into public match-making mechanisms. Second, since export-oriented foreign and domestic enterprise collaboration would generate export earnings (which will not be possible without collaboration), (i) there would be enough incentive toward paying the full cost of private match-making and providing export-oriented foreign/domestic enterprise collaboration risk coverage, and (ii) there would be enough incentive for private match-makers to emerge if there were enough volume to serve, at least in the medium term. But without a visionary initia- tive by national and international authorities, such institution-building would rarely occur, just as it has not occurred so far. - 125 - REFERENCES Arrow, Kenneth (1974), "Limited Knowledge and Economic Analysis," Amrican Economic Review, Vol. 64, No. 1 (March 1974). Demirguc-Kunt, A. and R. Erzan (1991), "The Role of Officially Supported Export Credits in Sub-Saharan Africa's External Financing" PRE Working Paper Series No. 603, The World Bank. Koike, Kazuo (1987) "Skill Formation Systems: A Thai-Japan Comparison," Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 1987, pp. 408-440. Koike, Kazuo and Takenori Inoki (1989), An International Comnarison of Skill Devel2oment: South East Asia and Jagan. Tokyo: Toyokeizai, 1987 (in Japanese). Oman, Charles, (1989), New Forms of Investment in eve_qoling Country Indus- tries: Mining, Petrochemicals, Automobiles, Textiles, Food, Paris: OECD Development Center. Rhee, Yung Whee, Bruce Ross-Larson and Garry Pursell (1984) Koreas Competi- tive Edge: Managing the Entry into World Markets. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1984. Rhee, Yung Whee (1985), "Instruments for Export Policy and Administration: Lessons from the East Asian Experience," World Bank Staff Working Paper, No. 725. The World Bank. Rhee, Yung Whee (1989a), "Managing Entry Into International Markets: Lessons from the East Asian Experience," Industry Series Paper No. 11, Industry and Energy Department, The World Bank. (1989b), Trade Finance in Develoging Countries: Policy and Research Series, No. 5. The World Bank. Rhee, Yung Whee and Christine Soulier (1989), "Small Trading Companies and a Successful Export Response: Lessons from Hong Kong," Industry Series Paper No. 16, Industry and Energy Department, The World Bank. _____________ (1990), The Catalyst Model of Development: Lessons from Bangladesh's Success with Garment Exports." World Development, Vol. 18, No. 2. Rhee, Yung Whee, Katharina Katterbach, and Janet White (1990), "Free Trade Zones in Export Strategies," Industry Series Paper No. 36, Industry and Energy Department, The World Bank. Rhee, Yung Whee and Therese Belot (1990), "Export Catalysts in Low-Income Countries: A Review of Eleven Success Stories," "World Bank Discussion Paper, No. 12, The World Bank. - 126 - Rhee, Yung Whee (1991a), "The Role of Export Initiation in Economic Develop ment--Lessons from Korea." (Paper presented at the First Afro-Asian Banking School, Bangalore, India), The Journal of the Indian Institute of-Mankera, Vol. 62, No. 1 (January-March 1991). (1991b), "A Framework for Analyzing Choice of Alternative Duty-Free Import Systems by Foreign and Domestic Firms" (mimeographed), Industry Development Division, The World Bank. Stiglitz, Joseph (1989), "Markets, Market Failures, and Development" The American Economic Review, May 1989, pp. 197-203. UN Centre on Transnational Corporation (1988), Transnatginal Coxporatios in World Development: Trends and Prosnects. New York: UN, 1988. World bank (1989), Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth--A Long-Term PersRective Study, The World Bank. World Bank (1991), World Development Report. 1991, The World Bank. Young, Ernst (1990), Business Services in Internstional Trade and Invest ment Promotion: A Report oresented to the USAID, January 1990. a - 127 - ANNEX I Types of foreign collaboration and export orientation of sample firms interviewed in the 16 Sub-Saharan African countries Ta I COUNTRY A FIRM T'YPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXP. EXPORT SEEIUNG FOREtGN FOREIGN PARThER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- ESTAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALUE MARKE COLLABORA'lON? COLLABO- PARtTNER (OR PATRtIATR LUSED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RAIlON FOREIGN IN 1991 OR 1991) OR COLILABORAfION INFLUENCE) TAKEN 1991) 1. JV N/A Portugl 600 13 (ornay 1976 Tat*e 72% S7m Sub regi0% No 20) (knitted USSRo . ~~~~~~~~~fbic) S I No"e Sate CQ . N/A 0 1991 Prw, fith 100% S2m Eurup4 Yes (M*~4 (former (onr Arc set uip) co.) ) (ore 3. M Ag Slaw com South Afrks 650 (including 0 1981 citrus fruit 100% 50.6m South Yes fwmia- - - Africa _ _ _ _ _ 4. MA$ State Ca> USSR, Eatan 650 0 1973 Gannent 90% S5. USSR, Yes, :Nqpg N Eu (fle (knitted pastn m for .rkic Aggeolea) goods) Euntpep ao to Wesan _ .-,_._ __ _ __._. ._...___ ___ _ae S. JV NJA U.K. NWA 20 1986 Cotton, N/WA Eampe and No tomato pse (cottop), Far Fat . sit(d S1 _ ._ . _ i *i ,_5 0 .0 _____: .- _ ................... _ 2 1- - 1'' F Iab acolNy a FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXO. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- ESTAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALE MARKES COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARtTNER (OR PATRIA721S LISHBD 1990 OR (1I9 AND TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 9"91) OR COtLABORATION INFLUENCE) 1991) , _ . . . . .~~~~~~~~~~ OVER) . 1. TA, SC, L Prate Sl Laka CrA) 220 4 169 Garmt 100% $15 U.S. Yas TM AS or SC U.S.(S( (9) I TA. SC, L2 Prvate Si lanka (TA) 350 (toty 2 1969 arment 100% U5.5m U1& Ym desperate for TM US (SC) dosed dring (cho.t (90) Ag SC or N bInda (LI) 3/914191 due to skrs rIadton oft t)aket) 3. FDI, SC .S Lanka (PDI) 350 2 1990 Gament 100% N/A U& Yea, V for capac" U.& (SC) (o e _no 4. SC Prvae US. 320 0 1989 Garmet 100% NIA U.S Yes more SC r. JI Pte- UL (7%) 0 N/A 1969 Tents 20% NIA Sub regi_n, No South 6. V Private UJL 6000 (lnduding N/A 1967 Cand 9S% NIA Etc No (2%) _ 3000 in farm) -eMl - - - __ 7. V Slawe Co. Eupe 1500 S 1963 Food 5% $5 SUb Nrgi WA & LF Prvate India 25 0 1979 Hand tool Small $02n Zimbwe Y1a,desp ete for N fiacon (196S- or TA A& - - _. .________ (19B5-90) ___________ ___________________9 9. FO, ., LF Pivate German (O BL) WA 1 1965 Deal, 1S% N/A Sub regio NIA Indi (LI) (ign oMaet"c 10. JV, PrA PIte d 280 34 1966 TutU 90% of WA UJL Id* Yea 13$.ft (1PA) (spinning garmen Sub region 11. , T Ag, State Cob. SwhAa IFC, 210 N/A 1966 Fished 80% $Sm Eume Yes, T Ag and PTA FTA e kater Far BtCr Ag. 12. FDI . Swlead 16(50 1 1991 Frak ri 100% Sit 7n No rempormy) 0~~~~~~~~owem ew (lca I I 13 TN A�. LF rivat Europe (T)M AS) 700 3 1968 SpoIn 40 $In Sub mom Yes, 1w amFd" - - - -~~~~~~~~n~L - - - i4. TA, LY PrIgat | ma NAA | O $. Sub MMl 15. FDI . UUK 600 NIA 1959 PAC" S16M Sub Utic NO uL . | |Uing wftv. N 16. A& (tdiag < ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 I 1m TA4 Ag or N. f11- 1 FE 0 t 19S O Rube 0% N/A Subai deat Y _ _ I_ b oa) agmcj ) orders in 19.zt d iJV SS) 2 30 2 19 7 8 P oG bx e a 10 % 014 WY S u- N I A o ~_- -gA - - - Fi v a anD i ( d eaCm " 1 9 _ 1 9 46 S u o b e 0 A4 m S u b t eYb e N o 19: FV, TA, I1~ v Swxit e (J) ; t231 w 0 q e am tw b -- wmw is Mc ftic "PoopvSOAm o TabeS COUTRY C I.