WPS8437


 Policy Research Working Paper                    8437




Using Satellite Imagery to Revolutionize Creation
   of Tax Maps and Local Revenue Collection
                              Daniel Ayalew Ali
                               Klaus Deininger
                                Michael Wild




 Development Economics
 Development Research Group
 May 2018
Policy Research Working Paper 8437


  Abstract
 The technical complexity of ensuring that tax rolls are com-                       prices from the land registry, targeted surveys, and routine
 plete and valuations current is often perceived as a major                         statistical data, this makes it possible to use mass valuation
 barrier to bringing in more property tax revenues in develop-                      procedures to generate tax maps. The example of Kigali
 ing countries. This paper shows how high-resolution satellite                      illustrates the reliability of the method and the potentially
 imagery makes it possible to assess the completeness of exist-                     far-reaching revenue impacts. Estimates show that height-
 ing tax maps by estimating built-up areas based on building                        ened compliance and a move to a 1 percent ad valorem tax
 heights and footprints. Together with information on sales                         would yield a tenfold increase in revenue from public land.




  This paper is a product of the Development Research Group, Development Economics. It is part of a larger effort by the
  World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the
  world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/research. The authors
  may be contacted at dali1@worldbank.org, kdeininger@worldbank.org, and mwild@worldbank.org.




         The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
         issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
         names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
         of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
         its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.


                                                       Produced by the Research Support Team
    Using Satellite Imagery to Revolutionize Creation of Tax Maps and Local
                                                       Revenue Collection                  ¶




                                                            Daniel Ayalew Ali
                                                              Klaus Deininger
                                                                Michael Wild




                                                  The World Bank, Washington DC
                     dali1@worldbank.org, kdeininger@worldbank.org, mwild@worldbank.org




         JEL Classification: C21, E31, Q24, R32, R38
         Keywords: property taxes, property values, satellite imagery, mass valuation, spatial hedonic model, Rwanda




¶
  We thank the Rwanda National Resource Authority (RNRA) for data access, and we gratefully acknowledge funding support from the German
Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development through GIZ, the United Kingdom Department for International Development, the
International Growth Center (IGC) and the European Space Agency (ESA) through the “Earth Observation for Sustainable Development” Urban
project under the ESA/WB partnership program. We would like to thank C. Aubrecht (coordinator of collaborative activities under the ESA/WB
partnership) for facilitating the collaboration; and the GAF AG, Geospatial Service Provider, Germany team particularly S. Gomez and T. Haeusler
for coordinating the generation of building heights and footprints using high resolution satellite imagery. We are also very grateful to T. Hilhorst
and S. Murray (IGC) for their helpful comments and suggestions.
1. Introduction

Population growth, agricultural mechanization, and climate change are commonly believed to be associated
with high rates of urban growth in developing countries, especially in Africa, where most residents are still
concentrated in rural areas and the demographic transition is still in its early stages. Historically, cities’
ability to capitalize on spatial proximity and positive externalities from the agglomeration of skills (Glaeser
2011) implied that urbanization was a key driver of economic growth. Yet as globalization severed the link
between agricultural surpluses and city formation (Gollin et al. 2016), urbanization without growth and the
formation of ‘consumption cities’ has become a distinct possibility for cities that are unable to deal with
issues such as planning, pollution, public health, crime, and provision of infrastructure and other services.
This will make it difficult to attract highly skilled individuals or to produce tradable goods in a way that
ensures competitiveness and allows to capitalize on benefits of global integration such as risk diversification
and scale.

To generate the resources for urban service provision, the ability to raise funds in a non-distortionary way
and to have effective delivery mechanisms has become an important precondition to realizing the potential
of cities. Surging prices for urban land and the scope for using taxes on land and property to enhance
revenues when the tax base for income or profit taxes is narrow make property taxes one of the few viable
options to finance sustainable expansion of cities in developing countries (Youngman 2016). In fact, as
most of the resulting benefits will be capitalized in land values (Collier and Venables 2017), taxes on real
property have been identified as a highly inventive-compatible way to finance local services and
infrastructure.

However, despite their conceptual advantages, developing-world revenue from recurrent property taxes is
still far below that of developed countries, even in relative terms. Instead, developing countries often rely
heavily on transfer taxes, which are counter-productive because they tend both to discourage efficiency-
enhancing land transfers while encouraging reversion to informality by avoiding registration as well as
corruption by under-declaring land values. Two issues that may contribute to the widespread failure of
using property taxes are the high fixed cost of establishing and ensuring currency of the associated valuation
infrastructure and collection systems and the difficulty of conducting counterfactual analysis (see, e.g., Bahl
and Wallace 2008; Kelly 2013). As maps to identify taxable properties are often incomplete, out of date,
and access to them is fragmented between government units it is not uncommon to find that less than 50%
of taxable properties are on the tax roll (Blochliger 2015; De Cesare 2012). Ensuring property taxes can be
collected in low-cost ways that are fair, progressively linked to property values, and buoyant, requires
automated valuation methods based on market values to be updated routinely without a danger of triggering
appeals (IIAO 2013). While data integration, automating processes, and use of technology are believed to


                                                       2
have great potential (McIlhatton et al. 2012), there are few examples in the developing world where property
taxes have been successfully implemented (Franzsen and McCluskey 2017; McCluskey et al. 2012).

Using the example of Kigali, we demonstrate how remotely sensed imagery can significantly reduce the
cost of establishing and updating tax registers by allowing automated generation of building footprints and,
based on building heights, an estimate of total built-up area. If data on land prices are available, this
information, together with spatial data routinely available from statistical institutes, can be used to inform
routine processes of computer-assisted mass appraisal (CAMA).1 Imputed values for land and property
from the CAMA model, together with administrative records on taxes collected on individual properties,
allows us to provide information on (i) potential revenue gains from full collection of current lease fees;
(ii) likely yields from and incidence of a uniformly applied 1% tax on residential land and property; and
(iii) the implicit cost of exemptions currently being discussed by Rwandan policy makers. This could not
only make collection of property taxes much easier but also ground the debate on tax reform by providing
more reliable data on which to base scenarios.

For Rwanda, three findings stand out: first, only about 40 percent of the potential yield of US$4.9 million
from current lease fees is collected, suggesting that more efficient collection could heighten returns. Efforts
to reduce costs of compliance (e.g., automated billing or reminders) may thus have high returns even in
Rwanda, where all properties have been mapped. Second, because lease fees are regressive, moving to a
1% value-based tax would not only spread the tax burden more equally but could also increase revenue to
about US$19.3 million—almost 10 times what is currently collected. Finally, while there may be scope for
exempting those at the very bottom, the exemptions for ‘low-cost housing’ currently proposed by policy
makers are too generous: they would leave only 5% with any building tax obligation.

Defining built-up area based on building footprints and heights derived from remotely sensed imagery
offers even more scope to ensure complete coverage in places where recent urbanization implies that tax
rolls are no longer current. Combined with transparent valuation models and broad publicity, it could help
municipalities to not only generate sustainable own-source revenue but also to gradually reduce reliance on
transfer taxes, which in many places seem to be a major reason that land registries revert to informality.

In what follows, section 2 discusses the challenges confronted by cities, how recurrent taxes on land and
property can help resolve them, the technical and political economy obstacles to implementing them, and
the resulting priority given to using instruments to collect taxes that are less efficient and more distortionary.
It describes property taxation in Rwanda, noting similarities to and differences from what can be observed
elsewhere. Section 3 describes use of remotely sensed information to construct a map of built-up areas that

1
  In most countries, such information may need to be collected in surveys or from institutions, such as bank data on mortgage lending. As the only
African country to have established a complete and fully digital registry of rights, Rwanda has price data available.

                                                                        3
can complement other data and to estimate a model of computer-assisted mass valuation that makes it
possible to compute potential yield from a 1% property tax and compare it to the yield from current lease
fees. It also links the results to current reform proposals for Rwanda, discussing exemptions and ways to
separate taxation of land and of buildings. Section 4 concludes by drawing out the implications of the study
for policy and future research.

2. Conceptual Background

While cities make it possible to achieve unprecedented agglomeration effects, realizing these benefits in
ways that enhance a city’s long-term competitiveness hinges on the effectiveness of services to counter the
negative aspects of density. As most benefits from local services will be capitalized in land values, taxes
on land and other real property have long been advocated as a method of financing services that is incentive-
compatible. Property taxes have other desirable properties in that they are progressive, difficult to avoid,
with yields that are quite stable over time. Yet, even in relative terms, the contribution from such taxes to
revenue is much lower in the developing world than in developed countries. This, together with reliance on
distortionary transfer taxes instead, suggests that reducing the high fixed costs of collecting property taxes
may be one way to increase use of property taxes and enhance their distributional fairness.

