FC1PY GOF                                     14334
The Role of the State in Financial
Markets
Joseph E. Stiglitz
This paper reexamines the role of the state in financial markets and identifies
seven major market failures that provide a potential rationale for government
intervention. In practice, government interventions in capital markets, even in
industrial countries, haue been pervasive. The paper provides a taxonomy of
those interventions with respect to both the objectives they serve and the instr-
ments they employ.
There is a role for the government in financial markets, but the success of
government interventions has been mixed. It is important that interventions be
well designed. The paper sets out principles of government regulatory interven-
tions and applies them to prudential regulation. It then e-xamines three other
areas of intervention-directed credit, financial repression, and competition
policy-and identifies circumstances in which some amount of financial repres-
sion may actually be beneficial.
T       he role of the government in financial markets is a long-standing debate
that has engaged economists around the world. There are certain recur-
rent themes in this debate.
The history of modern capitalism has been marked by the linked phenomena
of financial crises and economic recessions. Although bank runs are not as
prevalent as they were in the nineteenth century, the economic costs of finan-
Joseph E. Sriglitz is a member of the Council of Economic Advisers. The views expressed are solely those
of the author and are not necessarily those of any institution with which he is or has been affiliated.
This paper has received support from the Institute for Policy Reform, the National Science Foundation,
rhe Hoover Institution, the Sloan Foundation, the Center for Economic Policy Research, and the World
Bank. The author acknowledges with gratitude the helpful comments provided by David P. Dod and the
research assistance of Thomas Hellmann.
Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993
@ 1994 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK  19



cial .Y.bacles-such as those associated with the collapse of the savings and
loan associations in the United States-are no smaller. Nor is the United
States the only country beset by problems; in recent years government inter-
vention has been required in Japan, in a number of European countries, and
in numerous developing countries. What action, if any, should the state take
to ensure the solvency and stability of financial institutions?
* The past decade has been marked by important financial innovations. Ne-
technologies record transactions at record speed; partly with the aid of these
new technologies, new instruments and institutions have been created. Do
these chaxnges necessitate a reevaluation of the role of the state?
* Sophisticated and well-developed capital markets are seen as the hallmark
of a developed economy. Not surprisingly, as the developing countries move
toward more sophisticated financial systems, they have sought to create the
requisite institutions. What role should the government play in creating
such systems?
* Finally, the spirit of deregulation that has been a dominant theme in eco-
nomic policy discussions during the past two decades is increasingly being
felt in financial markets as well. The daim is that market liberalization will
enable the financial system to perform its main function of allocating scarce
capital more efficiently and will thus benefit the rest of the economy. I argue
that much of the rationale for liberalizing financial markets is based neither
on a sound economic understanding of how these markets work nor on the
potential scope for government intervention. Often, too, it lacks an under-
standing of the historical events and political forces that have led govern-
ments to assume their present ro[e. Instead, it is based on an ideological
commitment to an idealized conception of markets that is grounded neither
in fact nor in economic theory.
A basic thesis of this essay is that financial markets are markedly different
from other markets; that market failures are likely to be more pervasive in these
markets; and that there exist forms of government intervention that will not
only make these markets function better but will also improve the performance
of the economy. Of course, the existence of market failure need not, by itself,
justify government intervention; financial operations are complex, and regula-
tors are beset by a variety of problems. It is argued, for instance, that the U.S.
savings and loan debade is a manifestation not of market failure but of
regulatory-or government-failure. To some extent, this view is correct, but to
conclude from this experience that there should be less government regulation is
incorrect. I argue that the problem arises because the regulations are poorly
designed. It is necessary to appreciate the limits-as well as the strengths-of
government intervention. Although views of the precise role of the government
will differ from country to country, some general principles can be identified.
Before beginning the formal analysis, some preliminary observations may be
useful. First, massive interventions in financial markets are common. In the
20                                       The Role of tbe Stae in Financia Markets



United States these include banking and securities regulations as well as direct
government involvement in lending activities. Indeed, throughout the 1980s
about 25 percent of all loans were either originated by government agencies or
carried govemment guarantees (see Schwarz 1992). There are government loan
programs for students, for small businesses, for housing, for exports, and for a
host of other worthy causes.
Second, financial debacles are ubiquitous. In recent years crises in financial
institutions have rocked Chile, Hong Kong, Malaysia, and many other econ-
omies. While popular discussion has focused on the budgetary costs of, say, the
U.S. savings and loan bailout, these costs are only part of the problem. The
financial institutions lent money on projects the returns from which were insuffi-
cient to repay the borrowed funds. A central function of financial institutions is
to direct resources to the activities with the highest returns. Evidently, however,
they failed to do this: returns in many cases were not only negative but massively
so. The problem arises from misplaced incentives, partly due to inappropriate
government policies.
Third, the extensive media coverage of the stock and bond markets makes it
tempting to conclude that these markets are the central institutions of capital-
ism. But in fact, as is shown in table 1, a relatively small fraction of total
investment is financed by new equity or bond issues. There are good theoretical
reasons for this, which I discuss at greater length below. For now, I simply note
that if raising funds were the primary function of equity markets, we would have
to judge them to be an extremely cosdy way of doing so: the transaction costs
(the resources involved in running the financial markets) amount to 25 percent
of all new investment-not just new investment finanwd through the equity
market.
The stock market is, first and foremost, a forum in which individuals can
exchange risks. It affects the ability to raise capital (although it may also contrib-
ute to management's shortsightedness), but in the end, it is perhaps more a
gambling casino than a venue in which funds are being raised to finance new
ventures and expand existing activities. Indeed, new ventures typically must
look elsewhere.
Finally, many of the widely touted financial innovations contribute little to
economic efficiency; indeed, they may be welfare-decreasing. For instance,
financial technology permits a faster recording of transactions, but it is doubtful
whether this yields significant efficiency gains, and to the extent that greater
resources are required, welfare may actually be decreased.
The last point is illustrated by a simple parable (see Summers and Summers
1989). Assume that a number of people are engaged in a productive activity-
say, listening to a lecture. By some fluke, a hundred-dollar bill falls at the feet of
each person present. Each individual has a choice: to stop paying attention and
grab the bill at once, or to wait until the end of the lecture and then pick up the
money. Although the latter option is more effic,irt (since it does not entail the
disturbance of productive activity), it is not a Nash equilibrium. Given that
Stigltz                                                            21



Table 1. Net Sources of Finance of Nonftnancia Corporations
Bank   Trade                Capital          Stazst:tal
Economy           Retentons finance  credit  Bonds  Equity  transfer  Otherb  adjustnent
Thailand
1970-76            51.41   31.94  -1.74  12.59   9.25    -         0.2S    -3.59
1977-80            52.80   30.12  -2.32  11.28  12.40    -         0.00   -4.31
1980-83            50.40   32.80  -2.42  12.65   8.62    -         0.97    -3.22
Korea, Rep. of
1985-89            40.20   27.66    -    14.35  17.63    -          -        -
1980-84            36.40   37.15    -    12.79  13.62    -          -        -
1970-79            27.60   52.30    -      4.75  14.75    -         -
Malaysia
1986-91            61.00   34.00    -       -     2.00    -        3.00      -
Taiwan (China)
1965-80            37.70   34.31    8.63   1.72  24.11    -        5.60  -11.80
1981-85            36.35   27.91   0.32   8.59  25.42    -         2.34      -
1986-90            23.59   38.11   0.9S   3.87  31.92    -         1.32      -
France
1970-85            66.30   61.50  -0.70   0.70  -0.40   2.6   -14.90    -5.10
Gernany, Fed. Rep.
1970-89            80.60   11.00  -1.90  -0.60   0.90   8.50       1.50     0.00
Japan
1970-87            17.70   28.00  -7.80   4.00   2.70    -         1.30     0.10
United Kingdom
1970-89            98.00   19.80  -1.60   2.00  -8.00   2.10    -4.10    -8.20
United States
1970-89            91.30   16.60  -3.70  17.10  -8.80    -        -3.80    -8.70
- Noc railable.
a. Data for Asian economics arc not available but are hkcly to be induded in the Other column or in the
statistical adjustent.
b. Refers to sales of assets.
Source: For Organizaton of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) country data, unpublished flow-
of-fhids figures from the Center for Economic Policy Research (cEPR), International Study of the Financing of
Indusy.
everyone else is waiting, it pays each individual to bend down to gather up not
only his hundred-dollar bill, but also that of his neighbor. But there is no real
social gain from picking up the bill a few minutes earlier, and there is a real
social cost. Many financial innovations that involve faster recording of transac-
tions do little more than allow some individuals to pick up hundred-dollar bills
faster, "forcing" others to follow suit (for a formal model see Stiglitz and Weiss
1990). Better financial markets may contribute to economic efficiency, but the
extent to which they do so requires careful scrutiny. Improvements in secondary
markets do not necessarily enhance the ability of the economy either to mobilize
savings or to allocate capital.
Earlier discussions of financial markets, particularly in developing countries,
have focused on their role in mobilizing savings for industrialization. We now
22                                              The Role of the State in Financial Markets