~~~~ _ _ __ . *_ . ..- r FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOAYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT E2K. EX. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF eX. 6STAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALUIE MARXETS COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRIATES IJSHED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 O)R 1991) OR COLLABORATION INFLUECE) 1991) I . . , . _ ~~~~~~~~~~~OVER) t. FO. TA. Priate Nomay (FO, TA) 400 4 1968 Farifure 959 WA En I Yes. FTC, FrA ~Genman (FM cadnai U.K _TA) _k - and It* 2. FO, TA, Private Nethrands (FO, 1200 NIA 1966 Tcxdte (wax 20% MIA Sub regio Yes, for mtatet aeem FrA TA) priots, U~S. _ _____ ._ U (FTA _ _.. - L, . __- 3. FDI. Gecman 50 2 1976 Woodea 70% N/A Yes housld S __.. .____ __ ithems - G 4. FDI . Koa 905 (sa: 750) 170 (sea: 150) 1978 Fisb 60% N/A Taa: No to UAS C. Res to ff mmmltet ._ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ as) _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ S. Taiwan 91 N/A 1989 Steel 10% WA Sub mrca No 6. PDI , US. ((cy an 15 1 1980 EmbrodMt 0% 0 . Yes, to take oer the sale) -toeyans 7. TA priae Sweden IA NIA 193 Canned juice 10%(40% NIA SubA kow Yes, for arket area expctd Northern when new Africa 8. LF Private Leb 200 NWA , NA Matre 30% NA Stb rba Yes 9. F____EL Private Fhnee 15 0 WA Garmt S% NA U.S. Yes, for market a 10. None P6vate . Ihe compa 0 1975 Gcarent 0% 0 Yes ,.~~~~~~~~~prtn 5.. yqaS _ _ A__ __ T ^k COUNTRY D FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAK EORT EXP. W. EXRT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- ESTAB- PRODUCT SHARE VALVE MARKE COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRIATRS LISHED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 1991) OR COLLABORATION INFLUENCE) TAKEN 91) 1. TA Pdvaue J_ (_ ak_ 560 0 1965 GanCt 5% NIA OECD Yes, T Ag PMA]6) (T41Nus) (bum) _ ... ._ 2. None Prate 2 0 1969 Hortculture 100% NIA Yce, TM Ag. 3. None Pritc a 5 0 1965 Hotctuure 100% MIA up Y, TM AM. 4. None Private . 2 0 1988 Horkullure 100% NIA em Yes, TJM Ag. 5. TM 4Ag Pointe U.S. S 0 1989 Vanil 100% SI515WO U.S NO .,~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~- Tae S: COUNTRY B FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOY- NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXP. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FORE3ION PARTNER FOREIGN MbENT IN OF EX- ESTA3- PRODUCr SflARB VALUE MARK6 COIAAlORATION? COLLA8O- PARTNER (OR 1991 PATRIAIeS LISHED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 1991) OR COLLABORATION INFLUENCE) TOAVKERN 991) 1. LP Prvate India 2_ 0 1985 Footwea 10% S12O00O Sub regin. Yea, M Ag. _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ ,__ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ .,__ _ _ _ U .K. 2. None PAivate . 200 0 1974 Chilies, 80% $300,000 Sub reon. Yet, JV dhalls Soutb _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Africa 3. LF Private Ina 60 0 1970 Dbalb. 99% 5600,000 South Yes, M Ag or SC $Marsy Africa. _ ___ __ _______ ____.__ I., Asbi 4. TIM Ag Pdvate Ta (TM Ag, 60 6 19 Gannent 33% $700000 US. No Mt A UC.(MI A) South M Ag South Aia (M Afrika AS) S. FDI . U K. 130 N/A 1975 Fishiag 100% WA US, No Flies Canada, Australia, _ * . ~~~~~ ~ ~ ~~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~Europe _ 6. LF Private India 200 0 1972 Garments 1% 5500,000 South Yet, TIM Ag or SC Afdca _ 7. JV Private U.K. 4400 20 1967 Trike 25% S6m Europe No 8. LF Private Pakistan SO 0 NIA 1975 Garment 20% $2r. U.S. Yes, TIM Ag. TIM Ag (up Taiwam to rea:ntV Ipt eal). FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EORT EXt. ANNUAL EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTHER FOREION IN 19 OF BX. SrAB- PRODUCT SARE - Esx. MARKS OOLLABORATION COLLABO- PARThR (OR PATRIAM L1SHED (t9 VAUE AND TYPE OF RATnON FOREIGN IN 1991 R OR VALMUO CA'OR INFLUENCE) TA9R 1991) 1 OR - . . . ___ OVER) _ - - 1. JV ates Famcea (0% 1100 1 (7 197 Tballe (Sc 35% N/A Eusp MThuc ltltc COMPMY ttwsl, 23 4004~~~~~~oeb hacy (gzq (rW7 ind ist being, at the dotEr); �1040); Sub i dnwtwt8. beginning) 10% -qo 2. JV State Fracs 1000 N/A 1922 Teio(gm 30% - Sub ele se tw ti _______ coany dloth, apetd S indus b being 3. PO NIA Fnce 200 2 N/A Texile 30% NIA Sub region Yes, for madkt ==L 4. FDI, TA Lebaum Frnch S60 3 1963 Ganna cr- 80% N/A Franc Yes, ekibn m SC. SC .(EI TA); shbit, (reet (90%); Sub Hmg K*(Sq_ pajamas) yeast) rcn S. IDI PFOP Lebsx Frech 300 3 1976 Garment 90% NIA Euree NO TA, BL (en)Sbrgn -_Hona .eKmw, . __e_____ - - - 4s 6. Nome Pwate . 10 0 1972 Gaent 0% for 7. PFA Pr c Frne e S 0 NIA Fashon Imegua N/A Frace Yes, for mrke ac 8. FDI - P 35 2 _ _ 1970 Lge 35% NA Aidn No 9. FDI I" . rPe 1500 N1A 179 Canned tuna 100% N/A Face No 10. FDI . Fane 1000 NI/A 1962 Canri tuna 100% N/A France No 11. PDT F0e 0 2 NIA F,n 80% N/A Fkance No .(_ - - - - - -amcd Table 6. COUNMY I (aUnL) 12. |P . 20 WA NIA Fislu 100% NIA E e 13. ,V a -___._ . ____ _ _.__A_ adivity Europe_Yes 13. tdnte Franch h2 NA WA 1989 Fob ting Stat NIA Fc .es tanning Co.; 1S% tFrnce _F.,ncb private aid 14. LF Lebanon 70 3 1983 Leather 25% NIA Sub rqpon Yes for mSaret -_________________ ____.___.____.__._ shoes , _.___ S _FDI Lebanon. Taiwan 100 15 1986 Plastic shoes 20% N/A Sub region No 16. LF PJdvat Lebano s0 0 1980 Plastic shos 0% - . Yes, for markt s MOand prodt desig, 17. FDI_ France 15 2 1965 Furniture 10% NIA Fane Ye, or market ac 18. FO Pfnvte Fraac 600 NWA 1986 �tlal onI 100% NIA France Yes for mant ac. (farmers) ~~~~~~~(for medacat use and ________ . _________ -spirits) ___ 19. JV Pdvate Fanc(F) 600 NIA 1956 Hand mad 0% Cigar to a FO swims F)cgars, a"por to cigWarts Europe banned ______________ ~now 20. iv Priate ue ( 2000 N/A 1982 COsetlans, 25% NIA Sub region No FO Franc F) (origin- detegents, palm oil, _________ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ ~ cotton, oIl 21. FE Pat Europe N/A N/A NIA Palm oil 30% N/A Eutope Yes. s bearcfor - refining pailnei. 22. FDl,(istaer Swbs 2700 NIA 1959 Coffee, 65% NWA Europe No companies) cocoa Sub raion Food roduct ___ _ _ _ _ _ .