2.1 The Relationship of Public Services and the Competitiveness of a City
Historically, most human intellectual and material progress originated in cities (Jacobs 1986), which have
fostered economic growth and innovation through a combination of spatial proximity and human capital
externalities (Glaeser 2011). However, the potential of cities to act as engines of growth depends on their
having institutions to effectively address the negative externalities, such as congestion, pollution, and
disease, that have accompanied growth in cities virtually everywhere. For most of history, the institutional
and financial prerequisites imposed by the need to overcome these “demons of density” implied that
urbanization was contingent on a city having achieved a certain per capita income (Jedwab and Vollrath
2015). The scope for global trade and improvements in public health and technology together have lowered
this threshold, creating the prospect of “urbanization without growth” (Fay and Opal 1999).2

Thus urbanization in “consumption” rather than “production” cities may be driven by a rural push or booms
in the non-tradable sector that, in Africa, have often been fueled by resource rents (Gollin et al. 2016).
While not eliminating the economic and risk diversification benefits of urbanization,3 failure to develop
institutions for effective planning and resource mobilization (Besley et al. 2013) to reduce the demons of
density may lead to a situation where the costs of urbanization outweigh the benefits. Empirical evidence

2
  Unlike the traditional model, in which high agricultural productivity, was a precondition for city growth, today, in an interconnected world, high
agricultural productivity may actually slow urbanization (Glaeser 2014).
3
  To the extent that climate-related shocks reduce economic opportunities and cause workers to emigrate from rural areas, the risk diversification
that cities offer may be very important (Henderson, Styoreygard, and Deichmann 2017).

                                                                         4
suggests that many African cities have thus far failed to live up to this challenge (Jedwab et al. 2017) and
instead are crowded, costly, and disconnected (Lall et al. 2017).4 In light of the durability of urban buildings
and infrastructure, this may in the long term affect city structure and competitiveness. High transport and
wage costs resulting from inappropriate infrastructure and lack of affordable services may trap some cities
in a low-level equilibrium that leaves them unable to competitively produce goods that are tradable globally
(Venables 2017). Considering its high expected rates of city growth in the near future and the high cost of
providing services after cities are built, this is particularly pertinent for Africa.

Property taxes have long been identified as the largest source of untapped municipal revenue that could
ease the revenue constraints on local governments and allow the emergence of competitive cities (Collier
et al. 2017). Coverage with digital cadastral maps is a necessary precondition if property taxes are to be
collected both effectively and fairly.5 Where cities expand rapidly, it is also a precondition for effective
planning and delivery of services. Yet, as table 1 shows, of 159 non-OECD countries in the World Bank’s
Doing Business surveys, only about a third have registered and mapped most of the main city’s private plots
(though not necessarily public land) and only about 20% percent have digital cadastral maps available. Only
5% of African and South Asian countries, where most of the expected surges in urban population will be
concentrated, have digital cadastral records even for the main city. For those countries, use of digital
products based on remotely sensed imagery can be transformational, opening new avenues for collecting
local revenue and helping to clarify and realize other benefits from documenting ownership rights.

2.2 Pros and Cons of Taxes on Land and Other Real Property

In developing countries, taxation as a share of GDP is only 25–50 percent of that in developed economies
(Besley and Persson 2014), primarily because (i) a great deal of the economic activity is informal, beyond
the reach of traditional taxes on income and profits; (ii) institutional capacity to collect taxes is more
limited; and (iii) even if taxes are assessed and levied, cultural and political factors such as fragmented
polities, lack of transparency, and a minimal sense of national identity may cause widespread avoidance of
payment.

It has long been noted that local taxes on land and property can avoid some of these shortcomings and that,
because land cannot be moved, they are difficult to avoid, can be designed to fall mainly on the wealthy,
and are relatively stable against shocks (Norregaard 2013). They are thus less distortionary and less subject
to tax competition than consumption or income taxes.6 Moreover, by raising the cost of holding property,


4
  Microdata confirm that developing countries are seeing a rapid reallocation of workers to densely populated areas (Gollin et al. 2017).
5
  Paper maps are susceptible to unauthorized tampering, difficult to update or use for planning, and imply that collection of property taxes will incur
high transaction costs because they preclude low-cost electronic billing or tax collection via mobile money.
6
  In fact, a number of revenue-neutral tax reforms to boost growth often aimed to shift part of the revenue base from income taxes to consumption
and property (Norregaard 2013).

                                                                          5
such taxes may discourage speculation and encourage more intensive land use. Where provision of public
infrastructure and other services causes rapid appreciation of land prices, taxes on land and property have
been linked to benefits from such investment. In Mexico, infrastructure improvement, such as street
asphalting in residential neighborhoods, was capitalized into higher property values within two years
(Gonzalez-Navarro and Quintana-Domeque 2016). Support for a benefit view of land and property taxes
also emerges in U.S. residential neighborhoods where housing supply is inelastic (Lutz 2015). As fiscal
instruments and land use regulations interact (Blochliger et al. 2017), land taxes will affect land use and
can reduce sprawl, as in Pittsburgh in the 1980s (Oates and Schwab 1997), in other U.S. settings thereafter
(Banzhaf and Lavery 2010), and in Italy (Ermini and Santolini 2017).7

Although the high visibility of property taxes can make it difficult to gather broad political support (Bahl
and Wallace 2008), it increases accountability for how tax proceeds are used—an observation supported
by evidence from OECD countries where greater reliance on property taxes by subnational governments
has enhanced fiscal discipline (Presbitero et al. 2014). Beyond the political issues arising from high salience
of property taxes, the reason most often quoted as an obstacle to broader use of land and property taxes is
the high costs and the administrative requirements for establishing a cadaster and maintaining it.8 The time
and human resources needed to conduct or adjust valuations and deal with appeals have often been viewed
as a major deterrent to broader use of a registry, especially in cities with rapidly expanding populations
where the potential from doing so would be greatest and property tax revenues could be quite buoyant.
Studies from Latin America (Sepulveda and Martinez-Vazquez 2012), Pakistan (Piracha and Moore 2016),
Indonesia (von Haldenwang 2017), Sierra Leone (Jibao and Prichard 2016), and many other African
countries (Franzsen and McCluskey 2017), suggest that capacity constraints and the inability to fairly
administer a property tax have often deterred reforms. Such constraints may also underpin the
disproportionate reliance of developing countries on transaction taxes, despite their disadvantages in terms
of undermining predictability, imposing frictions on land market operations, pushing transactions into
informality, and creating incentives for fraudulent under-declaration of transaction values (Dachis et al.
2012).

2.3 Ways to Tap This Potential

The conceptual advantages of taxing property and the enormous variety of ways to implement it
notwithstanding,9 in developing countries recurrent taxation of land or property makes up a limited, and


7
  In Italy, differential tax rates between a city’s core and periphery can make the core urban area more compact. In Spanish municipalities during
1994-2005, sprawl increased demand for new infrastructure, the cost of which was covered mainly by intergovernmental transfers, which created
moral hazard incentives for local governments (Hortas-Rico 2014).
8
  Some support for this notion is provided by the fact that use of land taxes is often more advanced in cities than in countries as a whole (McCluskey
and Franzsen 2013).
9
  For a comprehensive review of property tax systems globally, see Almy (2013).

                                                                          6
often decreasing share of revenue. As table 2 illustrates, since the 1990s, the share of land and property
taxes in GDP (1.7%) or total tax revenue (0.45%) stood unchanged in real terms in advanced markets;
increased from 0.4–0.6% of GDP (equivalent to 0.15–0.22% of tax revenue) in emerging markets; and
dropped from 0.09% to 0.05% of tax revenue (0.2% of GDP) in low-income developing countries.