recognize that financial markets do much more and that how well they perform
these other functions may affect not only the extent to which they can mobilize
savings but, more broadly, the overall efficiency and rate of growth of the
economy. (For a more extensive discussion see Fama 1980; Stiglitz 1985; Stiglitz
and Weiss 1990; Greenwald and Stiglitz 1992b.) The principal roles of financial
markets are transferring capital from savers to borrowers; agglomerating capi-
tal; selecting projects; monitoring; enforcing contracts; transferring, sharing,
and pooling risks; and recording transactions, or, more generally, "running" the
medium of exchange. In this description, capital markets deal not only with
intertemporal trade but also with risk and information. The three are inexorably
linked; since intertemporal trade involves dollars today for promises of dollars
in the future, there is always the risk of default, and information about the
borrower's likelihood of repayment is critical. Thus even if we would like to
separate the exchange, risk, and information roles, we cannot.
The various functions are linked, but in ways chat are not inevitable. For
instance, banks link the transactions functions and the functions of selecting and
monitoring. With modem technologies, the transactions function can be sepa-
rated. In the cash management accounts offered by various U.S. brokerage
firms, money is transferred into and out of "banks" instantaneously. The bro-
kerage house handles the transaction, but no bank balances are kept, and
accordingly, no loan function (such as selecting and monitoring projects) is
performed.
Market Failure
Financial markets essentially involve the allocation of resources. They can be
thought of as the -brain" of the entire economic system, the central locus of
decisionmaking: if they fail, not only will the sector's profits be lower than they
would otherwise have been, but the performance of the entire economic system
may be impaired.
The standard theories of the efficiency of competitive markets are based on
the premise that there is perfect information or, more precisely, that the infor-
mation held by individuals or firms is not affected by what they observe in the
market and cannot be altered by any action they can undertake, including
acquiring more information. Thus the fundamental theorems of welfare eco-
nomics, which assert that every competitive equilibrium is Pareto efficient, pro-
vide no guidance with respect to the question of whether financial markets,
wshich are essentially concerned with the production, processing, dissemination,
and utilization of information, are efficient. On the contrary, economies with
imperfect information or incomplete markets are, in general, not constrained
Pareto efficient (Greenwald and Stiglitz 1986); there are feasible government
interventions that can make all individuals better off. Thus not only is there no
presumption that competitive markets are efficient, but there is a presumption
that they are inefficient. Moreover, even with no other barriers to entry, in the
Stiglitz                                                          23



presence of costly information there is a presumption that markets will not, in
general, be fully competitive. This strengthens the presumption that markets, in
the absence of government intervention, are not constrained Pareto efficient.
Determining whether or how government interventions can improve matters is a
more subtle question. But first it may be useful to discuss why costly information
gives rise to market failure.
Information and Market Failure
Information differs from conventional commodities in several important ways.
Information is, in a fundamental sense, a public good. The two essential features
of a pure public good are nonrivalrous consumption (the consumption of the
good by one individual does not detract from that of another) and nonex-
cludability (it is impossible, or at least very costly, to exclude anyone from
enjoying the public good). Information possesses both of these attributes. (For
instance, if I tell someone something I know, I still know it; his knowledge of
that fact does not subtract from mine.) As is well known, competitive market
economies provide an insufficient supply of all public goods-including infor-
mation. Because of the difficulties of appropriating the returns to information,
there are often externalities associated with its acquisition. Others benefit from
the information acquired by an individual.
Moreover, expenditures on information can be viewed as fixed costs; they do
not need to increase with the amount of lending (although lenders may spend
more on acquiring information when larger amounts are involved). Because of
the fixed-cost nature of information, markets that are information-intensive are
likely to be imperfecdy competitive. There may, in fact, be many firns engaged
in similar activities, but it will not pay firms to obtain exactly the same
information-say, concerning a particular borrower (see Stiglitz 1975b; for a
brief discussion of the implications for credit markets see Jaffee and Stiglitz
1990).
Without perfect competition, markets will not, in general, be efficient.
Finally, if there are to be incentives to gather information, markets must be, to
some extent, informationally inefficient; not all information can be transmitted
from informed to uninformed investors (Grossman and Stiglitz 1976, 1980).
Accordingly, financial markets-whose essential role is to obtain and process
information-are likely not only to differ from markets for conventional goods
and services but to differ in ways that suggest that market failure will be particu-
larly endemic in financial markets.
Seven Market Failures in Financial Markets
We now turn to a description of several of the key manifestations of market
failure in financial markets.
24                                        The Role of the State in Financial Markets



MONITORING AS A PUBLIC GOOD. Problems of inform.ation as a public good
arise in at least two contexts in financial markets: information about the sol-
vency of financial institutions, which is obviously of great value to investors (or
depositors) who are considering entrusting funds to or withdrawing funds from
a particular financial institution; and information about the management of
these institutions, which affects the risk and return on investments.
Monitoring solvency can be viewed as one aspect of the more general problem
of monitoring the use of capital. How well an economy functions depends on the
efficiency with which its capital is allocated. It is management's responsibility to
allocate resources efficiently and to monitor the firm's workers. But who moni-
tors the managers? In principle, the answer is the board of directors. This only
pushes the question back one step: who mnonitors the board of directors? And
what incentives do they have to do a good job?
Monitoring, like other forms of information, is a public good. If one share-
holder takes actions that enhance the value of the shares of the firm (for
instance, by improving the quality of management), all shareholders benefit. If
one lender takes an action that reduces the likelihood of default-for instance,
by monitoring management more dosely-all lenders benefit. As in the case of
any public good, there is an undersupply; too little effort is expended on mon-
itoring financial institutions-with the expected consequences. First, because
the managers know that they are not being monitored, they may take inap-
propriate risks or attempt to divert funds to their own use. Second, because
investors cannot rely on financial institutions, fewer resources will be allocated
through the institutions, and they will not be able to perform their functions as
well as they might otherwise.
EXTERNALITIES OF MONITORING, SELECTION, AND ENDING. One of the most
important functions of financial institutions is to select among alternative proj-
ects and to monitor the use of the funds. The observation that another lender is
willing to supply funds reassures the potential investor. It confers an externality,
the benefit of which is not taken into account when the first lender undertakes
his or her lending activity. By the same token, the second lender may confer a
negative externality on the first lender. (Because the likelihood of default is a
function of the total amount borrowed, lenders may try to restrict borrowers
from securing funds from other sources; Arnott and Stiglitz 1991.)
There are other "within market" externalities. Investors, too, have imperfect
information. When a bank fails, they may conclude that similar events may have
adversely affected other banks as well and may decide to withdraw their funds,
possibly inducing a run.
The presence of a large number of "bad" firms seeking to raise equity makes
it more difficult for good firms to raise capital because potential investors find
it difficult to sort out the two. This is an example of the familiar kind of
externality associated with selection problems: the existence of firms that are
Sugltitz                                                            25



bad risks imposes screening costs and can even "spoiP' a market (see Stiglitz
1975c).
Some externalities extend across markets. Actions in the credit market affect
the equity market, and vice versa. For instance, the fact that a bank is willing to
lend money affects the firm's ability to raise equity capital, both because it has a
positive signaling effect and because potential stockholders know that it is more
likely that the firm will be supervised by the bank. In recent years equity owners
have exerted strong negative externalities on creditors by restructuring; by
increasing debt, they have reduced the market value of outstanding debt.
Under modern capitalism, at least for large firms with widely diversified
ownership, there is a separation of ownership and control that gives rise to an
important class of monitoring problems and externalities. Shareholders exercise
effective control neither diretly, through the proxy mechanism, nor indirectly,
through the 1akeover mechanism. Banks, through their threat not to renew
credit, often exercise far more influence. This view can be traced back to Berle
(1926) and was revived by Stiglitz (198S). In either case, those exercising control
have significant effects on others; for instance, bank monitoring, while it may
reduce the likelihood of insolvency, may also reduce the upside potential of
equity.
The design of financial institutions and regulations may affect the extent and
form of monitoring as well as the extent to which externalities are internalized.
The close relationships between banks and their borrowers observed in Japan
may facilitate monitoring (see Aoki 1992), and the fact that banks may own
shares in the firm may reduce the potential scope for conflicts of interest between
the banks and shareholders. In the United States such links are prohibited by the
Glass-Steagall Act, and banks that are involved in the management of firms
which have borrowed money may lose their seniority status as creditors in the
event of bankruptcy.
xTEmRALmnES OF FINANCIAL DISRUPTION. The macroeconomic consequences
of disruptions of the financial system provide one of the more important ratio-
nales for government intervention. The failure of even a single financial institu-
tion can have significant effects. It is often argued that the cost of bankruptcy is
greatly overestimated because the assets of the firm do not disappear but merely
change ownership. Although there may be some truth in this contention, the
essential asset of a bank-its information capital-is not easily transferred. In
the event of bankruptcy, this information capital may be largely dissipated.
Thus the bankruptcy of a single bank-and even more so the bankruptcy of
multiple banks-may disrupt the flow of credit to particular borrowers.
Bank insolvency has indirect effects as well. Borrowers may have to cur-
tail their activities, with further repercussions on customers and suppliers.
This may lead to a cascade of effects familiar to students of general equilibrium
theory (see Stiglitz 1987a). There are also signaling effects: for instance, even if a
bankruptcy does not trigger a financial panic, some depositors will withdraw
26                                       The Role of the State in Financial Markets