__ _ _ _ _ ___ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ milk) - - - 23 FD I _ U.s240 2 1966 Battedes 0% NIA S g No FDI - TIk7: COUNTRY ( FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXt. WORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN I991 OF EX- ESTArw PROIDUCT sHARE VALUE MARIE COIABORATION7 COLLABO PARTNER (OR PATRtATES LrSE (1"9 OR AND TYE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 191) OR COLLABORAON INFLUENCE3) TAKEN - 199) 1. FDI . UJC 290 6 1977 GU S N0% NMA Sub rgo No 2. DI Zm_ ia I 70 2 1979 Patks 85% NJ A Subye" Y.TJA.M . None pdv.e 42 0 1982 Ganei 0. . Yea 4. TA Prdve APDF 89 2 1974 Ganoea 10% WA Sub regio MIA 5. FDI . utc 7 - 2 t , I�87 rp p 90% VA Subreo1n Noll ,.U . S. ~~~rn - - ~~U.K. 7 2 1967 - p M 90% NMA Su k No TableS: WomJnT H ~~~~_ _ . -~ = . .. - _ _ TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EX?. EX. EXPORT SEEDaNG FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNIR FOREIGN IN 1991 OF Ex- ESrAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALUJB MARXKI COLtABORAION? CORABO- PARTHER (OR PATRIAS LSHED (199 OR 1990 AND TYPE OF RATION FORMIGN IN 1991 (O191RO COUARORAT1OX _ _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~OVBR1 1. PF, SC, TA Prvae Fne (FE, SC 850 A few 1987 Garunt 100% $11 FRance yea, acmpdm to UNIDO (TA) MAd km wsee oUS. embroldeay -adm &ONO TN - ~~~ -. _,._. .. _ m-at 2. FDI, SC, M Indan FraN 700 N/A 1991 Gamn 100% S15m USSRm Ye, atmpng to Ag DFDu have Facc sto other P>raSeISC. EC canuy n UMS USSR (II A) -a...s rbrouh TiM 3. D F 900 NIA 1987 Co_dmnS, 100% $35%000 FDDCC N/A 4. JV Pvae France 3S (phu b1m) N/A 1/1991 Dwuk Uvr, 50 535,000 NI/A toIanR (_dk coasen AM A widk Sol - -_- - - 5. N Stoe CO PSn FA 2,500 10 195 2 Taow 60% $10m No 6. LF,rvate 1 U 5) 7 NIA 1987 H 1009 120,00 US. Yes, V(w j 9 7. FDI,SC n12D NIA 19S I 10D9I) rane Y rl cah M AS & N_ Private Foca 200 ( ed .7 (apct| 1991 Man-|aae 100% MA NIA JV ha been acbieved 9. LF Prdvate 1 1989| Fhds, 100% s500,000 NIA N/A io. FDt - Fracc 80O 2 1949 C1OM, 70% |Ssooo0o N/A NIA | , i) (. _ 1, .u 1-_., 9: COUNTRY I fIRM ORIGIN OF EMPLOYAEBN` NUAMB YEAR RCRT EOR ANEXPOR PR EKNO FOREIGN . . _ COE _ INO , ESTAB. SHLRE _ ._RKEf !I8TER (O AiAm USE 19 RVLEAD TMOFMO -~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~I N99 1991 .O tVA WO O AT_ _ . IV NWA Suibgbm 2000 NA 1910 MIA N/ Eump No 2. iv NA lad aBrk"h 1ISO WA 9? lcadej 75% YAMn NA EU9o no I iv WA B*Ms IND0 NIA 19ow Coat..apm 2WA Bmp. No0 - - - - -~~~~~d" - 4~ . . N1 S. NV WA HagIoog (0) 41 WA 1914%2% / Sub feogls No (1954) sme~iUS. 4. Nioac Prvate too 097 Leather 10% NWA US. Yes 7. iv NWA LebinO (60%) ISO WA 1960 Leathr Smal 6 NWA itaIy/Pbad Yje for k.m Amm. a. Name Privat 135 Y 19 ar Lken mm f 9. NV WA -dso NWA 199 Gament 100% WA US. No ~.L.. .Ii bZlM.. ~. �. ,in1~.O. ~ --e m I1 N WA ladft 3000 NOA 1975 Al.m 5% N/A Sub raoa No 12. ame pivae 1200 I 1975 -Lah Srl % Yee, for Met am. 139. N WA Br eA 4000 (2000 I W A 1959 Sub o No (40%) _1aa 16.uoia 14. N primate Frc (80%) O 1990 Ps0d N/A F.ac .ob 15. DIV Bts R" uW NIA s19 7 From 80N5% N A Euo No 16. FE Pvate UJL 0 N/A Traing W9A N/A US; NO 1t R A (t S WA 19S9 ~~~~~~~~get o ERope b ..- - l2_,..._) 17. FE Prite U U. 2 0 1990 Thdlt an WA N/A tA No _ * = - _ == N [.bb1'0: COUNT J FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXP. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- ESTAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALVE MARWK COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PAMIATES LISHED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RA`ION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 1991) OR COLLABORATION INFLUENCE) TAKEN 1991) _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ OVER ) 7. N Pdate U.IC 27S 3 1987 Pine 100% N/A OBCD N South Afica tikm (%) . , . . _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Sulb regoe 2I FDI . South At8a to0 1 1989 Pi1e 100% NIA OECD No _________ __ _____ _____ __ _________ __ _ __ _ ttum ultur __ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ _ 3. FDI South Abica 464 3 1965 Sucakees 100% N/A South No 4. FDI South Atia 1S 3 1988 Wddin 90* NIA Sub regm No S. FDI Caaaa IJUL 6 2 1985 Had- 90% NIA Sub rgin No 6. P01 SootAI U.S. 50 2 196 Sates 90% NA OEM_ No 7. JV Prate IS 2 1967 Waa PUMP 90%m WA Suab regbl No I _ * . =.-- Tal Ii COUNTR K FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENTf NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EX?. EXPRT SEEKIN FOEIGMN FOREIGN PAR1NER FOREIGN IN 199L OF EX- ESTABE PRODUCT SHARE VALUE MARKT COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRIAT LISHED (1990 OR (19" AND TYPE OF RATnos FOREIGN IN 199 OR 199) OR COLLABORATIoN INFLUENCE) KEN 99t) - OVER~ -., - - 1. T AS Priae TAWa 146 2 198? BatteIs 25% M32Meo Sub negon Yes, at to 2. TA pzivat Europe 25 N/A low Fra *mlta lam 5140,000 Framee atrcaetn to ETA vegctabIcx. (Crab apn ales contact bull veact- iaHVW Opotbo.tb __________ _________ c~~~~~~~~~oncenta tes jbks 1) Aa. 3. FO private Belgim 147 0 1987 Househol 30% $3000 Sub mS$mo Ya.wat o este Ft~~~~~~~A1 (6lnes Ibmegh i rS - -O - 16? 0 1 - Hx X 4. LF Pivate lodi 3S 0 17 Gahvnlted Only I $5000 ZlSe Yes. TIM Ag. steel dset a _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ - contract _ __kw o 5. FE Pivate It6 62 0 1987 Gannents 30% S, BdxL N1A 6. N hime Begium, Germ 250 cdin 0 197S Qulnpina N/A S15000 A No _____ ________ seasonal 2 rmerab ._____ - - 1. Prte Fran 2 (120 sason NIA 1990 Vc 90 $125,000 Eup Yes, M A o . . . . ..= ,=,= Tb I COUNTRY L FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOY NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXORT ANNUAL XORT SEE G FORE1GN PARTNER FOREIGN MENT IN OF EX. RSTAB. PRODUCI SHARE EBPORT MARKEIS FOREIGN COLLAE0 PARTNER (OR 1991 PATRIATIS LISHED (1990 OR VAIUE COILABORA- RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 991) (19" OR TION? & TYPE OF INFm.UENCE) TAKN 199) COLLABORATION 1. FDI C.n 76 26 1o Garme jean., 100% $12. Ewa" NO 2. FDI Fbm 120 4 199 AembIy of 80-00 $2.7. Sub eion yet. ma._e_tg .__ _ .__ _ _ .__ _ bre and __ .tenme ,L I. NV PdIae Fane and 80 2 1990 Frn" dhimps 80% $Ism Franc YU Gen=w (13 mW~~~~~~~~an sea food 0 a3 ktwdbom 4. FDI . =(SOW,US, 70 NIA 1991. Fte himp 100% S1.0m F"c No 1992 ad gee lood S. FDI . Fsance 90 WA 1e90 80% S2.Om Suib No 6. FDtI. It*1taIl wke So 3 191 Shoe. 99% WA No NO Ultt OthEp9 ("bX h . . . _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Subr4 (3%) _ _ 7. Jv pvate Ftenda (pool of - . 12 P*tr1 Sub reon No _ _ _ _ _ bhw estosi _ _ _ _ ak ar a_ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ - - ._ __ .- ,X.w._,_ 8. MA, TA, Prinle GMn 140 A 1992 Garment W(. 80_6 $1pe5 Sub No LO . . _ __ . - (190i") -._. t( 9. MtA Sta eo. U.S 300 NIA 1985 Ste NIA WA Sub __in No 10. FDI Pm Leban - G o d a nt ( 100% Fraw, Sub No .~~~~~~~~IW h dkb~al) regiOn It. FDI . an$ too NVA 1990 amet oats 110% NWA US. No ___ ~~~~J d ___ _ _ _ ___ _ to _ _ 12. FDI Face 100 3 19B Food podc 70% SU. Sub regin No - __ __ ___ 13 EDI . N_l 79 1 I? Plac Iem WA Subriok No Demak . ___._ ( antubes ._.__.__- 14 Fe PPEvare Ewcur* 17 0 1974 wood 70% 501. Ua Yes IS. LF Pe Leba 60 4 1987 Axlnumm 10% WA Sub iomn Yes Ndo F 19 ar b9 e _eedieii A E er 10 s a pod ikvehor innWaERPZ Table : COUNTRY M FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXP. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- ESTAB- PRODUCT SHARE VALUE MARKETS COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRIATES LISHED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 1991) OR COLLABORATION INFLUENCE) TAKEN 1991) i________ -____ _ . OVER) 1. FDI U. K. 55 2 1978 Semi- 100% NIA Sub region No 2. JV Pratc NtA 65 3 1986 Semi- 100% MIA Europe No leather 3. Non" Pmtue - o 1 1988 Cut flowet 1000 _ NlA Europe Yes, M Ag. 4. FDI . U.K. 300 3 1964 Beans 5% NA Europe No 5. FDI Germany 1000 9 1973 Garments 60% S2.4m Europe No _ . ._ _ ,- . __ = - _).. _ Tabl 14: COUNTRY N FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXP. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- ESTAB- PRODUCT SHARE VALUE MARKETS COUABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRIAThS LISHED (1990 OR (1990 AND TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 1991) OR COLLABORATION INFLUENCE) TKN1991) l ~~~~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~OVE-R} _ 1. FD, SC Ita (FD 240 N/A 1984 Garden 10% $17S,000 N/A Yea, MOM TIM Ag of Sweden (SC) _ = furnitture , SC 2. Mt A State Co. Eurqe 1100 6(onlly 197 Coton 70% $3m N/A N/A 3. FDI, SC India (FDI) 350 3 (orinll 1960 Housebold 25% $17S,00 N/A N/A __________ Swede (SC) _I _ 12 textile 4. FDI India 300 N/A 1984 Sisal twina 8s% $4m U.S. N/A 5. N Stte Co. U.K. NfA N/A 1985 Tea 80% S35m N/A N/A 6. None Private N/A NIA 1974 Gem stone 75% $220,000 N/A cutdt Ango 7. TA Sate Co. Swlzedland 2000 0 198 Tetile 20% SIm Enwpc Y Img claoainwith a Komsn MNC 8. FFD1, TA, - I (FUX. TA) 130 3 1978 Automoie SO% $200000 Sub wkgpm, N/A FrA U__ ___ _ rdlaomUJC. Table I COUNTY 0 =~ ~ ~ ~~~~~. i _ _- ___ ..- _ FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EXP. EXPORT SEEKING FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX- S1STAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALUE MARK� COLLABORATION? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRIATS LlSHED (1990 OR (1990 AN4O TYPE OF RATION FOREIGN IN 1991 (OR 199) OR COLLABORATION INFLUENCE) TAKEN 1991) _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _O V ER ) _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ _ 1. JV Priate Tnolaa 60 0 1986 Sugar I'l0% NIA Sub re"o Yes 2. JV Private Spain (35%) 207 36 (ma on 1979 Froe and 100% NWA Hump. No (65%) aNps) - ance, E 3. FDI U.S 68 2 (o*rI l 1983 phrmaen u 60% NrA Sub region No _ ..~__ __ ._ _ _ _ _ _ ._._.__ cal nendds .__ _ ._ _. 4. 1A . &ukina Faso 130 0 N/A Rubber sir 60% NIA Sub regio Yu difficub _1=A(rA) S. JV riate KOa 70 5 _ 193 Afrkaen hair 60% N/A Sub egio Yes __ FDI K KO 80 7 18 Afrkan hair 60% NIA Sub region Yes 7. LF PrvLebano so 50 2 1984 Pask 60% N/A Sub on Yet sign SC wthb SC Frenc (signig sandals Prance _ 5C ~~~~~~~SC)_..___Fae|t 8. FDI Frante 100 o 198 ChilU 100% WA Fta=cc Yes .______ ..______. sandals _ > 9. JV Pdite Franc (5%) 820 8 19S5 Tetle 25% WA Sub region, Yea (95%) (. US ____ .______ _______ Franca 10 LF Priate Lebano (I 250 2 1991 Textle 20% N/A Sub reo Yes TA Prane (TrA FO) (odgin. (bazin- FOaly fc) 11. LF Pdvatc Lebon (L 160 1 1985 Cotton 14% WA Sub region Yet FL Fnce (D. FO) (oign thbreat FO ally 12. NV Prvatc Ws BEC. 950N WA 199 Gament 0%. lbo "A Europe Yet Frnkh (WCE) co. wn t) bankaqt bfoe sUer Ome year of 13. LF Private Lebanon 100 N/A :1994 plastic items 40% WIA Sub region Y without foreign 14. LF Private Lebanon 60 W/A 1983 Plasic Items 20% W/A Sub reaion Yes 15. FDI Lebanese (Orom 300 NWA 1983 Plastic shoe 30% NWA Sub region Yes, M AS or SC to Cote dlvoire) ctrMbe . J I I I markm~~O - 145 - _ - _ _ - _m -! __ -,- -] -_ -f - -i X, fi -f f s} XJ a!1 - ~~~~ 1 - - - - - - - i Tabk 16 COUNTRY P _ - - _ _ . _ _ * _~._ ,_ __. FIRM TYPE OF LOCAL ORIGIN OF EMPLOYMENT NUMBER YEAR EXPORT EXP. EX?. EXPORT SEENG FOREIGN FOREIGN PARTNER FOREIGN IN 1991 OF EX. ESrAB- PRODUCr SHARE VALUW MARKE1 COLLABORAJON? COLLABO- PARTNER (OR PATRLAIAS LISHED (1990 OR (199 AND TYPE OF RA1ION FOREIGN IN t991 (OR 11) OR COLLABORAlON INFLUENCE) TAK 1991) l l . . ~~~~~~~~~~~~~OVER). 1. Prvte EC (TM Ag) ISO 1951 Pbagaett 10% t VA Sub vo LF ____U.K (LF) ___cl I TA Piate Japa (twa4-y 30 0 1984 sewin 0% Ye I TA Prvate EC (fA) IVA NIA 1967 Footwer 25% NIA Eupe Y, TM Al. LF UAL (LF empoienx 4. TA ?iato NIA CrA) 1000 1 1931 Packah0a S% NlA Sub reio Yes, TIV AC - - - -U.K IJ71 iiii- I S. LF Pte U.K. (f) 700 0 1941 Rolag 65% Sub reion NA FO NA stock, stee _ __ __ __ . nk ._ _ 6. LF Privt U.IC 2100 0 1960 Gsn=U 5S% NtA South Yet, TM At, (0%) 7. V Pate U. I 700 O 1953 Pa7g % (40% N/A Sub ngo NIA LF m,esials labfnalm - 147 - Anng2;11 SAMPLE EXPORTERS' COMMENTS ON DUTY (INDIRECT TAX, AND RESTRICTION)- FREE AND FOREIGN EXCHANGE ACCESS/ ADNINISTRATION FOR RAW MATERIAL/IXTEPJEDIATE INMUT/AND CAPITAL GOODS FOR EXPORT PRODUCTION 1. Botkfia A duty drawback system has been implemented. As 85% of Botswana's imports arrive duty-free from South Africa (under the Southern African Customs Union.11) and from Zimbabwe (under a bi-lateral trade agreement), the system is not much used by exporters. It does not appear that the special incentive program for 100%-export-oriented firms in Selebi-Phikwe includes a special free-trade status, such as a BMW or EPZ, other than the drawback system. It does not appear that exporters are encountering problems in access to foreign exchange, due to the country's abundant foreign exchange reserves. 2. Burundi An improved duty drawback scheme and a scheme for the reimburse- ment of transaction taxes have been introduced recently. However, exporters are not yet sufficiently familiar with the new duty drawback scheme, and some are confused by the new pi 2 X,es. Also, since most of the firms interviewed are only partial exporters, &..dy tend to be dissuaded from using the drawback scheme because of the complicated procedures. The import licensing require- ments (the license is granted for only six months and is required for each product) have been a burden for some exporters. Exporters' access to foreign 1/ The Southern African Customs Union (SACU) includes South Africa, Namibia, Lesotho, Swaziland, and Botswana. South Africa collects customs duties for all members states' imports from outside the union and collects excise on local production. As a result, member states have relied heavily on imports from South Africa. - 148 - exchange appears to be problem free, primarily because foreign exchange reserves are currently strong. 3. Cote d' Ivoire An export premium was designed to compensate for the tariffs paid on import duties as well as to compensate for the overvaluation of the FCFA. From August 1986, when the scheme became effective, to February 1990, 79 enterprises have availed themselves of export premiums. Although all sampled companies were eligible under this scheme, no payment has been made since 1988, due to lack of funds and mismanagement. Exporters indicated that access to, as well as the amount of, the export premium scheme lacked transparency and automaticity. In addition, the procedures are long and cumbersome. In turn, a major share of exporters are relying on a BMW scheme (Admission Temporaire) for their duty-free imports. But two of the firms interviewed indicated that they deliberately refuse to use it because of the administra- tive hassle it entails. Larger companies have customs officers posted on their premises, but rarely is the relevant officer present at the right time. Delays, transportation costs, and overtime rapidly add up. Some manufacturers report they are unwittingly in default at all times because of these bureau- cratic constraints: delays to renew the agreement, to obtain an approval, to locate a customs officer, etc. There is no foreign exchange access problem, even though difficulty in having access to financing (see below) may indirect- ly limit access to the foreign exchange needed to import materials for export production. 