Efforts to increase coverage by updating tax maps and updating valuation rolls by applying uniform mass
valuation have been taken to enhance transparency and perceived fairness of the process in many countries
(Almy 2014). This has generated large fiscal benefits even in developed countries like Italy (Casaburi and
Troiano 2016); where fiscal and legal cadasters are interoperable, it has also made it easier to demonstrate
ownership of land. In the Netherlands, valuations of some 8 million properties via CAMA are conducted
annually, bringing real estate taxes up to 2.8% of GDP. Assessed property values are publicly available,
allowing owners to update data online, increasing trust in and the transparency of the system, and because
of interoperability and integration of the cadaster with other public data, provide additional benefits, e.g.,
by preventing mortgage fraud (Kuiiper and Kaathman 2015). In Cape Town, each dollar invested in
property tax administration yielded a more than 50-fold return, and the ability to use tax receipts in
documenting ownership resulted in significant outreach and impact on poverty (Barlow 2015). In Bogota,
a series of reforms that started with self-assessment moved on to link the fiscal and legal cadasters, and
then improved valuations that have more than tripled tax revenue. In Lithuania, assessed values more than
quadrupled as a result of gradually refining the mass valuation system (Almy 2015); it is now the core of
an elaborate private-sector-driven data information system that provides many benefits (Grover et al. 2017).
Where effective and routine systems to collect property tax are lacking,10 gains from administrative
simplification could be much larger. In such situations, property taxation may also contribute to increasing
state capacity and citizens’ trust in the state, as Weigel (2017) argues to be the case in the Democratic
Republic of Congo (Weigel 2017).

Even where tax maps and realistic valuations are in place, increasing collection effort may yield high returns
in terms of increased revenue collection.11 In the U.S., where property tax contributes 30% of local
government revenue and some 73% of local taxes, the performance of local governments varies widely.
Simple reminders, especially if combined with a description of the effect of nonpayment, have greatly
increased collections (Chirico et al. 2017). In Peru a reminder to pay had a persistent positive impact on
payment; disclosure of information on neighbors’ level of compliance was even more effective (delCarpio
2015); similarly, in Argentina, a deterrence message also heightened taxpayers’ propensity to pay (Castro
and Scartascini 2015).


10
   Franzsen and McCluskey (2017) provide an excellent and exhaustive survey of land and property tax systems in Africa, noting that in many of
these the level of taxes is based on self-declaration or the payment procedure is very cumbersome.
11
   For a comprehensive review of experiments to increase taxes more generally, i.e., well beyond the property tax, see Hallsworth (2014).

                                                                      7
3. Applying a Mass Valuation Model to Kigali

Rwanda is of interest because it is the only African country that has established a complete and fully digital
legal cadaster. While it is somewhat surprising that the data are not used for fiscal purposes, the registry
reliably records prices for any transaction. Together with data on building heights or the volume of built-
up area generated from high-resolution satellite imagery, this can feed into a CAMA model to impute the
potential yield from a 1% tax on residential land and property. Beyond comparing the magnitude and
incidence of such a tax to actual and potential yields from the current system, this also makes it possible to
estimate the likely effects of proposed exemptions, thus laying the foundation for better-informed policy.

3.1 Context and Setting

Rwanda stands out among African countries for having recently completed a nationwide first-registration
program that covered 11.6 million parcels (Nkurunziza 2015), thereby helping to establish the full cadastral
database now commonly referred to as LAIS—the land administration information system. LAIS contains
spatial and textual data for all registered land parcels in Rwanda; each parcel is unambiguously identified
and mapped via a unique parcel identifier (UPI). The UPI is used to link via web services to the mortgage
registry maintained by the Rwanda Development Board (RDB) and can also be accessed by the Rwanda
Revenue Authority (RRA). However, lease fees—the equivalent of property taxes—are still based on self-
declaration. This fails to take into account changes in land prices or to realize the potential cost savings
from automated billing and issuance of reminders. Exemptions may further reduce tax yield; for example,
in Kigali city 60% of all parcels and 99% of agricultural parcels are exempted from paying lease fees.12
Efforts to address these shortcomings include preparation and debate of a draft property tax law,13 a recent
version of which aims to impose a base lease fee of RWF 0-500/m2 (plus a surcharge of half of the base fee
on oversized land), and a tax of 1% on the value of buildings above a threshold of RWF 30 million. One
likely scenario, for expositional purpose, is to use the current flat lease fee of RWF 70/m2, assigned to more
than 85% of the parcels in Kigali city, for areas below 300 m2 and then apply RWF 105/m2 for the additional
areas above 300 m2.

With some 6% of land parcels formally transferred annually (Ali et al. 2017), Rwanda’s land market is
highly active in international terms. Sale prices are registered for all properties transferred and, because
registration fees are independent of registered property values, incentives for misreporting are minimized.14
Table 3 illustrates that, of some 11.6 million parcels covering 2.064 million ha nationwide (i.e., an average
of 1,800 m2/parcel or 1,300 m2 for residential and 1,900 m2 for agricultural land), 0.4 million or about

12
   Since a full exemption is granted to agricultural parcels smaller than 2 ha, with the average size of parcels being 0.19 ha virtually all agricultural
land is exempt from paying lease fees.
13
   As discussed below, only 30% of residential parcels in urban Kigali paid lease fees in 2015—only $1.95 million of a potential $6.74 million.
14
   This is reinforced by the fact that reported land transfers and prices are similar to what emerges from household surveys.

                                                                           8
70,000 ha are in Kigali city. While nationally 64% of parcels (66% of area) are used for agriculture and
12% (8% of area) for residential purposes, in Kigali 49% (56% of land area) are used for agriculture and
35% (17% of area) for residences. For 2013–16, sales were registered for some 85,000 properties, almost
half in Kigali and some 20,000 in our study area. Property prices averaged US$28 per m2 for residential
and US$4 per m2 for agricultural land nationwide and US$40 (US$ 7.5) or US$ 51 (US$ 11) per m2 for
residential (agricultural) land in Kigali and our study area, respectively.

To compare potential to actual revenue from land and more effective collection of current lease fees, we
draw on 2015 parcel-level data for land tax revenue from the Rwanda Revenue Authority (RRA). Although
RRA and RNRA use the same UPI to identify properties, so that in principle RRA could use the cadastral
map to automatically bill owners for land lease fees owed (as assessed at the time of registration), this has
not been done. Instead lease fee charges are still based on self-declaration. Table 4, based on using the UPI
to link RRA and LAIS data, illustrates that only about 40% (45,000) of the 112,000 residential parcels in
Kigali were subject to land lease fees and 37,000 did so. In urban Kigali in 2015, only US$1.95 million of
US$6.74 million owed on residential properties was collected. Thus, in urban Kigali alone, closing the
collection gap could more than triple revenue from land use fees.15

As the property registry does not contain data on many building characteristics needed for a mass valuation
exercise, we drew on other data sources. Most importantly, to generate information on built-up area, we
used 0.5m-resolution Pleaides Tri-Stereo imagery (acquired in August 2015) for a 340 km2 study area that
covers the central business district (CBD) and most of urban Kigali (see figure 1).16 Applying a semi-global
matching algorithm (Hirschmueller 2011) to this imagery made it possible to elaborate a Digital Surface
and a Digital Terrain Model. After filtering out trees using the Normalized Differenced Vegetation Index
(NDVI), building heights for each of the imagery’s 0.5 m/pixels could then be recovered as the difference
between the surface and the terrain model (Bärisch et al. 2017). We overlaid the result with boundaries of
cadastral parcels obtained from LAIS, considered only heights above 2 m to exclude vehicles, and used the
area covered by pixels with the same height as an estimate of building footprint. Building volume was then
computed as the product of building footprint and height. Figures 2 and 3 illustrate the results for a low-
and a higher-density neighborhood in central Kigali. While they illustrate some issues that might have been
addressed by further processing, cost considerations led us not to proceed.17




15
   Comparing the potential revenue gain to the total cost of about US$50 million for the national land registration program suggests that the program
did help to generate significant benefits.
16
   The size of the study area was dictated by data availability and cost considerations.
17
   The main issue that could be addressed by further processing would be to obtain more precise estimates of building footprints. This would also
make it possible to address some sources of error in estimating the height of structures in steep areas and small and low buildings that might be
hidden by trees or located in highly dense areas. Exploring ways to automate this process is an important area for future research.

                                                                         9
The data thus generated are illustrated in table 5, highlighting that, with median parcel area of 400 m2,
building height of 3.7 m, and built-up volume of 304 m3, about 20% of the area in the urban part of our
study area is built up.18 Complementing these data with the 2012 population and housing census, the 2014
establishment census, shapefiles for the location of schools from the National Institute of Statistics, and a
map of road networks from the Rwanda Transport Development Agency made it possible to generate
additional property attributes for inclusion in a computerized mass appraisal model.