funds from other financial institutions because of a perceived risk of default.
These withdrawals may have an adverse effect on other financial institutions by
leading investors to question their viability. When institiutions make decisions,
however, they do not take these externalities into account; they only look at
their private costs and benefits. Thus the public interest in the solvency of
financial institutions may exceed the private interests of the owners and
managers.
Governments cannot sit idly by when faced with the impending collapse of a
major financial institution. Moreover, both banks and investors know that the
government will step in because it cannot commit itself not to intervene in the
economy. There have been isolated cases in which the government has not
intervened, but these cases have usually involved small banks whose failure
posed no threat. The difficulty of holding the govemment to specific commit-
ments is one of the central ways in which the government differs from the private
sector. The private sector relies on the government to enforce its contracts. But
who can enforce government commitments?
The government thus performs the role of an insurer, whether or not it has
explicitly issued a policy. The provision of insurance tends to alter behavior,
giving rise to the well-known problem of moral hazard; that is, the insured has a
reduced incentive to avoid the insured-against event. In this case, banks, know-
ing that they are effectively insured, may take greater risks than they otherwise
would. In particular, they may undertake risks similar to those being undertaken
by other banks, since they assume that although the government might ignore
the problems of a single bank, it could not allow the entire financial system to go
belly-up. So long as the bank does what other banks are doing, the probability
of a rescue is extremely high.
Most insurance gives rise to moral hazard problems. Insurance firms attempt
to mitigate the moral hazard problem by imposing restrictions. For instance, fire
insurance companies typically require that sprinklers be installed in commercial
buildings. Once we recognize the role of government as an insurer (willing or
unwilling), financial market regulations can be seen from a new perspective, as
akin to the regulations an insurance company imposes. The effects of some
versions of financial market liberalization are similar to an insurance company's
deciding to abandon fire codes, with similar disastrous consequences.
MISS[NG AND INCOMPLETE MARKETS. It is surprising that equity markets, even
in industrial countries, are so weak, since equity provides a mechanism for
sharing risks and there is considerable evidence that individuals (and firms) are
risk averse. In some important sense, therefore, these markets are not working
well. (See Greenwald, Stiglitz, and Weiss 1984. Contrary to the Modigliani-
Miller theorem, when information is imperfect, financial structure matters, as
does the range of available financial instruments; see Stiglitz 1988.) Similarly,
the prevalence of credit rationing suggests the existence of fundamental prob-
lems with credit markets. Not only are certain key markets (such as those
stiglitZ                                                           27



insuring a variety of risks) missing, but even long-term contracts that would
seem desirable were not available until relatively recently (in a historical sense).
In many countries their existence was the direct result of government actions (see
Rey and Stiglitz 1992).
Recent theories provide a single set of explanations for these well-documented
imperfections in the capital market: information is imperfect and costly to
obtain. Problems of adverse selection and moral hazard imply that the effective
costs of transactions in certain markets may be so high as to limit trade or to lead
to the demise of those markets (see Akerlof 1970; Greenwald, 1986; Stiglitz
1982).
The government has several marked advantages in risk-bearing. First, because
it can force membership in insurance programs, it can avoid the adverse selec-
tion problems that plague risk markets in general and insurance markets in
particular. Adverse selection has a social cost as well. Insurance firms must
spend large amounts to improve the quality of their pool of insured poli-
cyholders, and the prices (premiums and interest rates) of insurance reflect these
expenjditures.
A second advantage is the government's ability to mitigate the effects of moral
hazard that arise because lenders lack information. The government has the
power to compel the disclosure of information through a range of indirect
instruments, including taxes, subsidies, and regulations (for a discussion see
Arnott and Stiglitz 1986). Information available in the income tax system, for
instance, can be used to reduce the risks of loan default and to design loan
payments contingent on income.
A third advantage is that private markets cannot handle the kinds of social
risk associated with macroeconomic disturblances. Markets are good at insuring
individuals against accidents. But if all individuals are similar, who is to absorb
the social risk? It can be spread across generations, but only the government can
engage in such intergenerational transfers of risk.
Offsettng these advantages, however, the government is at a marked disad-
vantage in assessing risks and premiums, in part because such assessments are,
to a large extent, subjective. The government inevitably has to employ relatively
simple rules in risk assessments-rules that almost surely do not capture all the
relevant information-and political considerations will not allow it to differenti-
ate on bases that the market would almost surely employ. By contrast, the
market converts the subjective judgments of a large number of participants into
an objective standard. If a bank, say, complains about the risk premium charged
by the market (in the form of the rate it must pay to attract uninsured deposi-
tors), there is a simple answer: show the market the evidence that the risk has
been overestimated. The jury of the market renders a verdict. If the information
is credible, the risk premium will reflect that information.
The difficulties of determining whether interest rates are actually appropriate
exacerbates an ever-present problem with government lending programs: the
opportunity to provide (often hidden) subsidies. Students in the United States
28                                         The Role of the State in Financial Markets



and largc farmers in Brazil, for example, have been the beneficiaries of hidden
subsidies. The temptation to use such subsidies for political purposes is one that
many governments have found difficult to resist.
Another perspective, arguing the government should assume a significant
amount of risk within financial markets, emphasizes the government's responsi-
bility for dealing with the risks associated with the insolvency of financial in-
stitutions. If the regulatory structure is designed and enforced appropriately,
insolvencies should be relatively rare. In practice, macroeconomic downturns
are a major cause of insolvencies, and avoiding such downturns is the responsi-
bility of the government. Making the government bear the costs of a failure
to live up to its responsibilities provides a natural incentive for it to do its
job well. I
IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Earlier i noted that information naturally gives rise
to imperfect competition. This is important because the underlying belief in the
efficiency of market economies is based on the premise that competition not only
exists, but is "perfect." Yet in most countries competition in the banking sector
is limited.
The distinguishing characteristic of most markets is that any seller is willing to
sell to any buyer at the preannounced price. This is true in deposit markets, but
in loan markets borrowers may face a very limited number of suppliers and may
find it difficult to switch from one to another. Each bank has specialized infor-
mation about its customer base. A customer who has a long track record with
one bank and therefore is viewed as a good loan prospect by that bank may be
unknown to another bank and may therefore be considered a riskier prospect
(see Stiglitz and Weiss 1983). Thus the fact that there are ten lenders supplying
loans in a market does not mean that each customer has a choice of ten sup-
pliers. Even when there are many banks, competition may be limited.
PARETO INEFFICIENCY OF COMPETITIVE MARKETS. As is true for many theorems,
the proof of the fundamental theorem of welfare economics (the theorem that
underlies economists' faith in markets) employs a large number of assumptions,
some essential, some for simplification. Two of the assumptions are absolutely
crucial; in their absence, the theorem is not in general true: there must be a
complete set of markets, and information must be exogenous-that is,
unaffected by any action a participant in the market can take. As should by now
be clear, these assumptions are particularly disturbing in the case of financial
markets. Gathering information is one of the essential functions of financial
markets; sharing and transferring risk is another. Still, many risks remain unin-
sured, with the result that financial (risk) markets are incomplete.
Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986) note that when information is endogenous or
markets incomplete, the economy is not constrained Pareto optimal:2 there are
government interventions that take into account the costs of information and of
establishing markets that can make all individuals better off.
Sliglitz                                                           29



These particular market failures go beyond those referred to earlier. Even
when there are markets, and even wlhen they are competitive, private returns
diverge from social returns. The failure of the standard results concerning the
efficiency of markets can be npproached in two ways: by looking at why the
standard arguments fail or by looking at how government interventions might
improvc mattcrs.
The standard argument is based on the assumption of market-clearing prices;
prices then measure the marginal benefit of a good to a buyer and the marginal
cost to the seller. But credit markets cannot operate like ordinary auction mar-
kets, with the funds going to the highest bidder. With imperfect information,
markets may not clear. In credit markets those who are willing to pay the most
nmay not be those for whom the expected return to the lender is the highest; the
expected return may actually decrease as the intcrest rate increases becausc the
probability of default may rise. As a result, therc may be credit rationing: even
though there is an excess demand for credit, lenders may not increase the intcrest
rate. Rather, the interest rate will be set to maximize the lenders' expected
return. Thus credit is rationed when, at this profit-maximizing interest rate,
there exists excess demand for credit.
Moreover, social returns may differ from private returns. Lenders focus only
on the expected return that they receive; the total return includes the (incremen-
tal) surplus (profit) accruing to the entrepreneur. The projects with the highest
expected return to the lender may not be those with the highest total expected
retum, but they are the ones that get funded. Thus part of the rationale for
directed credit is that good projects may be rationed out of the market. Several
government programs reflect this perception of a discrepancy between social and
private retums, although in some cases the view is that the market is excessively
conservative and in other cases that it undertakes unnecessary risks.
In many countries the collapse of the real estate market has had far-reaching
effects on the entire financial system. But even short of these effects, social
returns to real estate may differ from private retums. This can be seen in a
situation where banks, instead of rationing credit, lend to those willing to pay
the highest interest rate. Consider the example of speculative real estate loans
versus loans for manufacturing. Because the maximum returns in manufacturing
are limited, there is a limit to the amount that borrowers are willing to pay. The
returns on real estate, however, are highly variable; prices can-and frequently
do-rise by more than 40 percent a year. (In any case, what matters is investors'
perceptions about the possible returns, and these indeed may be high.) So long
as there is limited liability and lenders are willing to make highly leveraged loans
and accept real estate as collateral, it pays real estate speculators to take out
loans even at seemingly exorbitant interest rates (more than 30 percent). They
are in a "heads I win, tails you lose' situation. If their hopes are realized, they
walk off with huge gains (particularly when viewed as a percentage of their
invested equity); if not, the lender is left holding the bag. Thus even if there were
no externalities associated with investing in manufacturing-no linkages outside
30                                         The Roae of tbe State in Financial Markets