4. Ghana Thirty percent of the sampled companies have applied the duty drawback scheme, but to this day, none has received refunds. According to the Ghana Export Promotion Council (GEPC), only three to four companies have actually availed themselves of this scheme. GEPC, as well as exporters, has - 149 - advocated the adoption of a duty exemption system, but no decision has been made. The bonded warehouse system is currently in operation, but its regula- tory framework may need to be revised. It suits only the needs of large companies that mainly import large consignments of the same goods. One company visited had a bonded warehouse where they only stored their bulk orders. Firms do not appear to have any problem in accessing foreign exchange through the auction system, even though difficulties in getting financing may indirectly limit access to the foreign exchange neec3d to import goods. However, it does not appear that there is a built-in mechanism that guarantees exporters' access to foreign exchange in the event of a foreign exchange shortage. 5. KeDya The only duty-free import scheme in operation until 1989 was the Export Compensation scheme, which can be considered a fixed-drawback system with a uniform drawback rate of 20% of export value for all listed export products. This disregards actual duty payments as a proportion of associated export value. The BMW system was introduced in 1989, and there were about a dozen garment factories operating under BMW licenses at the time of our interviews. In 1990 the EPZ law was enacted, and one factory was in operation within a private EPZ that had 12 completed factory buildings at the time of our interviews. Finally, the government introduced the duty exemption system, which is for those exporters that are exporting the li3ted products but that choose not to use the Export Compensation Scheme. Effective implementation of the duty exemption system will take time because the necessary implementation mechanisms, including estimates of imported input coefficients, have yet to be in place. Most exporters current- ly relying on the Export Compensation scheme indicated that they prefer the fixed drawback system to the duty exemption system because of the reduced paper work of the former. They expected delays in importing duty-free items - 150 v even though the current Export Compensation scheme has its own problems in terms of payment delays, associated working capital needs and interest charges, and only partial compensation of duties related to export commodities heavily relying on imported inputs. However, to make the fixed drawback system more rational in terms of providing close-to-free trade status, the more realistic fixed drawback schedules, which are close to actual duty payments for different products, have to be offered. Also, since the duty exemption system is very inflexible under the current implementation rules, only exporters with confirmed L/Cs are allowed to use it. Therefore, for exporters that stockpile their products before receiving export orders, a new individual drawback scheme has to be introduced if the government wants to ensure equal access to free trade status for them. In turn, exporters using the BMW scheme complained that although customs officials monitor factory operation around the clock, as well as accompany all container shipments from and to ports, the exporters have to put up expensive separate bonds for ports, container shipments, and factories. They also have to pay various high port charges and custom officials' overtime fees. BMWs in most developing countries do not require such bonds, and exporters do not pay such high charges and fees. All garment exporters with the BMWs export under subcontracting arrangements. They indicated that one of the major reasons the} cannot switch from subcontracting to L/C-based exports and imports--even when they know that L/C-based exports and imports would provide better profit margins--is their extreme uncertainity about undisrupted and speedy access to import licenses and foreign exchange to import the raw materials and intermediate inputs under L/Cs. For L/C-based imports they must have import licenses for every transac- tion in order to have access to foreign exchange, whereas for consignment- based imports (needed for sub-contracting production) such licenses are not required. These licensing requirements have been imposed mainly due to the uncertainty about the availability of foreign exchange to back up the licens- - 151 - es. This is evidence that there is no built-in mechanism that guarantees speedy access to foreign exchange for imported inputs for export production on a priority basis. 6. Madagascar The BMW scheme is hardly used, and the drawback system is not used at all, since no reimbursement mechenism is in place. The most commonly used scheme is the duty exemption system. However, several firms expressed concern about administrative requirements and cumbersome procedures that allot considerable discretionary power to customs. Even firms operating under the EPZ regime, complain of administrative hassles. Several firms in the garment industry remarked about the lack of experience, integrity, and commitment of customs officers. Inflexible application of the regulations governing free trade status causes problems also. For example, exporters of agro-products complain that, according to regulations, inputs cannot be removed from the factory; therefore agro producers have a serious difficulty convincing custom officials about the ultimate use of seeds imported duty-free. Another example is the problems of obtaining a tax waiver for the transport vehicles used for carrying fresh vegetables for export. Another firm complained about the 10% minimum import tax, in addition to customs duties, on machinery imported for export production (for example, slaughterhouse equipment used for duck liver production). 7. Malawi Even though import duties are quite low (less than 10% on raw materials and capital goods), a major difficulty for the exporters interviewed is that duties are charged on the full landed cost of an item, which is expensive because of the high transport costs for goods imported into Malawi. In addition, all Malawi businesses with a turnover of NK10,000 must register and pay a surtax. According to the 1988 Export Incentive Act and the Custom - 152 - and Excise Act, duty drawbacks on inputs and machinery, zero rating for surtax, and BMW for exporters are allowed. Most of the textile/garment manufacturers interviewed are using the pilot BMW scheme. Several firms have shifted from the duty drawback system, which they found to be too slow. FIAS has suggested that more transparent criteria for eligibility in the BMW program would be necessary, including a negative list of ineligible products, locating factories both inside and outside of industrial parks, and allowing duty free entry not only for material but also for machinery. Introduction of a duty exemption scheme has also been suggested. 