Descriptive statistics suggest that the average property is 5.6 km from the CBD and 600 m from the closest
primary school. Data on establishments, available only at cell level to protect respondent confidentiality,
suggest better job opportunities in urban Kigali, where some 1,330 people per cell were employed by local
establishments, compared to 360 in the city’s rural cells. With a per km2 cost of US$34 for imagery and
$112 for processing (and ample scope for further reductions, e.g., by linking to open street map data or
using local analysts), the total cost for the study area was about US$40,000.19

3.2 Factors Affecting Property Values and Model Suitability

CAMA models for property taxation typically involve estimation of a hedonic model on a set of properties
for which prices are observed and then using the model to impute the values of properties for which price
data are not available (IIAO 2013). Assuming that properties sold are a random sample, and following
Rosen (1974), property prices are expressed as                                    , ,      ,	where Pi is the sale price of property i; S
denotes structural attributes such as parcel or lot size, building size, and quality; L is a vector of observable
location-specific factors such as access to social services or jobs; and N denotes other factors capturing
neighborhood quality. Estimating this function makes it possible to derive implicit market prices for specific
attributes. Assuming that properties being sold are representative of the larger universe, prices can be
imputed as a basis for mass valuation.

Testing for the presence of spatial autocorrelation using Moran’s I statistic for residuals from OLS estimates
(see appendix table 1) rejects the assumption of iid error terms. To identify a suitable alternative model, we
used the Lagrange Multiplier test for model specification to identify the most important reason (omitted
spatial lag or spatially autoregressive errors) for spatial dependence (Anselin et al. 1996).20 As our objective
was to predict prices to assess the potential for property tax, we focused on the squared mean prediction




18
   It should be noted that because here we consider only building structures, the total built-up area (including roads and other infrastructure) will be
much higher in urban villages that include the central business district.
19
   The cost is as estimated by a team from GAF AG that includes the cost of imagery for the study area (340 km2) and processing of the Normalized
Digital Surface Model (NDSM) including filtering, tree elimination, quality enhancement, and calculation of relative building heights. The cost of
imagery will be as high as US$56 if archived data are not available, and the cost of processing will be as low as US$56 if street map or cadaster
data are available.
20
   Estimation results are highly significant for error and lag dependence models as well as their robust counterparts (appendix table 1).

                                                                          10
error that favors a spatial error model (see appendix table 3) over spatial lag (appendix table 2) or OLS
(appendix table 1) models. The spatial error model is specified as:

                                                                                             , with

                                                                                      ,

where Piv is the log of the market price of residential property i located in village v; Siv is a vector of
continuous structural variables in log terms, i.e., parcel or lot size in square meters and volume of buildings
in cubic meters; Liv is a vector of locational variables consisting of distance from the parcel to the CBD and
the nearest primary school or tarmac road; Nv is a vector of neighborhood attributes in log terms (except
the density measure) including density of built-up area and average and standard deviation of building
heights at village level, total residential land per cell and number of workers hired by business
establishments per cell;             is an error that follows a spatial autoregressive process with                         a vector of i.i.d.
error terms; the        s are parameters to be estimated; λ is a scalar autoregressive parameter measuring spatial
correlation in the errors; and W is a distance-based spatial weight matrix.21

The results from four specifications are reported in table 6 with successive columns for a basic regression
with only parcel area and locational and time factors (col. 1), adding access to public amenities such as
primary schools and tarred roads (col. 2), remote sensing data from satellite imagery (col. 3), and all of the
above (col. 4). Although all variables have the signs expected, incorporating image-based attributes clearly
and significantly improves goodness of fit.22 Also, the spatial autoregressive coefficient, λ, is highly
significant and, with an estimated coefficient of 0.79 for the preferred model, suggests a positive correlation
between error terms of nearby properties.

With estimated elasticities of 0.56 and 0.17, parcel size and volume of buildings on a parcel are important
predictors of the market prices of residential properties in Kigali even after locational and neighborhood
factors are accounted for. Signs of coefficients of locational attributes are consistent with expectation. Size
(-0.39 and -0.20) and significance of the coefficient on the property’s distance to the CBD is consistent with
a model of a monocentric city (Epple et al 2010), though it becomes insignificant once other locational
variables are controlled for (cols. 2 and 4). Weak access to public amenities proxied by distance to primary
schools (estimated coefficient of -0.05) and tarred roads (-0.14) is estimated to have a negative relationship
to property prices.

Beyond the variables noted, neighborhood characteristics affect residential property prices in urban Kigali
even after controlling for the spatial dependence of error terms. Coefficients of 1.62 on mean and -0.37 on

21
   The spatial weights are based on threshold distance of 435m at which each property has at least one neighbor. Alternative distance band weights
(750m, 1,500m and 5,000m) were used, but the one of 435m produced better goodness of fit using the likelihood ratio and AIC criteria.
22
   The log likelihood for models (4) and (3) is -13,835 and -13,983 as compared to -14,494 and -14,673 for models (2) and (1).

                                                                       11
standard deviation of village building heights imply that sales prices are higher in villages with taller but
more homogeneous buildings. Estimated coefficients of 0.17 on the volume of buildings and 1.09 on the
density of village built-up area are consistent with the notion that, all else being equal, larger residential
buildings in more dense neighborhoods fetch higher prices. Job opportunities as measured by number of
workers hired by local establishments are estimated to have a significant positive association with the value
of residential properties in urban Kigali, with an estimated elasticity of 6%. The stock of residential land
on the other hand does not seem to affect the market value of properties.

3.3 Assessing Different Models’ Predictive Power

To assess the models’ predictive power and suitability for out-of-sample predictions and policy advice, we
first compare estimated to actual sales prices within the sample by plotting results from the different models
against building volume (figure 4) and parcel area (figure 5) as well as current lease fees. Figure 4 suggests
that, because lease fees do not account for the fact that values increase with building volume, they fail to
maximize potential tax revenue. Failure to include building volumes in a CAMA model used for valuations
that form the basis of property taxes would thus be unfair in the sense that it would require owners of small
residential properties to pay proportionately higher taxes than those owning larger properties. Figure 4
shows that this is no longer the case if property taxes are estimated using models that account for building
volumes (models 3 and 4). Predicted values, though consistently below the true property value, track it
closely, providing a justification for using the estimated parameters from model 4 to predict the value of
residential properties in our urban Kigali sample.

Comparing predicted to actual land and property values (figure 5) suggests a good fit irrespective of the
specification chosen and a positive relationship between tax revenue and parcel area. Note that current lease
fees are more regressive than a hypothetical 1% property tax: average annual lease fees for the largest
residential properties in the regression sample would be less than US$200, compared to US$400 for a 1%
tax. The gap between property tax and land lease fees narrows as parcel size approaches the mean or median
(525 or 399 m2), implying that a property tax would be more progressive.

3.4 Exploring the Impact of Changes in Tax Base and Exemptions

Beyond using the results to predict residential property values in our study area and comparing the total
revenue potential of a property tax to what is or could be collected under the current lease system, the
hedonic regression allows us to explore via simulations what would happen if taxes were levied only on
land or if certain exemptions were adopted. Table 7 shows that, using the current system, potential lease
fees from all residential properties in urban Kigali sold in 2013-16 would be US$552,923. A 1% flat rate




                                                      12
could raise some US$2.6 million—more than four times the lease fees.23 Extrapolating this to all urban
residential properties in Kigali suggests that a move from the current lease fee, which has tax revenue
potential of US$ 4.9 million but collects only about US$ 2 million, to a 1% value-based tax could increase
revenue to between US$ 16 and US$ 19.3 million based on predictions from the spatial error (table 7) or
the lag model (appendix table 5).

Rather than a 1% flat fee, a proposal being discussed in government circles is to levy separate fees on land
and on buildings. One such proposal is to exempt the first RWF 30 million of a residential property’s market
value from property tax and levy a 1% property tax on the remainder while also charging a land tax of RWF
70/m2 (or more in premium locations) on properties below 300 m2 plus a 50% surcharge on any area above
300 m2. Without land price data or structure replacement cost, this requires decomposing the observed
market value of properties into the values of land and structure. Using simple hedonic methods (Diewert et
al. 2015; Kuminoff and Pope 2013), the value of the property is defined as:

                                                                                 ,

where V denotes the value of the property, L the quantity of land, S the quantity of structure, and Pl and Ps
the prices of land and structure. As prices for land and structures are often correlated, restrictions on
parameters are needed. Given it appears from our data that prices of land and structure vary by district, we
also controlled for district fixed effects and, assuming that the fixed community characteristics affect only
the value of the land (Eurostat 2013), attributed these to land values. We estimated a function of the form

                                                                                              ,

where Vid is the value of property i located in district d. The district fixed effects,                           , and            , measure
the components of land value and                         measures the structure value proxied by the volume of existing
buildings in cubic meters of property i in district d; and                       is the error term at the property level. Results
in appendix table 4 suggest that, at the mean of parcel area and building volume, the land share of property
values is 39–40 percent in the city’s three main districts,24 resulting in an average value per residential
parcel of US$ 12,175, US$ 11,611 and US$ 7,977 (or a value of US$ 24.6, US$ 19.5, and US$ 19.0/m2,
respectively) and an average building value of US$ 17,924, US$ 12,843 and US$ 12,881.