the investment itself-the social returns to manufacturing might exceed those
resulting from real estate speculation. The interest rate charged does not reflect
the social returns to investment.
These arguments establish that markets may not allocate capital to the uses
with the highest return. There may be systematic deviations between social and
private returns that direct government intervention-restricting some dasses of
loans and encouraging other classes-may partially address.
UNINFORMED INVESTORS. This final category of problems has motivated con-
siderable government intervention but is not, in a formal sense, a market failure.
What happens if individuals have information but do not process it correctly?
What happens if a lender discloses the terms of the contract accurately but
consumers cannot distinguish effectively between compound and simple inter-
est, do not understand provisions concerning indexing, and so on?
Indeed, there is a more general problem: decisions concerning investments are
based on probability judgments that are outside the province of economic analy-
sis. As welfare economists, we make no judgment about whether an investor's
calculation of the relative probabilities of different outcomes is right or wrong,
as part of the general doctrine of consumer sovereignty, but for some probability
judgments there may be objective data concerning relative frequencies. Of
course, there is always a judgment call concerning whether past experience is
applicable for inferring future likelihoods. Still, research (see Kahneman and
Tversky 1974) has drawn attention to the fact that there may be systematic
biases in most individuals' probability judgments. In that case, are policymakers
to make judgments about resource allocations on the basis of misperceived
subjective probabilities or on the basis of more relevant relative frequencies
(where these can be obtained)? Should the government intervene to ensure that
individuals' subjective judgments are determined with more complete knowledge
of relative frequencies or in fact are in accord with the government's perception
of the relevant relative frequencies?
Some of the disclosure requirements imposed by governments seem designed
to make sure that firms do not take advantage of uninformed consumers. But
information is at the heart of capital markets; much trading is based on differ-
ences in information. When someone buys shares, she or he is probably more
optimistic than the seller. What information should traders be required to dis-
close? Some of the disclosure requirements imposed by government seem
addressed to these problems, w  i-h, in terms of more conventional terminology,
would fall uinder the rubric of "merit goods and bads" rather than outright
market failures. There is a consensus that, by prol;biting unfair practices, gov-
ernment helps to create a more level playing field and promote investor confi-
dence; if there is a widespread view that markets are rigged, trade will be thin
and markets will not function well. Still, there is controversy over whether these
practices benefit financial markets, whether the regulations attempting to
Sdiglitz                                                          31



restrict these practices may actually make matters worse, and whether instead
principles of "caveat emptor" should apply.
The Role of the Government
A useful taxonomy groups government interventions according to categories
that relate to how these interventions are commonly discussed in the public
policy arena. There are two alternative taxonomies, one focusing on actions, the
other on objectives.
Government actions include creating and regulating financial market institu-
tions, intervening in these institutions through other than regulatory means, and
intervening directly in the capital market (providing direct loans). In addition,
many government policies, including those pertaining to taxes, bankruptcy, and
accounting, have an intentional or unintentional effect on financial markets.
Some actions can be seen as improving financial markets or using them to
accomplish other objectives; others substitute for financial markets. In pursuing
these actions, governments may be attempting to address the kinds of market
failure described earlier. But the government resolves market failure imperfectly.
Some interventions motivated by, say, pressures from special interest groups
actually impede the functioning of markets and redirect the allocation of capital
in ways that cannot easily be related to any correction of a market failure. I do
not have space here to comment on all of these roles, but in the context of
developing countries, the first-creating market institutions-requires special
comment.
One of the most important tasks in developing countries has been the creation
of financial institutions to fill gaps in the kinds of credit provided by private insti-
tutions. In some cases the reason that the private market has not provided a
particular category of financial service or loan may be clear: default rates are high,
and at an interest rate high enough to cover these defaults, the market is simply
not viable. Often the failure may be attributable to a lack of entrepreneurship, to a
lack of creativity or an unwillingness to bear risks, or to the faa that the expected
private retums to the institution may be markedly less than the social returns.
And, because successes are quicldy imitated, it may be difficult to appropriate the
returns from novel ideas, including new financial institutions and instuuments. In
other cases there may be questions about whether a particular innovation is legal
and an unwillingness to bear the costs and risks of finding out.
In some instances the government takes primary responsibility for creating
new financial institutions or institutional arrangements; in others it takes actions
that make the establishment of certain financial institutions viable or more
likely. Let me mention three examples.
Viable equity markets require fraud laws and accounting standards to ensure
that stockholders who do not control the company receive their share of the
profits (see Greenwald and Stiglitz 1992b). The absence of these laws and
accounting standards remains an impediment in many developing countries.
32                                        The Role of the State in Financial Markets



Beyond formal rules lies a gray area in which governments have attempted to
create a level playing field so that investors are less likely to be taken advantage
of by smart operators who avoid committing outright fraud. Regulations on
insider trading and on cornering the market fall within this rubric. It may be
necessary to establish a securities and exchange commission to create confidence
in the stock market.
The "thickness" of a market is important; bid-ask spreads are typicaUly larger
in thin markets, and thin markets are more subject to manipulation, short
squeezes, and high volatility. Governments can take actions to thicken equity
markets; an example is the decision by the Korean government restricting the
debt-equity ratio of large firms, which substantially increased the magnitude of
equity issues. (Because the share issues were associated with a legal change, the
usual asymmetric information concerns that impede the effectiveness of equity
markets were less operative.)
In bond markets investors face two kinds of uncertainties, concerning the
appropriate interest rate for the maturity of the debt and the appropriate pre-
mium to reflect default risk. Much of the uncertainty associated with the first
type of risk can be resolved by a well-developed government bond market,
which provides a yield curve. Governments may create these markets, even
when they have no immediate need for the funds, simply for the information
they providce.
Another way to categorize the activities of government in financial markets is
by the stated social objective. Under this grouping, the six broad categories of
government interventions are providing consumer protection, ensuring bank
solvency, improving macroeconomic stability, ensuring competition, stimulat-
ing growth, and improving the allocation of resources.
Principles of Regulation
The government does have powers (arising from its ability to compel and pro-
scribe) that the private sector lacks. At the same time, it is subject to constraints
and limitations (including equity constraints and restricted ability to enter into
commitments) that may make it less effective than private sector enterprises.
The essential problem of public regulatory policy is to ascertain which interven-
tions can bring to bear the strength of the government so as to improve the
workings of financial markets.
Once regulations are put in place, governments must monitor banks to ensure
compliance. Regulators should be guided by certin principles in choosing what
should be reguaLted and what standards should be set.
Indirect Control Mechanisms
Not all variables are easily observable. Consider the requirement that banks take
"prudent actions" and exercise faithfully their fiduciary responsibilities. Ascer-
'tiglitz                                                          33



taining whether a particular loan is or is not prudent is tricky. Having govem-
ment regulators appraise every property to see whether the collateral is in fact
adequate is feasible but expensive. Reviewing every action to see whether there
might be a conflict of interest or a violation of a fiduciary responsibility would
be prohibitively costly. Accordingly, regulators must rely on indirect controls.
These take two forms, incentives and restrictions.
INCENTIVES. Incentive-based regulations provide an environment in which the
incentives of managers are aligned with those of regulators. Adequate net worth
requirements, for instance, provide an incentive to be prudent. If the bank goes
bankrupt, the owners have more to lose; it is as simple as that. There is a general
theorem showing that when net worth falls below a certain critical threshold,
banks switch from a risk-averse to a risk-loving stance; that is, of two investments
with equal total mean retums, banks would actually prefer the riskier loan.
RESTRAINTS. As noted earlier, insurance firms attempt to mitigate the moral
hazard problem by imposing restrictions-we could as well call them
regulations-on those they insure. Or they set different rates depending on
whether the insured party conforms to some regulation; for instance, houses
with sprinklers would qualify for lower rates for fire insurance. They thus try to
mitigate the moral hazard problem by restricting behavior that will result in a
higher probability of accident. Similar considerations apply to banking. Many
banks, if not forbidden to do so, would make bad loans to their officers and to
relatives of their officers. This may be a matter of fraud and deception: the bank
officers may be attempting to transfer wealth to themselves by charging interest
rates below the actuarially fair levels. Or it may be no more than bad
judgment-the bank officers may be enthusiastic about their own projects and
consider the probability of success very high. Because such errors are so com-
mon, because monitoring a project is so difficult, and because the opportunities
for fraud and misjudgment are so rife, it is not unreasonable for regulators to
restrict loans to insiders. But if the project is viable, the insiders should be able to
get loans from other sources.
Restrictions on loans to insiders do not completely address the problem,
however, because of "reciprocity." The owners of bank A may make loans to the
owners of bank B, and conversely, at rates that do not reflect the true actuarial
risk of default. These problems are exacerbated when the owner of a bank is an
industrial firm and the bank can be persuaded to give favorable treatnent to the
firm's suppliers and customers. Again, the cost of detecting such abuses is very
high. It is far simpler to stipulate that an industrial firm may not own a bank.
(The firm's shareholders would derive an advantage from ownership of the bank
only if the firm were to take advantage of its ownership position or if the
management of the firm-say, an automobile manufacturer-had some mana-
gerial comparative advantage in running a bank. The former is an argument
against having industrial firms own banks; the latter seems unpersuasive.)
34                                       The Rok of the State in Financial Markets