8. Mozambigue In principle, all investors are exempt from import duties on inputs or materials used for export production with a value-added higher than 35% (or for products for the domestic market when value-added exceeds 45%). All certified foreign investors are exempt from import duties on inputs and raw materials used for export production. A duty drawback scheme may be used although there is no formal drawback scheme as such. In addition, the vague provisions do not cover certain inputs that are necessary for exports (such as chemicals or Wax for fruit production and export). A BMW also may be used. A textile exporter is trying to obtain BMW status for its factory. One of the priorities of the newly-created Export Promotion Agency (IPEX, June 1991) is to design an adequate duty drawback scheme; draft was in preparation at the time of the survey. Exporters also complain about the 7.5% import tax (as well as the corporate income tax of 50%, customs fees on imports for export production, and an export tax of 5-10%). All exports have to be licensed, and customs clearance is very slow. The government, with the assistance of the UK Overseas Development Administration, has prepared legislation for the estab- liskment of an EPZ regime. An EPZ plan was submitted to the government by Hong Kong developers who want a site for Hong Kong investors wishing to - 153 - relocate abread; no positive response has been given. In turn, exporters have access to foreign exchange through the secondary foreign exchange market (established recently) or through the exporters' foreign exchange retention scheme. However, due to foreign exchange shortages, it is unclear whether exporters' foreign excl;nge demands are automatically met. 9. Nigeria Half the exporters interviewed had applied for the duty drawback scheme. Ineffective implementation of the scheme is evident from the fact that one exporter received the drawback some two years after applying, and half the exporters interviewed had not applied at all, because they reckoned that their export volume did not justify their application or because the estimated cost, in terms of bureaucratic headaches, exceeded the expected returns. Others were waiting to be granted the right to manufacture under a BMW scheme. However, despite the efforts by the Nigerian Export Promotion Council and exporters, a BMW scheme or duty exemption system has not been instituted yet. While the foreign exchange auction system (implemented recently) and the foreign exchange retention scheme (25% of export proceeds) have eased the foreign exchange access problem, access to foreign exchange for importing raw materials and intermediate inputs for export production is not absolutely guaranteed on a priority basis. Exporters reported that under the current auction system, foreign exchange is allocated to the banking system which does not have any incentive to ensure exporters' priority access to foreign exchange. Exporters report that they frequently resort to a number of "gimmicks" to meet their import needs: they open accounts in a dozen or more banks and /or break down their invoices, and resort to purchasing foreign exchange at a higher price on the "black market." But such a market does not enable them to open L/Csl - 154 - 10. SeneeAl The Dakar EPZ (Zone Franche Industrielle de Dakar, or ZFID) was inaugurated in 1975. As of July 1991, eight industrial companies were operating in the EPZ. All eight companies pointed out the ineffectiveness of the zone administration. The following are some examples of their complaints. An EPZ enterprise indicated that it experienced 280 power breakdowns in one year. The firm complained about the government's failure to ensure true free trade status, because firms are forced to pay the so-called COSEC tax at the seaport (0.3% of total export value) and the ASECNA tax at the airport. Other complaints targeted: the extra transportation costs that stem from the failure of one-stop service at the zone; the EPZ's location which is 18 km away from town; the high annual EPZ fee (CFAF 5.8 million for each company); and the rents. Most exporters outside the EPZ rely on the duty exemption system ("Admission Temporaire"). We were not able to evaluate the effective- ness of the system in great detail. 11. Swaziland There is no duty-free import scheme. Since Swaziland is a menber of SACU and its economy is heavily integrated with the South African economy, there is no need for such a scheme so long as imported inputs for export production come from South Africa. However, there is no means of duty-free access for imported inputs (for export production) that come from outside SACU. Likewise, access to foreign exchange is automatic as long as the goods to be imported are covered by an import permit issued by the Ministry of Finance. The processing and obtaining of import permits are reportedly adequate. - 155 - 12. Tanzania A duty drawback scheme was recently introduced (1988/89) but has not been used much. Exporters complain about long delays in reimbursement by the Board of External Trade (up to nine months), thus tying up scarce capital. Since not all exporters are eligible, this situtation encourages smuggling. There is no compensation for capital equipment and spare parts, and the system involves complex administrative procedures. Partial exporters are at a greater disadvantage, because of difficulties estimating input-output coeffi- cients. The Board of External Trade also charges a commission. For example, one textile importer, that has to import various inputs (dyes for its textile production), has renounced any claim to a drawback because of the many compli- cations. A bonded warehouse scheme apparently is used by a few large textile producers. Exporters also complain about the sales-tax burden. Although an Open General License System and a General Export Retention Scheme with a uniform retention rate of 35% for non-traditional exports have eased the foreign exchange access problem, it does not appear that exporters' access to foreign exchange is guaranteed on a priority basis, due to the shortage of foreign exchange. A number of exporters interviewed were uncertain about their import licenses and associated foreign exchange availability and worried about delays in honoring L/Cs. 13. Togo Customs procedures are reported to be exceptionally smooth and speedy. Beyond the rapidity of customs clearance--it takes a maximum of a week to clear goods out of customs--the lack of "hassle" and uncertainty in customs operation is noteworthy. (In neighboring Nigeria, it is reported that production schedules are often disrupted by various problems encountered in customs.) All exporters interviewed acknowledged the smoothness of export - 156 - procedures and the comprehension and flexibility of customs officers. Exporters seem to have no major complaint about the "admission temporaire" scheme. In turn, a decree instituting an EPZ was promulgated in September 1989. As of late August 1991, 17 companies had been granted the "accord definitif" (final agreement), out of which 10 had already started operations (and four were already in operation); 19 had been told "accord being re- viewed." 14. Ugand There is a drawback scheme for duties and sales taxes on imported inputs for export. However, the scheme as presently implemented does not work properly. The paperwork required to claim a drawback is, according to exporters and the Export Policy Analysis and Development Unit (EPADU), extremely bureaucratic and time-consuming. In effect, very few exporters have been successful in claiming a drawback or have even bothered to do so. Recently EPADU recommended that the government introduce a duty exemption system. No BMW system or EPZ regime is in place. EPADU has also prepared for the Minister of Planning and Economic Development a policy paper on an EPZ regime. Meanwhile, exporters have access to foreign exchanges through an Open General Licensing (OGL) scheme and non-traditional exporters' foreign exchange retention accounts. However, it is uncertain whether exporters' access to foreign exchange is guaranteed based on these schemes. 