Using 40% as the average value of land, this suggests that, with the proposed exemption, only the top 5.1%
of urban Kigali’s residential properties would pay building tax. This would reduce potential tax revenue to
48% of what could be obtained using a flat 1% property tax (with 85% of yield from the land tax). A failure
to ground proposed exemptions in actual price distributions and a failure to assess the revenue implications

23
  The difference in estimated property taxes using the actual sales price and predicted property values is about US$560,000.
24
  Mean parcel areas and building volumes in Gasabo district are 497 m2 and 470 m3; in Kicukiro district are 605 m2 and 569 m3; and in Nayrugenge
district are 423 m2 and 353 m3.

                                                                      13
of such proposals ex ante thus may result in adoption of approaches that are not only unfair but also yield
only a fraction of what may be possible. To illustrate the usefulness of low cost methods to obtain potential
yield from a property tax but also to ex ante assess revenue implications of alternative rate structures or
exemptions, table 7 uses price predictions from the preferred (spatial error) model for exemption cut-offs
set at 25% or 50% of mean property value.25

4. Conclusion and Policy Implications

With current processes of urbanization differing from those observed historically in several respects, a city’s
competitiveness will increasingly depend on its ability to address the ‘demons of density’ by planning ahead
and raising the revenue needed to provide services effectively. The case of Kigali illustrates that high
resolution remotely sensed imagery can be used to reliably check the completeness of valuation rolls and,
if data on land values are available, also run land valuation models at a fraction of the time and resources
required by more traditional technologies. This can enable cities in developing countries to augment the
financial resources at their disposal, lessening dependence on central transfers; enhancing service quality;
and possibly also helping to ensure currency of property registries to make private property rights more
secure (Salm 2017).

To complement the results obtained here, three areas of enquiry seem promising. First, even if spatial data
can be made available at low cost, least-cost (sampling) strategies to obtain the land values required to run
a meaningful CAMA model are needed. Second, while several avenues to translate improved coverage with
data on property tax into higher revenue exist—e.g., by reducing the cost of tax collection through mobile
payments, applying peer pressure, etc.—knowledge on how to most effectively use these, or combine with
adoption of differential rate structures, remains limited. Finally, the spatial data underpinning property tax
rolls can also widen the range of options open to both the public and private sectors, from setting and
enforcing building and planning standards to finding the most cost-effective ways to modernize
infrastructure and other service provision and assessing the potential benefits from spatial data in this area
would be of great interest for future research.




25
     Similar results for the spatial autoregressive lag model are presented in appendix table 5.

                                                                            14
Table 1: Coverage of Registry or Cadaster in Main City by Region, 2017
                                        EAP        ECA       LAC       MENA    OECD        SAS        SSA       Total
 Most plots in main city registered      56.0      57.7      18.8        47.6   87.1       14.3       14.6      42.1
 Most plots in main city mapped          52.0      65.4      34.4        47.6   93.5       14.3       12.5      45.8
 Cadaster is digital                     28.0      46.2      28.1        14.3   87.1       14.3        4.2      32.1
 Cadaster and registry linked            32.0      76.9      31.3        81.0   87.1       14.3       31.3      51.6
 No. of countries                         25        26        32          21     31          7         48        190
Source: Data from 2017 ‘Doing Business,’ www.doingbusiness.org.
Note: EAP = East Asia and Pacific; ECA = Eastern Europe and Central Asia; MENA= Middle East and North Africa; SAS = or
South Asia; and SSA = Sub-Saharan Africa regions.




                                                          15
Table 2: Trends in Collection of Property Taxes by Economic National Groups, 1990–2014, Percent
                                                         1990–94      1995–99     2000–04       2005–09       2010–14
 Property tax as     Advanced market economies             1.8          1.7          1.7            1.7          1.7
 share of GDP        Emerging market economies             0.4          0.4          0.5            0.5          0.6
                     Low income developing                 0.2          0.2          0.2            0.2          0.2
 Property tax as     Advanced market economies            0.047        0.045        0.046         0.046         0.045
 share of tax        Emerging market economies            0.013        0.015        0.021          0.02         0.022
 revenue (%)         Low income developing                0.009        0.007        0.009         0.007         0.005
Source: IMF Government Financial Statistics. Samples: 36 advanced economies, 62 emerging markets, and 22 low-income
developing economies.




                                                           16
 Table 3: The Land Registry in Rwanda, Kigali, and the Study Area, Parcel Characteristics and Transactions since 2013
                                                          Rwanda                   Kigali city                Study area
 Characteristics of registered parcels
 Number of registered parcels                            11,437,040                  395,978                    136,555
 Area of registered parcels (ha)                          2,064,176                   69,831                     14,210
 Parcel size (ha)                                            0.18                      0.18                       0.10
      Residential                                            0.13                      0.09                       0.07
      Agricultural                                           0.19                      0.20                       0.19
 Share of parcels (area) by land use type
      Residential                                           11 (8)                   35 (17)                    46 (72)
      Agricultural                                         64 (66)                   49 (56)                    30 (16)
      Commercial                                             1 (1)                     1 (2)                      4 (1)
      Forest                                                 8 (9)                     3 (7)                      3 (1)
      Admin./science/social                                 0.3 (1)                   0.5 (3)                     4 (0)
      Not categorized                                      13 (13)                    9 (12)                     10 (6)
 Parcels under lease (%)                                    97.76                     98.90                       100
 Transactions since 2013
      No. of properties sold                                85,797                    40,253                     19,036
      … of which residential                                47,287                    28,879                     16,730
      … of which agricultural                               38,510                    11,374                     2,306
      Sale value, residential property ($/m2)               27.52                     39.98                      51.16
      Sale value, agricultural land ($/m2)                   3.84                      7.47                      10.56
Source: RNRA LAIS database as of Dec 31, 2016.
Note: The study area covers that part of urban Kigali for which imagery to generate building heights was available (see figure 1).




                                                                17
Table 4: Lease Fee Collection in Urban Kigali, 2015
                                                             Residential   Agricultural   Others
 Parcels with lease fee obligation                             112,143         454         3,496
   Mean size (m2)                                                726         49,925        4,781
 Parcels with declared amount                                   44,985         245         1,130
 Parcels paying lease fees                                      37,025         189          942
   Mean size (m2)                                                677         19,201        3,932
 Lease fee obligation (US$)                                   6,742,827       7,548       743,042
 Lease fees declared at RRA (US$)                             2,444,347      14,774       205,640
 Lease fees paid to RRA (US$)                                 1,947,081      10,215       122,046
Source: LAIS and RRA, 2015.
Note: 40,887 agricultural parcels smaller than 2 ha are exempt.




                                                               18
Table 5: Statistics for the Study Area Drawn from Satellite Imagery
                                                                    Total           Urban             Rural           Source
 Parcels
 Mean parcel area (m2)                                             544.04           524.27            699.00           LAIS
 Mean parcel area (m2)                                             419.56           399.15            565.11           LAIS
 Property price (US$/m2)                                            52.06            55.96            21.55            LAIS
 Distance to CBD (km)                                                6.01            5.56              9.55
 Distance to tarred road (m)                                       475.48           391.76           1131.60            RF
 Distance to primary school (m)                                    704.48           612.95           1421.83            SF
 Mean building volume (m3)                                         475.00           486.13            387.77            SI
 Median building volume (m3)                                       295.73           303.78            242.86            SI
 No. of parcels                                                     15545           13786              1759            LAIS
 Villages
 Share of area under buildings                                       0.18            0.20              0.05             SI
 Mean building height (m)                                            3.66             3.70             3.42             SI
 SD building height                                                  1.56            1.60              1.27             SI
 Number of villages                                                  740              648               92
 Cells
 Size (km2)
 Residential area (m2)                                             829361          840286            791580            LAIS
 No. of residents employed in local establishments                  1,111            1,329             360              EC
 No. of cells                                                        107               83               24
 Sector level
 No. of sectors                                                       32               22               10
 Size (km2)
Source: Data from LAIS, NISR establishment census (EC), NISR population and housing census (PC), NISR school shapefile (SF),
RTDA road network shapefile (RS), and stereo satellite imagery (SI).
Note: The observations include parcels sold several times in 2013–16. After dropping duplicates the regression analysis was based
on 12,592 unique parcels from urban areas.