The problem we have just examined can be looked at from another perspec-
tive: banks provide their owners with a strong incentive for misjudgments that
benefit themselves, and regulators need to correct such incentive problems.
In addition, a financial institution with a substantial amount of equity in a
firm may have an incentive to lend the firm funds to "tide it over" a short-run
shortage of cash. It will be inclined to interpret the problem the firm faces as
minor, as a problem of liquidity rather than insolvency. A similar situation
occurs when a financial institution sponsors an equity issue and recommends
that its customers buy it. If the firm later faces a cash shortfall, the financial
institution has an incentive to provide funds to shore it up in order to maintain
its reputation as an issuer of equity. Its desire to maintain that reputation may
conflict with its incentives to make prudent loans. There are, of course, many
ways that a bank can aid a firm. It may provide a loan directly or make a loan to
a major customer of the finn to enible the customer to buy more of the firms'
products. Because of the difficulties of monitoring all the possible forms of aid,
it may make sense for regulators to restrain any institutions that make loans
with government deposit insurance-either implicit or explicit-from undertak-
ing certain other financial services.
Setting Regulatory Standards
The selection of the appropriate regulatory standard will depend on how well
the variable in question can be measured. It is possible that the variable is
measured with error, and, if the regulated firms have influence over what is
measured, there may be systematic bias as well. Consider the problem of the net
worth requirement. Ensuring that the bank does not become insolvent depends
on the variability of the asset portfolio as well as on the frequency with which
net worth is monitored. If net worth is monitored continuously, then as soon as
a bank's assets decrease in value, the decline in its net worth is registered, and
any bank that falls below a certain threshold is instantly dosed down. In that
case a relatively low standard might be chosen. In practice, however, there are
lags in detection and enforcement. The greater these lags, the higher the stan-
dard needed to ensure the probability that the true value of the variable in
question will be above the desired level.3
The greater the variability in the value of the assets, the higher the proba-
bility that a problem will arise, given any particular set of lags. That is why it
makes sense to have the type of risk-based capital standards that were developed
during the 1980s. Although these standards recognize that there is less risk
associated with a govemment treasury bill than with a commercial loan, the risk
adjustments are far from perfect. Even with some risk adjustment, given the
varying lags in and quality of information and the different degrees of vola-
tility in asset prices, net worth and capital requirements should be tailored to
the specific country. Thus while an argument can be made for a uniform mini-
mum standard, in practice the standards of the Bank for International Settle-
stiglitz                                                            35



ment (Bis) have become the standard. I would argue, however, that in some
countries and during some periods standards should be higher-perhaps sub-
stantially higher.
The regulations must also be based on the recognition that there are impor-
tant asymmetries of information between the bank and the regulators, since the
"books" of the bank are largely under the bank's control, so that the information
presented to regulators may quite possibly be distorted. Thus banks are in a
position to sell undervalued assets (and thereby record a capital gain over book
value) but hold on to overvalued assets and carry them on their books at book
value. When banks systematically engage in this practice, book value will sys-
tematically overestimate true value.
Resource and Incentive Problems
Limitations on resources and incentives often hamper the effectiveness of regu-
lation. Governments should do more than just complain about these limitations;
they need to recognize these limitations in the design of regulations and regula-
tory structures and try to take advantage of information and incentives within
the marketplace.
The problem concerning resources is straightforward. The administrative
resources available to the government are decisive for the effectiveness of its
performance. The limitations on salaries of government employees, as well as
other budgetary restraints, put government monitors at a marked disadvantage.
Is it likely that a $15,000-a-year (or even a $45,000-a-year) civil servant will be
able to detect the machinations of $100,000-a-year accountants? The more
complex the regulatory structure, the more likely that the differences in
resources will come into play.
The problem of incentives is more complex and involves the design and enforce-
ment of regulations. As noted earlier, private insurance firms have an incentive-
provided by the profit motive-to look for regulations that are cost-effective; that
is, regulations which reduce the occurrence of the insured-against event by enough
to warrant the inconvenience imposed on the insured and are relatively inexpen-
sive to enforce. The public sector often has no such direct incentive. Occasionally,
competition among communities and governments provides such incentives.
Many businesses are footloose and choose to locate where there is a favorable
regulatory climate. This does not necessarily mean an environment that minimizes
regulation; Singapore has established itself as a regional financial center, in part
because of the effectiveness of its regulatory system. More generally, our task as
public policy analysts is to look for cost-effective regulations.
Another concern is that incentives for enforcing the regulations may be insuf-
ficient. Bureaucrats and politicians often have an incentive to postpone the
strong enforcement of banking regulations in the hope that problems with banks
will disappear-or at least will not surface during their watch on the bridge. The
costs of postponement, which have proved to be significant, are borne by others.
36                                       The Role of the State in Financial Markets



It may be hard to design effective incentive structures where consequences of
actions today are realized only years into the future. At the very least, appropri-
ate accounting systems that reflect the costs of assuming certain risks attract
attention to what the government is doing and in this way help provide appro-
priate incentives. Thus the incentive to provide loans at less than actuarially
fair interest rates is mitigated to some extent by the requirement that the actu-
arial value of the loss be included in the budget in the year in which the loan is
made.
Since macroeconomic instability is one of the major causes of default, making
sure that the government bears some of the consequences may be an effective
incentive for stabilizing the economy. By the same token, making sure that the
government bears some of the consequences for failed financial institutions
provides it with greater incentives to monitor those institutions effectively.
Regulators do not always engage in regulatory forbearance. A significant
problem in the United States in the aftermath of the savings and loan debacle is
that regulators have been overzealous. Having been criticized for allowing too
many banks to fail and for waiting too long, they have taken the opposite tack,
and there have been widespread allegations that they have shut down banks
prematurely. The full consequences for taxpayers or investors are not taken into
account.
DscRETioN VERSUS RULES. One solution to the problem of regulatory forbear-
ance (or of overzealous regulators) would be to reduce the government's discre-
tionary judgment and establish strict guidelines under which intervention will
occur. There is always a tension between rules and discretion. It is impossible to
design rules that fit every situation. Less discretion therefore ensures a gre6;'er
chance (at least compared with perfectly exercised discretion) of inappropriate
action-say, dosing a bank that should not be shut down or allowing a "bad"
bank to stay open. Under any simple set of rules, these same two mistakes will
occur. Tightening the standards will increase the probability of one type of error
while reducing the other. Which point in the continuum is chosen depends on the
costs of the two types of errors and the relative likelihood that each will arise.
Some regulatory structures are much simpler than others and leave relatively
little scope for discretion. These include net worth and capital requirements,
with simple adjustments for risk, and ownership restrictions. By contrast, ensur-
ing that no transaction violates some fiduciary standard is costly and inevitably
entails considerable discretion.
MULTIPLE MONITORING AGENaES. Another standard objection to regulatory
structures that provide considerable discretion is that they can breed corruption.
In this connection it is useful to have more than one agency engage in monitor-
ing. Corruption aside, all monitoring is fallible. Considering the large costs
associated with allowing insolvent institutions to operate, one way of reducing
the likelihood of that occurring is to have more than one independent monitor.
Suiglitz                                                           37