15. Zambia One scheme that allows for duty-free access to imported inputs for export is the duty drawback scheme. According to exporters, the mechanism for claiming a drawback has been so time consuming that no exporter bothers any longer. (Still it is a big cost factor, as import-duty-plus-sales-tax adds up to at least 40% of the value of the imported inputs; indirect taxes (sales and - 157 - excise taxes) are refunded according to the amount of the taxes levied at the final stages of production, but are not refunded for taxes levied on imports. More effective implementation of the drawback scheme is an objective of the current revision of the investment code (the drawback scheme was already "streamlined' in 1986, without much success). There is a BMW system as well. Two large firms in the garment sub-sector use this and have a customs official stationed at their warehouses. It appears, however, that BMW status is granted only rarely and somewhat arbitrarily to exporters with "priority status". It is not clear how many exporters are operating under this status. Firms complained that supplies cannot be imported readily due to delays in foreign exchange allocations and slow customs procedures. Most firms, therefore, are forced to tie up large amounts of working capital in stock (one company reported that it has to stock inputs for a whole season in order to fill export orders on time). In principle, exporters have access to foreign exchange through the OGL system or the foreign exchange retention scheme. In practice, foreign exchange applications are often rejected on the grounds that the imported goods are unnecessary because they are available in Zambia. Further, it is reported by exporters that when foreign exchange applications are approved, the Central Bank often finds it difficult to honor the allocations, due to shortage of funds--it may take longer than a month for approved allocations to become backed up with foreign exchange funds. One foreign company, which has manufactured for the local market for 30 years, reported that for its recent- ly-started export production, it had to resort to obtaining foreign exchange from the mother company in the UK in order to import needed inputs. In the future, the firms hopes to use foreign exchange from its retention account. "Regular" exporters receive a 50% forex retention allowance while exporters with "priority status" benefit from a 100% retention scheme. Commercial banks are allowed to administer the export retention scheme. - 158 - 16. Zimbabea Over the next four years the government is phasing in an open general import licensing system. Most firms interviewed use the duty-drawback scheme but they complained about delays in drawback payments, which are tied to actual foreign exchange receipts--not shipments. They also complained about the non-refundable import surtax (20%). Exporters in eligible industries also have the option of using the duty exemption system. To register for the system, however, a company needs approval from three ministries, and most pay a bond and an annual registration fee. Excise duty may also be rebated on specified materials. A BMW scheme has recently been introduced and was being used by two firms at the time of our interview. As the government shifts from a quota-based import protection system to a tariff-based system, effective implementation of the duty-free import schemes should become more important. The open general import licensing (OGIL) scheme has significantly streamlined import procedures. However, an average of, at most, 30% of exporters' needed imports are on OGIL at this time, and there is uncertainty over upcoming release of further items through OGIL, making it difficult for exporters to plan. Exporters complained that complementary inputs and spare parts are not covered by OGIL yet. Under the export revolving fund (ERF), it is difficult to get approval for spare parts and replacement machinery. One company reported that it had a 35% efficiency loss the previous month because the ERF allocation for needed spare parts was not approved. Also, new exporters can hardly rely on the ERF for access to foreign exchange to import inputs not on the OGIL, due to collateral requirements of ERF-handling banks. - 159 - INDUSTRY SERIES PAPERS No. 1 Japanese Direct Foreign Investment: Patterns and Implications for Developing Countries, February 1989. No. 2 Emerging Patterns of International Competition in Selected Industrial Product Groups, February 1989. No. 3 Changing Firm Boundaries: Analysis of Technology-Sharing Alliances, February 1989. No. 4 Technological Advance and Organizational Innovation in the Engineering Industry, March 1989. No. 5 Export Catalyst in Low-Income Countries, November 1989. No. 6 Overview of Japanese Industrial Technology Development, March 1989. No. 7 Reform of Ownership and Control Mechanisms in Hungary and China, April 1989. No. 8 The Computer Industry in Industrialized Economies: Lessons for the 'Newly Industrializing, February 1989. No. 9 Institutions and Dynamic Comparative Advantage Electronics Industry in South Korea and Taiwan, June 1989. No. 10 New Environments for Intellectual Property, June 1989. No. 11 Managing Entry Into International Markets: Lessons From the East Asian Experience, June 1989. No. 12 Impact of Technological Change on Industrial Prospects for the LDCs, June 1989. No. 13 The Protection of Intellectual Property Rights and Industrial Technology Development in Brazil, September 1989. No. 14 Regional Integration and Economic Development, November 1989. No. 15 Specialization, Technical Change and Competitiveness in the Brazilian Electronics Industry, November 1989. No. 16 Small Trading Companies and a Successful Export Response: Lessons From Hong Kong, December 1989. No. 17 Flowers: Global Subsector Study, December 1989. No. 18 The Shrimp Industry: Global Subsector Study, December 1989. No. 19 Garments: Global Subsector Study, December 1989. - 160 - IMUSTRY SERIES PAPERS cont'd No. 20 World Bank Lending for Small and Medium Enterprises: Fifteen Years of Experience, December 1989. No. 21 Reputation in Manufactured Goods Trade, December 1989. No. 22 Foreign Direct Investment From the Newly Industrialized Economies, December 1989. No. 23 Buyer-Seller Links for Export Development, March 1990. No. 24 Technology Strategy & Policy for Industrial Competitiveness: A Case Study of Thailand, February 1990. No. 25 Investment, Productivity and Comparative Advantage, April 1990. No. 26 Cost Reduction, Product Development and the Real Exchange Rate, April 1990. No. 27 Overcoming Policy Endogeneity: Strategic Role for Domestic Competition in Industrial Policy Reform, April 1990. No. 28 Conditionality in Adjustment Lending FY8O-89: The ALCID Database, May 1990. No. 29 International Competitiveness: Determinants and Indicators, March 1990. No. 30 FY89 Sector Review Industry, Trade