                                                               19
Table 6: Hedonic Price Regression Results, Urban Kigali, Spatial Error Model
                                                             (1)             (2)                        (3)                 (4)
Log of parcel area in sqm                                 0.692***       0.665***                    0.578***           0.558***
                                                           (0.009)        (0.009)                     (0.010)             (0.009)
Log distance from the village to the CBD in km           -0.390***         -0.124                   -0.203***             -0.069
                                                           (0.105)        (0.082)                     (0.065)             (0.052)
Log number of workers at the cell level in 2014           0.108***       0.097***                    0.070***           0.061***
                                                           (0.021)        (0.020)                     (0.019)             (0.018)
Log of residential land at the cell level                   0.037           0.020                      0.010               0.018
                                                           (0.034)        (0.032)                     (0.029)             (0.027)
Log distance to tarmac road in meters                                    -0.157***                                      -0.135***
                                                                          (0.008)                                         (0.008)
Log distance to a primary school in meters                               -0.053***                                      -0.046***
                                                                          (0.020)                                         (0.018)
Log volume of buildings in m3                                                                          0.169***          0.165***
                                                                                                        (0.005)           (0.005)
Density of built up area of the village                                                                1.225***         1.092***
                                                                                                        (0.130)           (0.127)
Log average height of buildings at the village in meters                                               1.590***          1.623***
                                                                                                        (0.147)           (0.142)
Log SD of building height at the village in meters                                                    -0.312***         -0.373***
                                                                                                        (0.054)           (0.053)
Constant                                                        4.665***            5.899***           2.654***          3.540***
                                                                 (0.451)             (0.431)            (0.401)           (0.386)
Number of observations                                            12,592             12,592             12,592            12,592
Log Likelihood                                                 -14,672.830         -14,494.370       -13,982.850       -13,835.030
Wald Test (df = 1)                                            9,528.585***        5,194.450***      3,499.423***      2,296.457***
Lambda                                                          0.905***            0.869***           0.834***         0.787***
Note: Dependent variable is the log of the sales price per parcel for residential properties in Kigali in 2013-16. The spatial weights
are based on threshold distance of 435m at which each property has at least one neighbor. Alternative distance band weights (750m,
1,000m, 1,500m, and 5,000m) were used, but the one of 500m produced better fit using the likelihood ratio and AIC criteria.
Standard errors in parenthesis: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. The ‘spdep’ package of R was
used for the estimation.




                                                                 20
Table 7: Predictions for estimated Tax Revenue from a 1% Property Tax with various exemptions
                                                                              Est. revenue (USD)            Share of baseline
  A. Only properties sold in 2013-16 (in sample prediction)
  Lease fee (“current rate”)                                                          552,923
  1% property tax using reported sales price                                         2,616,113
  1% property tax using estimated price                                              2,081,242
  B. All properties in urban Kigali (out of sample prediction)
  Memo item: Potential lease fee using current rates                                 4,908,248
  Baseline: 1% property tax
  1% property tax using estimated price                                             15,984,606
  Scenario 2 (RWF 30 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.41
  Building tax                                                                       1,185,989                     0.07
  Total                                                                              7,720,185                     0.48
  Scenario 3 (25% or RWF 5 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.41
  Building tax                                                                       8,877,086                     0.56
  Total                                                                             15,411,282                     0.96
  Scenario 4 (median or RWF 9 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.41
  Building tax                                                                       7,463,678                     0.47
  Total                                                                             13,997,874                     0.88
  Scenario 5 (mean or RWF 13 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.41
  Building tax                                                                       6,202,656                     0.39
  Total                                                                             12,736,852                     0.80
Note: Results are based on the error model (f) and apply to our study area.
Scenario 2 involves a 1% of building value exempting all structures with values less than RWF 30 million (US$ 38,120) plus a
land tax (RWF 70 /m2 for area < 300 m2 plus RWF 105/m2 for area > 300m2) in line with the Government’s current proposal. To
illustrate revenue implications of different exemption structures, scenarios 3, 4, and 5 set the value of buildings to be exempted
from taxation at the first quartile (US$ 4,927), median (US$ 8,277), and mean (US$ 11,055) of the building value distribution,
respectively. Current lease fee rates imply that 0.45% pay RWF 5/m2, 0.16% pay 10/m2, 14% pay RWF 30/m2, and 86% pay RWF
70/m2.




                                                               21
Figure 1: Study Area Relative to Kigali’s Administrative Boundary




                                                         22
Figure 2: Estimated Building Heights, Central Kigali




                                                       23
Figure 3: Estimated Building Heights, Higher-Density Neighborhood




                                                  24
Figure 4: Within-sample Prediction of Potential Property Tax Liability, Model Results Compared

          400  300
   Amount in US$
      200 100
          0




                     0               2               4               6                  8
                                   Ln volume of buildings in cubic meter

                            Lease fee                             Property tax model 1
                            Property tax model 2                  Property tax model 3
                            Property tax model 4                  Property tax actual price


Note: A 1% ad valorem property tax rate is assumed throughout.




                                                             25
Figure 5: Within-sample Prediction of Property Tax Liability, Model Results Compared




Note: A 1% ad valorem property tax rate is assumed throughout.




                                                             26
Appendix Table 1: Hedonic Price Regression Results, Urban Kigali, OLS
                                                    (1)                                    (2)              (3)              (4)
Log of parcel area in sqm                       0.781***                               0.717***          0.575***         0.552***
                                                 (0.010)                                (0.010)          (0.010)           (0.010)
Log distance from the village to the CBD in km  -0.280***                                -0.016         -0.240***         -0.098***
                                                 (0.030)                                (0.029)          (0.026)           (0.026)
Log number of workers at the cell level in 2014  0.239***                              0.152***          0.061***         0.044***
                                                 (0.010)                                (0.010)          (0.010)           (0.010)
Log of residential land at the cell level       -0.192***                              -0.070***          0.004           0.040***
                                                 (0.014)                                (0.014)          (0.014)           (0.013)
Log distance to tarmac road in meters                                                  -0.241***                          -0.145***
                                                                                        (0.006)                            (0.006)
Log distance to a primary school in meters                                             -0.117***                          -0.059***
                                                                                        (0.011)                            (0.010)
Log volume of buildings in m3                                                                            0.195***         0.186***
                                                                                                         (0.005)           (0.005)
Density of built up area of the village                                                                  2.571***         1.947***
                                                                                                         (0.093)           (0.095)
Log average height of buildings at the village in
                                                                                                         2.783***         2.580***
meters
                                                                                                         (0.098)           (0.096)
Log SD of building height at the village in
                                                                                                        -0.506***         -0.538***
meters
                                                                                                          (0.039)          (0.038)
Longitude, decimal degree                              7.062***                        3.936***          3.320***         2.032***
                                                        (0.419)                         (0.404)           (0.366)          (0.362)
Latitude, decimal degree                                 -0.327                          0.079           1.918***         1.827***
                                                        (0.399)                         (0.379)           (0.346)          (0.341)
Constant                                             -206.820***                     -111.092***        -95.100***       -55.417***
                                                       (12.673)                        (12.211)          (11.055)         (10.938)
Number of observations                                  12,592                          12,592            12,592           12,592
R2                                                       0.359                           0.432             0.529            0.551
Adjusted R2                                              0.358                           0.432             0.528            0.551
Residual Std. Error                                      0.910                           0.856             0.780            0.762
F Statistic                                          1,172.842***                    1,197.294***      1,411.107***     1,287.790***
Spatial autocorrelation tests on the OLS
residuala
Moran’s I                                                                                                                    0.104
p-value                                                                                                                     2.2e-16
LMerr                                                                                                                        3961.5
p-vlaue                                                                                                                     2.2e-16
LMlag                                                                                                                        1821.5
p-vlaue                                                                                                                     2.2e-16
Robust LMerr                                                                                                                 2407.3
p-vlaue                                                                                                                     2.2e-16
LMlag                                                                                                                        267.32
p-vlaue                                                                                                                     2.2e-16
Note: Dependent variable is the log of the sales price per parcel for residential properties in Kigali over the 2013-16 period. Standard
errors in parenthesis: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. The estimation is done in R.
aThe reported test statistics are for the spatial weights defined at a threshold distance band of 435m for which each property has at

least one neighbor. Alternative threshold distances (750m, 1000m, 1500m and 5000m) are also used, but the Moran’s I is the
highest at 435m. The same is true for the other statistics.