A more general problem is, who monitors the monitors? In principle, the
monitors have supervisors. But often the supervisors are not well informed. If
there is more than one monitoring agency, a system of peer monitoring can be
employed; each monitoring agency in effect monitors not only the financial
institutions but also each other (see Stiglitz 1990 and Arnott and Stiglitz 1991).
Government's limited ability to monitor the regulators suggests that duplicative
regulatory oversight may have strong advantages which are well worth the extra
costs. Reformers who ignore the central importance of information and control
may look at organizational charts and suggest streamlining them to end the
allegedly wasteful duplication. Such reform efforts may, from this perspective,
be fundamentally misguided.
USING THE PRIVATE SECTOR TO EXTEND THE REACH OF REGULATION. Govern-
ment can take advantage of resources and incentives in the private sector to
stretch its regulatory reach and make its monitoring more effective. The earlier
suggestion that the government should focus on regulating such variables as net
worth or capital, which it can observe at relatively low cost, falls into this
category. Government is, in effect, using the force of private incentives; its only
role is to see that those private incentives are operative by ensuring that the firm
has enough of its own wealth at stake.
Governments need to remember too that the private market may serve as a
regulatory mechanism. A party who has been hurt by fraudulent behavior can
sue. Governments can enhance these incentives, as was done in the case of
antitrust, with treble damages. The government can also employ information
provided by markets to guide its regulatory behavior. Share prices and the prices
of (uninsured) bonds of financial institutions convey information about the
marketes confidence in those financial institutions. A fall in those prices may
provide important information for govemment regulators. And when the gov-
ernment sells off some deposit insurance risk through a reinsurance market, the
prices on that market can provide it with valuable information concerning the
risk of default.
Setting Prudential Standards
The three major principles of sound prudential regulation are to maintain high
net worth and capital requirements, to restrict interest rates on insured deposits,
and to restrict ownership and transactions where "fiduciary" standards are more
likely to be violated. I have already said something about the first and third.
After briefly elaborating on net worth requirements, I shall focus my remarks on
the second.
NET WORTH REQUIREMENTS. How important it is to measure net worth accu-
rately depends on the standards that are chosen. When net worth standards are
low, small errors may have broad consequences: a bank that is viewed as viable
38                                       The Rok of the State in Financial Markets



may actually have a negative net worth. If the net worth requirement is 20
percent of deposits and banks are closed when their net worth falls below that
level, it is less likely that the true net worth is negative, and less likely that the
government will be left holding the bag. The controversy over whether bank
assets should be marked to market needs to be viewed from this perspective. The
consensus among economists is that this would be beneficial; otherwise, a bank
may have a negative net worth even though its book value is positive. But the
bank's behavior is driven by its true net worth, not its book value. Banks claim
that marking to market results in a biased estimate because some assets are
difficult to mark to market and these assets may be undervalued. But, as noted
above, if there is a bias, it goes the other way: banks are always in a position to
realize any capital gains. In the absence of marking to market, banks may sell
assets whose market value has increased and hold assets whose market value has
declined, so that the book value of the assets systematically exceeds their true
net worth. With sufficiently high net worth requirements, the whole issue of
whether we mark to market becomes less important. By the same token, failure
to adjust deposit insurance premiums to reflect risk will be less important
because the premium need only reflect the probability that the net worth of the
bank becomes negative, and this probability (with appropriately high net worth
standards) will be quite low.
INTEREST RATE RESTEICTIONS. There is a wide body of opinion that opposes
restrictions on interest rates. But when the government is providing insurance, it
has the responsibility of any insurer to reduce the likelihood that the insured-
against event will occur. Limitations on interest rates should be viewed in this
context. Allowing banks to pay high interest rates when explicit or implicit
deposit insurance exists results in perverse incentives: banks compete for funds,
and those offering the highest interest rates (effectively guaranteed by the gov-
ernment) attract funds. But to pay those high interest rates, they have to take
high risks-augmenting the already-present incentive to take excessive risks. A
process I have described elsewhere as the Gresham's law of financial markets
takes place; risk-loving banks drive out more prudent ones.
It makes no sense for the government to allow the private sector to take advan-
tage of its implicit subsidy. If we believe that government insurance is as credible
as a government guarantee that it will pay back a treasury bill, then there is no
justification for paying higher interest rates than on treasury bills. Since banks
may be providing additional services, rates could be lower. To repeat: the regula-
tion on insured deposit rates is intended not to restrict competition but to restrict
the ability of banks to take advantage of any implicit subsidy.
Financial Repression
For the past quarter century governments of developing countries have been
warned to avoid financial repression. Financial repression provides one of the
sdglitz                                                            39



classic examples of welfare-decreasing government interventions in the market.
The standard argument against it is that low interest rates reduce savings and
thus inhibit economic growth. It is argued that because financial institutions are
essential to the efficient allocation of capital, free competitive markets are
needed to ensure that resources go to those who value them the most. The
borrowers who are willing to pay the highest interest rates on loans are those
whose projects will yield the highest return. If governments restrict interest rates
and replace efficient market allocation mechanisms with capricious public selec-
tion processes, the result is less capital, and what capital there is will be less
efficiently allocated.
These theoretical arguments have been buttressed with convincing empirical
and anecdotal evidence. Countries that abandoned financial repression did well,
and cross-sectional and time-series studies confirmed that there was a positive
relationship between growth and real interest rates. More recently, however,
this relationship has been reexamined. Studies of savings seem to indicate little
relationship between national savings and interest rates. This should not be
surprising, since theory suggests that, at least at the household level, income and
substitution effects go in opposite directions. Most econometric studies show
low interest elasticities. It is worth noting that Japan's postal savings banks paid
relatively low interest rites and yet were able to raise huge amounts of money,
suggesting that other factors (such as convenience and safety) may far outweigh
interest rates in determining the level of savings.
Recent theoretical work has emphasized the importance of the corporate veil:
the fact of imperfect information implies that funds do not move costlessly be-
tween the household and corporate sectors. Lowering interest rates can be viewed
as a transfer from the household sector to the corporate sector. Of course, if there
were no corporate veil, such a transfer would have no consequences, but if there is
a corporate veil, it may make a large difference. If the marginal propensity to save
is higher for corporations than for households (and there are a variety of reasons
why we might expect this to be so in a world of credit and equity rationing), this
transfer of wealth results in an increase in aggregate savings.
The argument that financial repression leads to inefficient allocation is equally
suspect. It is based on the failure to recognize the distinction between credit
markets and other markets. The analogy between the allocation of credit and
the allocation of other goods is fundamentally inappropriate. Closer examina-
tion suggests that financial repression can actually improve the efficiency %with
which capital is allocated, or more broadly, the total expected returns per dollar
of capital. There are several reasons for this.
First, as Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) emphasize, higher interest rates adversely
affect incentives and the mix of applicants, even when these effects are not so
strong as to outweigh the direct benefit of higher interest rates. Even if the
government selected projects at random, lowering the interest rate could
increase the expected quality of borrowers, and this effect would be even greater
if it were assumed that the government had some positive selection capabilities.
40                                         The Role of the State in Finantial Markets



Second, financial repression increases firm equity because it lowers the cost of
capital. Equity capital has several advantages over loan capital, leading to
investments with higher expected returns. The firm reduces the prospect of
bankruptcy that occurs when it cannot meet its debt obligations. (This prospect
of bankruptcy acts as a major deterrent to undertaking high-yield, high-risk
investments.) And firms are more likely to select good projects when they have
more of their own capital at stake.
Indeed, financial repression can be used as the basis of an incentive scheme to
encourage higher savings ar.d more efficient allocation of capital. Financial
repression creates a scarcity. Some will get the capital they want at the interest
rate being offered, while others will not. The government can set up a contest so
that those who perform well (as measured by, say, exports) get more access to
capital. Such contests can have strong positive effects.
The arguments against financial repression are based on a number of errors in
previous empirical studies.
�Failure to distinguish between small and large repressions. There is little
doubt that high negative rates of return can have significant deleterious
effects on the economy. These large repressions seem to have driven earlier
econometric studies. When countries with negative real interest rates are
excluded from the sample, higher real interest rates seem to be associated
with lower rates of growth.
� Failure to identify the problem. High negative rates of return are symptoma-
tic of a wider range of government failures. If 'good government" brings
about a more efficient allocation of resources and avoids severe financial
repression, there will be a negative correlation between financial repression
and growth, but it would be incorrect to infer from this that the low level of
economic growth is caused by financial repression.
Without ways of measuring "good government," it is difficult to identify
the correct causal structure. One hint at an answer is the rate of inflation.
High rates of inflation can be thought of as a reflection of "bad govern-
ment," or at least bad macroeconomic policies. The question is, correcting
for the rate of inflation (the overall quality of government), does financial
repression have a negative effect on growth? Our preliminary studies sug-
gest that it does not (Murdock and Stiglitz 1993).
* Failure to take account of demand-curve shifts. High real interest rates can
be a result of good investment opportunities (high demand for capital)
rather than of a lack of financial repression. Unless the economy is com-
pletely open, domestic interest rates do not provide a good measure of the
extent of financial repression. A better measure is the difference between
the curb market and ordinary rates of interest. Regressions for the Repub-
lic of Korea that include this variable show no evidence of a significant
effect of repression on growth (or on incremental capital-output ratios).
The estimated coefficients suggest that financial repression has a slightly
Stiglitz                                                             41