and Finance, November 1989. No. 31 The Design of Adjustment Lending for Industry: Review of Current Practice, June 1990. No. 32 National Systems Supporting Technical Advance in Industry: The Brazilian Experience, June 26, 1990. No. 33 Ghana's Small Enterprise Sector: Survey of Adjustment Response and Constraints, June 1990. No. 34 Footwear: Global Subsector Study, June 1990. No. 35 Tightening the Soft Budget Constraint in Reforming Socialist Economies, May 1990. No. 36 Free Trade Zones in Export Strategies, December 1990. No. 37 Electronics Development Strategy: The Role of Government, June 1990 No. 38 Export Finance in the Philippines: Opportunities and Constraints for Developing Country Suppliers, June 1990. - '61 - INDUSTRY SERIES PAPERS cont'd No. 39 The U.S. Automotive Aftermarket: Opportunities and Constraints for Developing Country Suppliers, June 1990 No. 40 Investment As A Determinant of Industrial Competitiveness and Comparative Advantage: Evidence from Six Countries, August 1990 (not yet publshed) No. 41 Adjustment and Constrained Response: Malawi at the Threshold of Sustained Growth, October 1990. No. 42 Export Finance - Issues and Directions Case Study of the Philippines, December 1990 No. 43 The Basics of Antitrust Policy: A Review of Ten Nations and the EEC, February 1991. No. 44 Technology Strategy in the Economy of Taiwan: Exploiting Foregin Linkages and Investing in Local Capability, January 1991 No. 45 The Impact of Adjustment Lending on Industry in African Countries, June 1991. No. 46 Banking Automation and Productivity Change: The Brazilian Experience, July 1991. No. 47 Global Trends in Textile Technology and Trade, December 1991. No. 48 Are There Dynamic Externalities from Direct Foreign Investment? Evidence for Morocco, December 1991. No. 49 Do Firms with Foreign Equity Recover Faster From Financial Distress? The Case of Colombia, December 1991 No. 50 International Competition in the Bicycle Industry: Keeping Pace with Technological Change, December 1991. No. 51 International Competition in the Footwear Industry: Keeping Pace with Technological Change, December 1991. No. 52 International Trends in Steel Mini-Mills: Keeping Pace with Technological Change, December 1991. No. 53 International Competition in Printed Circuit Board Assembly: Keeping Pace with Technological Change, December 1991. No. 54 Efficiency, Corporate Indebtedness and Directed Credit in Colombia, December 1991. No. 55 Small Enterprises Under Adjustment in Senegal, Maarch 1992. No. 56 Fundamental Issues and Policy Approaches in Industrial Restructuring, April 1992 Note: For extra copies of these papers please contact Miss Wendy Young on extension 33618, Room S-41G0; 162 - World Bank Tndustry and Energy Dept. ENERGY SERIES PAPERS No. 1 Energy Issues in the Developing World, February 1988. No. 2 Review of World Bank Lending for Electric Power, March 1988. No. 3 Some Considerations in Collecting Data on Household Energy Consumption, March 1988. No. 4 Irnproving Power Svstem Efficiency in the Developing Countries through Performance Contracting, May 1988. No. 5 Impact of Lower Oil Prices on Renewable Energy Technologies, May 1988. No. 6 A Comparison of Lamps for Domestic Lighting in Developing Countries, June 1988. No. 7 Recent World Bank Activities in Energy (revised October 1989). No. 8 A Visual Overview of the World Oil Markets, July 1988. No. 9 Current Intemational Gas Trades and Prices, November 1988. No. 10 Promoting Investrnent for Natural Gas Exploration and Production in Developing Countries, January 1989. No. 11 Technology Survey Report on Electric Power Systems, February 1989. No. 12 Recent Developments in the U.S. Power Sector and Their Relevance for the Developing Countries, February 1989. No. 13 Dornestic Energy Pricing Policies, April 1989. No. 14 Financing of the Energy Sector in Developing Countries, April 1989. No. 15 The Future Role of Hydropower in Developing Countries, April 1989. No. 16 Fuelwood Stumpage: Considerations for Developing Country Energy Planning, June 1989. No. 17 Incorporating Risk and Uncertainty in Power System Planning, June 1989. No. 18 Review and Evaluation of Historic Electricity Forecasting Experience, (1960- 1985), June 1989. No. 19 Woodfuel Supply and Environmental Management, July 1989. No. 20 The Malawi Charcoal Project - Experience and Lessons, January 1990. No. 21 Capital Expenditures for Electric Power in the Developing Countries in the 1990s, February 1990. - 163 - No. 22 A Review of Regulation of the Power Sectors in Developing Countries, February 1990. No. 23 Summary Data Sheets of 1987 Power and Commercial Energy Statistics for 100 Developing Countries, March 1990. No. 24 A Review of the Treatment of Environmental Aspects of Bank Energy Projects, March 1990. No. 25 The Status of Liquified Natural Gas Worldwide, March 1990. No. 26 Population Growth, Wood Fuels, and Resource Problems in Sub-Saharan Africa, March 1990. No. 27 The Status of Nuclear Power Technology - An Update, April 1990. No. 28 Decommissioning of Nuclear Power Facilities, April 1990. No. 29 Interfuel Substitution and Changes in the Way Households Use Energy: The Case of Cooking and Lighting Behavior in Urban Java, October 1990. No. 30 Regulation, Deregulation, or Reregulation-What is Needed in LDCs Power Sector? July 1990. No. 31 Understanding the Costs and Schedules of World Bank Supported Hydroelectric Projects, July 1990. No. 32 Review of Electricity Tariffs in Developing Countries During the 1980s, November 1990. No. 33 Private Sector Participation in Power through BOOT Schemes, December 1990. No. 34 Identifying the Basic Conditions for Economic Generation of Public Electricity from Surplus Bagasse in Sugar Mills, April 1991. No. 35 Prospects for Gas-Fueled Combined-Cycle Power Generation in the Developing Countries, May 1991. No. 36 Radioactive Waste Management - A Background Study, June 1991. No. 37 A Study of the Transfer of Petroleum Fuels Pollution, July 1991. No. 38 Improving Charcoaling Efficiency in the Traditional Rural Sector, July 1991. No. 39 Decision Making Under Uncertainty - An Option Valuation Approach to Power Planning, August 1991. No. 40 Summary 1988 Power Data Sheets for 100 Developing Countries, August 1991. No. 41 Health and Safety Aspects of Nuclear Power Plants, August 1991. No. 42 A Review of International Power Sales Agreements, August 1991. _ 164 - No. 43 Guideline for Diesel Generating Plant Specification and Bid Evaluation, September 1991. No. 44 A Methodology for Regional Assessment of Small Scale Hydro Power, September 1991. No. 45 Guidelines for Assessing Wind Energy Potential, September 1991. No. 46 Core Report of the Electric Power Utility Efficiency Improvement Study, September 1991. No. 47 Kerosene Stoves: Their Perfornance, Use, and Constraints, October 1991. No. 48 Assessment of Biomass Energy Resources: A Discussion on its Need and Methodology, December 1991. No. 49 Accounting for Traditional Fuel Production: the Household-Energv Sector and Its Implications for the Development Process, March 1992. No. 50 Energy Issues in Central and Eastern Europe: Considerations for the World Bank Group and Other Financial Institutions, March 1992. For copies, please call (202) 473-3616 or extension 33616.