                                                                    27
Appendix Table 2: Hedonic Price Regression Results, Urban Kigali, Spatial Lag Model
                                                           (1)                (2)                     (3)                  (4)
Log of parcel area in sqm                               0.622***         0.610***                  0.524***            0.514***
                                                         (0.009)           (0.009)                  (0.009)             (0.009)
Log distance from the village to the CBD in km         -0.108***          -0.037**                -0.203***           -0.108***
                                                         (0.014)           (0.016)                  (0.065)             (0.015)
Log number of workers at the cell level in 2014         0.128***         0.095***                  0.070***            0.049***
                                                         (0.009)           (0.009)                  (0.019)             (0.009)
Log of residential land at the cell level              -0.101***            -0.049                   0.010             0.040***
                                                         (0.010)           (0.011)                  (0.029)             (0.027)
Log distance to tarmac road in meters                                    -0.119***                                    -0.096***
                                                                           (0.006)                                      (0.006)
Log distance to a primary school in meters                               -0.052***                                       -0.023
                                                                           (0.010)                                      (0.016)
Log volume of buildings in m3                                                                       0.175***           0.171***
                                                                                                     (0.005)            (0.005)
Density of built up area of the village                                                             1.391***           1.142***
                                                                                                     (0.100)            (0.100)
Log average height of buildings at the village in meters                                            0.721***           0.825***
                                                                                                     (0.106)            (0.117)
Log SD of building height at the village in meters                                                   -0.076*          -0.150***
                                                                                                     (0.039)            (0.045)
Constant                                                      -0.802***         0.523***           -1.551***            -0.589*
                                                                (0.151)           (0.189)            (0.234)            (0.386)
Number of observations                                          12.592            12,592             12,592             12,592
Log Likelihood                                               -14,852.420       -14,645.330        -14,056.620        -13,923.010
Wald Test (df = 1)                                          5,324.495***      2,989.083***       1,661.369***       1,025.168***
Rho                                                            0.770***         0.673***            0.576***           0.507***
Note: Dependent variable is the log of the sales price per parcel for residential properties in Kigali in the 2013-16 period. The
spatial weights are based on threshold distance of 435m at which each property has at least one neighbor. Alternative distance band
weights (750m, 1,000m, 1,500m and 5,000m) were used, but the one of 500m produced better goodness of fit using the likelihood
ratio and AIC criteria. Standard errors in parenthesis: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. The
estimation is done using ‘spdep’ package of R.




                                                                28
Appendix Table 3: Mean Squared Prediction Error Compared
        Model                                    MPE
 1      OLS (all vars)                           1.785
 2      SAR (Model 1)                            1.839
 3      SAR (Model 2)                            1.809
 4      SAR (Model 3)                            1.719
 5      SAR (Model 4)                            1.701
 6      SER (Model 1)                            1.794
 7      SER (Model 2)                            1.770
 8      SER (Model 3)                            1.696
 9      SER (Model 4)                            1.678




                                                     29
Appendix Table 4: Results, Decomposing Property Value into Components, OLS
                                                                                      (1)
 Area in sq. m., Gasabo district                                                   25.17***
                                                                                    (0.802)
 Area in sq. m., Kicukiro district                                                 5.288***
                                                                                    (0.553)
 Area in sq. m., Nayarugenge district                                              45.49***
                                                                                    (1.985)
 Volume of buildings in cubic m., Gasabo district                                  38.64***
                                                                                    (0.764)
 Volume of buildings in cubic m., Kicukiro district                                22.24***
                                                                                    (0.793)
 Volume of buildings in cubic m., Nayarugenge district                             35.83***
                                                                                    (2.139)
 Gasabo district                                                                    -1,027*
                                                                                    (611.4)
 Kicukiro district                                                                 8,030***
                                                                                    (671.5)
 Nayarungenge district                                                            -10,860***
                                                                                    (1,088)
 Observations                                                                       12,592
 R-squared                                                                           0.565
Standard errors in parentheses: *** significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%.




                                                                 30
Appendix Table 5: Estimated Revenue from a 1% Property Tax, Study Area, Lag Model
                                                                              Est. revenue (USD)            Share of baseline
  A. Only properties sold in 2013-16 (in sample prediction)
  Lease fee (“current rate”)                                                          552,923
  1% property tax using reported sales price                                         2,616,113
  1% property tax using estimated price                                              2,081,242
  B. All properties in urban Kigali (out of sample prediction)
  Potential lease fee (using current rates)                                          4,908,248
  Baseline: 1% property tax
  1% property tax using estimated price                                             19,279,541
  Scenario 2 (RWF 30 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.34
  Building tax                                                                       2,522,892                     0.13
  Total                                                                              9,057,088                     0.47
  Scenario 3 (25% or RWF 5 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.34
  Building tax                                                                      10,915,960                     0.57
  Total                                                                             17,450,156                     0.91
  Scenario 4 (median or RWF 9 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.34
  Building tax                                                                       9,455,471                     0.49
  Total                                                                             15,989,667                     0.83
  Scenario 5 (mean or RWF 13 mn./ 300m2):
  Land lease fee                                                                     6,534,196                     0.34
  Building tax                                                                       7,832,834                     0.41
  Total                                                                             14,367,030                     0.75
Note: Results are based on the lag model (4) and apply to our study area.
Scenario 2 involves a 1% of building value exempting all structures with values less than RWF 30 million (US$ 38,120) plus a
land tax (RWF 70/m2 for area < 300 m2 plus RWF 105/m2 for area > 300m2) in line with the Government’s current proposal. To
illustrate revenue implications of different exemption structures, scenarios 3, 4, and 5 set the value of buildings to be exempted
from taxation at the first quartile (US$ 4,795), median (US$ 8,920), and mean (US$ 13,334) of the building value distribution,
respectively.