positivc effect, perhaps for the reasons cited above (Murdock and Stiglitz
1993).
Directed Credit
Programs of directed credit attempt to intervene in the way that banks allocate
credit. The theoretical rationale for such interventions in the market has been
outlined earlier: without government intervention, the bank will not allocate
funds to those projects for which the social returns are the highest. This is true
even in the absence of technological spillovers. Thus DeLong and Summers
(1990) argue that there is a strong positive correlation between investment in
machinery and economic growth-a relation that can perhaps result from
learning-by-doing and technological spillovers. But these are benefits that con-
ventional banking might simply ignore.
By the same token, the widespread problems many banks faced when real
estate markets collapsed provide strong evidence that financial institutions failed
to take social returns into account in making real estate loans. Directed credit-
this time, restrictions on certain categories of loans-may be desirable.
Rationalefor Directed Credit
Most of the successful economies of East Asia have relied on directed credit
programs. There are perhaps four arguments for undertaking such programs, as
opposed to, say, providing subsidies for sectors the government wishes to
encourage or taxing those it would like to discourage. These rationales are
discussed below.
UNDERDEVELOPED TAX SYSTEMS. Directed credit, in contrast to subsidies, does
not require the use of government to raise revenues. Because developing coun-
tries have traditionally faced budgetary constraints, they have seen directed
credit as a marked advantage. There may be less to this than meets the eye:
governments have been persuaded that they should operate like ordinary busi-
nesses, with cash coming in equal to cash going out. Governments are in the
business of making sure that the total expenditures of societ match total out-
put. Fiscal restraint, attained by making sure that cash coming in meets cash
going out (ignoring for the moment complications arising from international
resource flows), is one way of making that more likely to happen, but it is
neither necessary nor sufficient. The magnitude of the monetary-credit stimulus
must also be taken into account.
If loan markets were nothing but auction markets, the interest rate would
equate the demand for new funds (loans) with the supply. But credit markets are
not auction markets. Rather, banking regulations give banks the right, in effect,
to issue money-that is, daims on goods. The bank issues these daims on the
42                                       The Role of the State in Financial Markets



basis of its judgments concerning who is creditworthy. Individual banks do not
ask whether the sum total of these claims is consistent with macroeconomic
equilibrium. And because the interest rate is being used for purposes other than
market clearing-it affccts both the mix of borrowers and the actions they
take-the price system may not ensure macroeconomic equilibrium either.
Ensuring such equilibrium becomes the task of the central bank (see Stiglitz and
Weiss 1990).
If, through one mechanism or another, governments manage to suppress
consumption, resources are made available for investment. For instance, credit
can be supplied at low interest rates, or investments can be subsidized. The
difficult part is not raising taxes but suppressing consumption.
PUBLIC FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS IN EAST ASIA. This brings me to the second
reason that some governments, at least in East Asia, undertook extensive gov-
ernment lending programs: they were able to reduce consumption, in part by
providing safe and convenient vehicles for savings (for example, Japan's postal
savings system). The government thus had a cash flow to be allocated. Again, to
a large extent, governments were misled by the analogy with the business
sector-although here the error was perhaps smaller than that discussed above.
Thinking as a business would, the government assumed that it had to invest
these funds well. Since it had, in effect, borrowed the funds from consumers, it
had to be sure to earn a return on the funds to repay the amount promised. In
fact, though, government is different from business. The government could use
the funds and subsequently "capture" the amount required to repay depositors
through taxation (an option not open to private firms). The funds flowing into
the postal savings banks provided an indicator of the resources available for
investment, but the government could have stimulated that amount of invest-
ment in other ways; it did not have to get the returns directly through loan
repayments.
THE EFFECTIVENESS OF DIRECTED CREDIT. In any country the relationship be-
tween the magnitude of the subsidy provided and the level of investment that
firms undertake is uncertain. The price system appears to be a highly unreliable
control mechanism when economies are in a recession. And it is equally likely to
be unreliable in developing countries, where conditions are constantly changing.
Thus, controlling the quantity of credit is a surer way of providing for macro-
economic stability than controlling the price (interest rate) and is even more
effective than controlling the price through subsidies. (In the latter case two
sources of uncertainty are introduced: the relationship between the magnitude of
the subsidy and the price that borrowers will have to pay, and the relationship
between the price that borrowers have to pay and the amount of credit that will
be issued; see Weitzman 1970.)
ECONOMIES OF SCOPE. Given that banks must carefully scrutinize loan applica-
tions in any case, it may not be that difficult to screen for a broader set of
stiglitz                                                         43



objectives. Will the project yield highi social returns, and are there positive
linkages with other sectors? Sectors of the economy that satisfy these criteria
(provided that the differcnce between the private and social returns is large
enough to merit intervention) may be targeted with directed credit. Once thesc
sectors have been identified, therc should be little incremental cost associated
with a bank's including thcsc criterin in its selection mechanism.
The Targets of Directed Credit
Although much of the popular criticism of directed credit programs focuses on
the difficulty of picking winners, most of the successful economics of East Asia
chosc broadly based objectives, traditionally focusing on cxport promotion and,
more recently, on tcchnology. (Besides directing credit toward these areas, credit
was directed away from other arcas, such as real estate and consumer durables.)
TECHNOLOGY. The reasons for the emphasis on technology are easy to see;
there are standard "public goods" arguments that the nature of knowledge
results in marked discrepancies between social and private returns (see Stiglitz
1987b). Firms may be unable to capture the social returns generated by their
innovations because of competitive imitation. As a result, the economy is likely
to underinvest in the development of new technologies. Directing credit toward
technology-intensive industries can be an effective tool for promoting
innovation.
EXPORT-ORIENTED CREDIT. Why these countries focused on export orienta-
tion-and why such a focus should have been so successful in promoting eco-
nomic growth-may seem more problematic; after all, standard economic theory
says that countries should promote their comparative advantage. In some cases,
this should entail producing import substitutes, in some cases, exports, and in
some cases, nontradables. In the process of growth, to be sure, comparative
advantages would change; in any case, comparative advantage should not be
defined only in relation to current resources and competencies. One has to focus
on dynamic comparative advantage. As an economy grows, the mix of products it
produces may well change, but there seems no a priori reason (at this level of
generality) why this mix should consist primarily of goods that are exported
rather than substitutes for goods that are currently imported. Why the seeming
bias toward exports? And why has this bias been so successful?
There are several possibilities. The standard analysis focuses on a shortage of
foreign exchange. By increasing exports, the shortage is relieved. For instance,
in the post-World War II era the government of Japan overvalued the yen and so
faced a shortage of foreign exchange. (If the foreign exchange rate had been set
at an equilibrium level, the scarcity of foreign exchange would have been no
different from the scarcity of any other resource.)
But there is a more fundamental reason: exports provided a rational criterion
for allocating credit. Government has only limited information concerning
44                                        The Role of the State in Financial Markets



which firms are performing well. This problem is particularly severe in the
context of development because relatively few firms may be engaged in similar
activities, and officials have only limited bases for comparison. A related prob-
lem is that in the early stages of development short-run profits provide an
imperfect indicator of long-run performance. The profits that accrue as a result
of imperfect competition in the domestic market accrue at least partially at the
expense of consumers. By contrast, if a firm succeeds in the export market, it is
more likely that it is able to provide a product at a lower price than its foreign
rivals or a product that appeals to the world market. It is more likely that export
markets are competitive. And even if they are not, it is of no concern to the
country; the profits of the firm then come at the expense of foreign consumers,
about which governments of developing countries are much less concerned.
Accordingly, from a social perspective, success in exporting may be a better
indicator of whether a firm merits additional funds than success in domestic
markets. Banks, however, typically prefer domestic to foreign lending, and for a
simple reason: to the bank, whether a firr's returns are social or private is
irrelevant; the bank just wants to be sure that there will be returns, and more
risk is associated with lending for export projects. Consequently, banks will
underutilize the informnational content of successful exports.
Thus export-oriented policies u-re desirable because they provided a good
measure of performance-a better measure than profits-and there were, in
addition, technological spillovers. Government intervention was required
because of the difference between private and social (risk-adjusted) returns to
lending for exports.
Competition Policy
Competition policy poses a difficult quandary. Ideologues of the right, as well as
certain special interest groups within the financial community, have an easy pre-
sciption: because markets are naturally competitive, all the government has to do
is to remove the barriers that it has placed in the way of the competitive process.
To be sure, financial sector regulations in effect reduce competition (although
the reduction is often an unintended side effect of regulations imposed to ensure
financial solvency or prevent abuse by financial intermediaries). Competition
policy represents a balance between conflicting concerns. Alternative views of
competition policy are based on differences not only in the weights associated
with these concerns but also in judgments about how well the banking sector
functions in the absence of government intervention.
Advantages and Disadvantages of Competition
There is a consensus that competition is important in promoting efficiency. Not
only doea competition lead to lower costs, but it also provides incentives for
Sfglitz                                                            45