                                                               31
References

Ali, D. A., K. Deininger, and M. Duponchel. 2017. "New Ways to Assess and Enhance Land Registry Sustainability: Evidence
        from Rwanda." World Development 99, 377–94.
Almy, R. 2013. "A Global Compendium and Meta-Analysis of Property Tax Systems." in L. I. o. L. Policy (ed.), Working Paper,
        Cambridge, MA.
——. 2014. "Valuation and Assessment of Immovable Property." Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism # 19, Organisation for
        Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.
——. 2015. "Property Valuation and Taxation in Lithuania." Land Tenure Journal, 15(2), 2948.
Anselin, L., A. Bera, R. Florax, and M. Yoon. 1996. "Simple Diagnostic Tests for Spatial Dependence," Regional Science and
        Urban Economics, 26, 77–104.
Bahl, R., and S. Wallace. 2008. "Reforming the Property Tax in Developing Countries: A New Approach." International Studies
        Program Working Paper Series, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University
Banzhaf, H. S., and N. Lavery. 2010. "Can the Land Tax Help Curb Urban Sprawl? Evidence from Growth Patterns in
        Pennsylvania." Journal of Urban Economics 67(2): 169–79.
Bärisch, S., P. d’Angelo, A. Müller, and F. Lang. 2017. "Operationelle Photogrammetrie Aus Dem All – Digitale
        Oberflächenmodelle Aus Höchstauflösenden Satellitenbilddaten." In Geoinformationssysteme 2017: Beitraege Zur 4.
        Münchner Gi Rund, edited by T. H. Kolbe, et al. Berlin: VDE Verlag.
Barlow, C. 2015. "Meeting Challenges of Land & Property Administration in Developing Countries." Fair & Equitable 5(8):3–8.
Besley, T., E. Ilzetzki, and T. Persson. 2013. "Weak States and Steady States: The Dynamics of Fiscal Capacity." American
        Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5(4): 205–35.
Besley, T. and T. Persson. 2014. "Why Do Developing Countries Tax So Little?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(4): 99–
        120.
Blochliger, H. 2015. "Reforming the Tax on Immovable Property: Taking Care of the Unloved." OECD Economics Department
        Working Papers: 1205,OECD Publishing, Paris.
Blochliger, H., C. Hilber, O. Schoni, and M. von Ehrlich. 2017. "Local Taxation, Land Use Regulation, and Land Use: A Survey
        of the Evidence." OECD Economics Department Working Paper 1375, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Casaburi, L., and U. Troiano. 2016. "Ghost-House Busters: The Electoral Response to a Large Anti-Tax Evasion Program."
        Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(1): 273–314.
Castro, L., and C. Scartascini. 2015. "Tax Compliance and Enforcement in the Pampas Evidence from a Field Experiment." Journal
        of Economic Behavior and Organization 116: 65–82.
Chirico, M., et al. 2017. "Procrastination and Property Tax Compliance: Evidence from a Field Experiment." NBER Working
        Papers: 23243. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Cambridge, MA.
Collier, P., et al. 2017. "Land and Property Taxes for Municipal Finance." International Growth Center, London.
Collier, P., and A. J. Venables. 2017. "Who Gets the Urban Surplus?" C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers 12001, Center for Economic
        Policy and Research, Washington, DC.
Dachis, B., G. Duranton, and M. A. Turner. 2012. "The Effects of Land Transfer Taxes on Real Estate Markets: Evidence from a
        Natural Experiment in Toronto." Journal of Economic Geography 12(2): 327–54.
De Cesare, C. M. 2012. Improving the Performance of the Property Tax in Latin America. Policy Focus Reports. Cambridge,
        Mass.:Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
delCarpio, L. 2015. "Are the Neighbors Cheating? Evidence from a Social Norm Experiment on Property Taxes in Peru." Princeton,
        NY. [[publisher?]]
Diewert, W. E., J. de Haan, and R. Hendriks. 2015. "Hedonic Regressions and the Decomposition of a House Price Index into Land
        and Structure Components." Econometric Reviews 34(1-5): 106–26.
Epple, D., B. Gordon and H. Sieg. 2010. "A New Approach to Estimating the Production Function for Housing." American
        Economic Review 100(3): 905–24.
Ermini, B., and R. Santolini. 2017. "Urban Sprawl and Property Tax of a City's Core and Suburbs: Evidence from Italy." Regional
        Studies 51(9): 1374–86.
Eurostat. 2013. "Handbook on Residential Property Prices Indices." Methodologies & Working Papers, European Union,
        Luxembourg.
Fay, M., and C. Opal. 1999. "Urbanization without Growth: A Not-So-Uncommon Phenomenon." Policy Research Working Paper
        Series 2412, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Franzsen, R., and W. McCluskey. 2017. Property Tax in Africa. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Glaeser, E. 2011. Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier.
        New York: Penguin Group, Penguin Press.
Glaeser, E. L. 2014. "A World of Cities: The Causes and Consequences of Urbanization in Poorer Countries." Journal of the
        European Economic Association 12(5): 1154–99.
Gollin, D., R. Jedwab, and D. Vollrath. 2016. "Urbanization with and without Industrialization." Journal of Economic Growth
        21(1): 35-70.
Gollin, D., M. Kirchberger, and D. Lagakos. 2017. "In Search of a Spatial Equilibrium in the Developing World." NBER Working
        Paper 23916, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc,, Cambridge, MA.


                                                              32
Gonzalez-Navarro, M., and C. Quintana-Domeque. 2016. "Paving Streets for the Poor: Experimental Analysis of Infrastructure
        Effects." Review of Economics and Statistics 98(2): 254–67.
Grover, R., M.-P. Torhonen, P. Munro-Faure, and A. Anand. 2017. "Achieving Successful Implementation of Value-Based
        Property Tax Reforms in Emerging European Economies." Journal of European Real Estate Research 10(1): 91 National
        Bureau of Economic Research, Inc,106.
Hallsworth, M. 2014. "The Use of Field Experiments to Increase Tax Compliance." Oxford Review of Economic Policy 30(4): 658–
        79.
Henderson, J. V., A. Storeygard, and U. Deichmann. 2017. "Has Climate Change Driven Urbanization in Africa?" Journal of
        Development Economics 124: 60–82.
Hirschmueller, H. 2011. "Semi-Global Matching: Motivation, Developments and Applications." In Photogrammetric Week 2011,
        edited by D. Fritsch. Berlin: VDE Verlag.
Hortas-Rico, M. 2014. "Urban Sprawl and Municipal Budgets in Spain: A Dynamic Panel Data Analysis." Papers in Regional
        Science 93(4): 843–64.
IAAO. 2013. "Guidance on International Mass Appraisal and Related Tax Policy." Chicago: International Association of Assessing
        Officers.
Jacobs, J. 1986. Cities and the Wealth of Nations: Principles of Economic Life. Harmondsworth, Middlesex, UK: Penguin,.
Jedwab, R., and D. Vollrath. 2015. "Urbanization without Growth in Historical Perspective." Explorations in Economic History
        58: 1–21.
Jedwab, R., L. Christiaensen, and M. Gindelsky. 2017. "Demography, Urbanization and Development: Rural Push, Urban Pull and
        … Urban Push?" Journal of Urban Economics 98: 6–16.
Jibao, S., and W. Prichard. 2016. "Rebuilding Local Government Finances after Conflict: Lessons from a Property Tax Reform
        Programme in Post-Conflict Sierra Leone." Journal of Development Studies 52(12): 1759–75.
Kelly, R. 2013. "Making the Property Tax Work." International Center for Public Policy Working Paper Series, Andrew Young
        School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University.
Kuiiper, M., and R. Kaathman. 2015. "Property Valuation and Taxation in the Netherlands." Land Tenure Journal 15(2): 47–62.
Kuminoff, N. V., and J. C. Pope. 2013. "The Value of Residential Land and Structures During the Great Housing Boom and Bust."
        Land Economics 89(1): 1–29.
Lall, S. V., J. V. Henderson ,and A. J. Venables. 2017. Africa's Cities: Opening Doors to the World. Washington DC: World Bank.
Lutz, B. 2015. "Quasi-Experimental Evidence on the Connection between Property Taxes and Residential Capital Investment."
        American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7(1): 300–30.
McCluskey, W. J., et al. 2012. "Computer Assisted Mass Appraisal and the Property Tax." A Primer on Property Tax. Oxford, UK:
        Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
McCluskey, W. J., and R. C. D. Franzsen. 2013. "Property Taxes in Metropolitan Cities." In Financing Metropolitan Governments
        in Developing Countries, edited by R. W. Bahl, et al.,Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
McIlhatton, D., M. McCord, P. Davis, and M. Haran. 2012. "Geographic Information Systems and the Importance of Location." A
        Primer on Property Tax. Oxfofd, UK Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Nkurunziza, E. 2015. "Implementing and Sustiaining Land Tenure Regularization in Rwanda." In How Innovations in Land
        Administation Reform Improve on Doing Business, edited by T. Hilhorst and F. Meunier. Washington DC: World Bank.
Norregaard, J. 2013. "Taxing Immovable Property Revenue Potential and Implementation Challenges." IMF Working Paper 13/129
        International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Oates, W. E., and R. M. Schwab. 1997. "The Impact of Urban Land Taxation: The Pittsburgh Experience." National Tax Journal
        50(1): 1–21.
Piracha, M., and M. Moore. 2016. "Revenue-Maximising or Revenue-Sacrificing Government? Property Tax in Pakistan." Journal
        of Development Studies 52(12): 1776–90.
Presbitero, A. F., A. Sacchi, and A. Zazzaro. 2014. "Property Tax and Fiscal Discipline in OECD Countries." Economics Letters
        124(3): 428–33.
Rosen, S. 1974. "Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition." Journal of Political Economy
        82(1): 34–55.
Salm, M. 2017. Property Tax in Brics Megacities: Local Government Financing and Financial Sustainability. Cham, Switzerland:
        Springer.
Sepulveda, C., and J. Martinez-Vazquez. 2012. "Explaining Property Tax Collections in Developing Countries: The Case of Latin
        America." In Decentralization and Reform in Latin America: Improving Intergovernmental Relations, edited by G. Brosio
        and J. P. Jimenez. In association with the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. Cheltenham, U.K.
        and Northampton, Mass.: Elgar.
Venables, A. J. 2017. "Breaking into Tradables: Urban Form and Urban Function in a Developing City." Journal of Urban
        Economics 98, 88–97.
von Haldenwang, C. 2017. "The Political Cost of Local Revenue Mobilization: Decentralization of the Property Tax in Indonesia."
        Public Finance and Management 17(2): 124–51.
Weigel, J. 2017. "Building State and Citizen: How Tax Collection in Congo Engenders Citizen Engagement with the State."
        Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Youngman, J. 2016. A Good Tax: Legal and Policy Issues for the Property Tax in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln
        Institute of Land Policy.


                                                              33