firms to discovcr unserved niches in the market. The returns that can be
obtained reflect the values that consumers place on these services.
These arguments are standard for any industry. In credit markets an additional
argument is that competition affects credit availability-not so much the total
amount of credit (which may be more related to macroeconomic considerations)
as the pattern of allocation. The larger the number of banks, the greater the
likelihood that there may be more than one bank willing to lend. This is impor-
tant. When there is only one bank, the borrower may not be able to obtain funds,
and this poses an impediment to the entry of firms into a market. For this reason,
lack of competition in the banking sector has a deleterious effect on the producing
sector that goes beyond the higher interest rates its monopoly position confers.
But competition is a two-edged sword. Lack of competition leads to higher
interest rates (one of the standard concerns with limited competition), but it also
leads to higher profits. And higher profits increase the strength of financial
institutions and reduce the risk of insolvency.
The United States may have had the most competitive banking sector in in-
dustrial countries. It is not surprising that it has, as a result, been a source of
innovation. The incidence of bank insolvencies, however, has been higher than in
many other countries. This may be partly a consequence of improper regulation,
but it is also a reflection of the high levels of competition that have reduced the
spread between deposit and lending interest rates and cut into profit margins.
In most sectors of the economy insolvencies resulting from excessive competi-
tion are not viewed as a problem. If too many firms enter an industry, prices
drop, profits decline, and the weakest firmis leave. Some of the capital is trans-
ferred to other sectors. Other, sunk, capital is "lost," but the loss is borne by the
investors.
In the banking sector, however, there are further ramifications. As profits
decline, the net worth of all banks is eroded, with adverse effects on depositors
and borrowers. If net worth is reduced only slightly, banks will lend less, and
borrowers will suffer. With laiger reductions in net worth, some banks take on
more risk, and the savings and loan syndrome sets in. Depositors (or the agency
that insures deposits) bear the cost. In either case, the ran:ifications of excessive
entry are borne not by the investors but by others.
If banks could instantly raise new equity capital to offset the erosion of equity
resulting from excessive entry, the damage done to the surviving banks would be
easily undone, and the market would not suffer. (To be sure, the original inves-
tors in the surviving banks, as well as in the banks that had to leave the market,
would suffer.) But, in fact, banks cannot raise new capital so easily. A depletion
of equity cannot be easily undone. And even if aggregate equity were to remain
unchanged-with the reduced equicy of incumbenit financial institutions being
offset by the new equity of entrants-particular borrowers, cttached to the
disadvantaged financial institutions, would suffer.
Moreover, profits in financial institutions may arise not only from providing
needed services more efficiently but also from exploiting market imperfections
46                                         The Role of the State in Financial Markets



more effectively. Financial institutions seem perfectly willing to offer essentially
identical accounts that pay markedly different interest rates, hoping (real-
istically) that at least some uninformed customers will accept a lower-than-
competitive interest rate.
Limitations on Competition
Many or the curbs on competition are by-products of other objectives. The gains
from the purported achievement of these other objectives have to be weighed
against the possible costs (and benefits) of restricted competition. Three exam-
ples will illustrate the point.
FIDUCIARY RESPONSIBILITY. It is clear that financial institutions are entrusted
with the care of other people's money and should not use the funds for the
benefit of, say, the officers of the institution. If information were costless,
investors could withdraw their funds from any institution that engaged in such
practices. But information is imperfect, and there is evidence that even when
informed of an impending collapse, many depositors-including those who are
only partially insured-do not withdraw their funds. Markets provide, at best,
limited discipline.
The next line of defense is regulation. Regulations prohibit untoward behav-
ior, but regulators can only imperfectly monitor the actions of banks. As a
result, they must rely on indirect control mechanisms. They can make sure that
there are no conflicts of interest that would tempt banks. This perspective
explains many of the observed restrictions on banks and owners. The tempta-
tion, even in good faith, to make favorable judgments concerning insiders' cred-
itworthiness is overwhelming.
Most countries impose restrictions on who can own a bank. These are partly
concemed with the character of the owner-the owner should not be a person
who has a record of abusing trust. But they are also concerned with incentives;
there are advantages to restricting ownership to those who have less incentive to
abuse the fiduciary relationship.
One of the principal justifications of the Glass-Steagall Act in the United
States, which establishes a division between investment banks and commercial
banks, is that it lessens the likelihood of abuse of the fiduciary relationship. An
investment bank which ..as recommended to its customers that they buy the
shares or bonds of a particular company may be tempted to shore up that
company with loans (which other banks either would not make or wouldl offer
only at a far higher risk premium) if, a short while down the road, it runs into
financial difficulties.
It is easier to impose restrictions on the categories of activities in which
different financial institutions can engage than to monitor individual actions
undertaken by each institution. As always, there are tradeoffs. The reduced
likelihood of malfeasance incurs a cost, often of reduced competition. How
siglitz                                                            47



significant the cost is depends on the particular regulation. For instance, it is
argued that the barriers between investment and commercial banks restrict com-
petition and interfere with economic efficiency. Here, the principal question
concerns the magnitude of the economies of scope. If they are significant, then
forcing these different economic activities into different organizations interferes
with the ability to take advantage of economies of scope. There are probably
some economies of scope. The question is, how significant are they? Indeed, the
economies of scope that are observed may be closely linked with the possible
abuses that arise when the barriers are eliminated.
REGIONAL RESTRICTIONS. The United States has imposed strong restrictions on
interstate banking. Perhaps the political force was provided by the concern that
small loca' banks would be driven out by large national banks-a typical exam-
ple in which a class of firms that cannot survive in the competition of the
marketplace turns to government for protection.
Yet there may be a grain of truth in some of the arguments (besides rent
protection) in favor of restrictions. One argument is that they may make actual
competition more effective-with these restrictions, many local banks might
stay in business; without them, only one large bank might survive.
Another concern is that, without restrictions, there will be a diversion of
funds toward the larger centers. Local information is important in lending activ-
ity but not in deposit activity. Large banks may tend to garner funds from a wide
range of sources but to concentrate the allocation of funds in the areas about
which they have more information and where they can monitor borrower activ-
ity at lower cost-usually, large metropolitan centers. From both an economic
and social perspective, such concentration of lending activity-and thus of eco-
nomic activity more generally-may not be desirable (see Greenwald, Levinson,
and Stiglitz 1993).
Again, there are tradeoffs: geographic restrictions on banking have, as we
have noted, ambiguous effects on competition, but they do limit the extent of
portfolio diversification of banks, thus amplifying the effects of local shocks on
len.ing activity and increasing the solvency risk of banks.
At least some of the obiectives may be accomplished as (or more) effectively at
less cost in other ways. For instance, the concern about diversion of funds
toward the money centers may be addressed by tying lending activity to the
locations of deposits (although such constraints raise the possibility that funds
will not be allocated in a way that maximizes-at least, private-returns.)
COMPETITION FROM FOREIGN BANKS. Competition from foreign banks is a third
realm in which government policies designed at least in part for purposes other
than reducing competition may nonetheless have had that effect. These policies
have been the subject of extensive controversy. Industrial countries have put
considerable pressure on developing economies to open up their financial mar-
kets to foreign competition. Those who repeat the mantra that markets work
48                                       The Role of the State in Financial Markers



well in the absence of government intervention see no reason why the govern-
ment should impede competition in the market in this way. I contend that there
aie at least three good arguments for these restrictions. The first is a variant of
the infant industry argument (see Dasgupta and Stiglitz 1988). Because there is
considerable "learning by doing" in the financial sector, protection may be even
more important in this industry than in others. Depositors may feel greater
confidence in the security provided by a large international bank, thus putting a
small, new domestic bank at a marked disadvantagc.
Free trade arguments suggest that one remedy is for the domestic bank to
lower interest rates and increase its loans to strengthen its learning. This requires
attracting additional funds from depositors. But depositors may be relatively
price-insensitive; the additional safety of the larger international bank implies
that the domestic bank would have to pay substantially higher interest rates to
attract funds. In some cases government guarantees may offset this advantage.
Certainly Japan was able to gather deposits through its postal savings system
while paying relatively low interest rates, presumably because depositors had a
great deal of confidence in these accounts. But in other countries investors may
actually have more confidence in a foreign bank. At the deposit interest rates
domestic banks would have to pay to be competitive, they would lose substan-
tial amounts of money, and imperfections in capital markets mean that without
govemment subsidies, the institutions may not be able to finance this deficit.
Because the governments of developing countries do not have the funds for
subsidies (or, more formally, the shadow price on government funds is
extremely high), protection is more desirable.
A second reason that protection may be more important in this industry than
in others is the discrepancies between social and private returns to lending.
Those discrepancies may be different, and larger, for lending by foreign banks.
Foreign banks may be at arn informational disadvantage in relation to domestic
banks, and this may bring about a different pattern of investment. Foreign
banks may, for instance, be relatively better informed concerning multinational
firms and may direct funds to the local subsidiaries of these firms, thereby
reducing the flow of funds to local entrepreneurs.
A third reason is that international banks may be less sensitive than local
banks to 'window guidance" and other indirect pressures. In several countries,
local bank officials have complained that they did not mind foreign banks'
entering their market if they entered on a level playing field and, in particular, if
they entered subject to the same rules, explicit and implicit, that face domestic
banks. But, in fact, foreign banks are less vulnerable than domestic banks. The
maximum punishment that the government can normally mete out is to dose the
bank. For a large international bank, that may be a relatively small punishment;
for a domestic bank, it is the economic equivalent of death. Thus national banks
will inevitably be more sensitive to the wishes of the government. Moreover,
there is likely to be a stronger sense of social cohesion between domestic banks
and the government.
sigltz                                                             49



Here, too, there are tradeoffs: the presence of foreign banks may decrease the
governmcnt's control of the economy. Different countries, in different situa-
tions, will inevitably balance these considerations differently.
Imperfect Competition in the Banking Sector
This paper suggests that the banking sector is not well described by the model of
perfect competition with well-informed buyers. Those countries that have not
actively promoted competition have relatively few banks. The reasons for this
are not entirely well understood. There appear to be some economies of scale
and of scope, but not enough to justify the extremely small number of firms in
many economies. In the United States there is evidence that many small banks
can be highly profitable, exploiting their greater knowledge of local markets and
avoiding the diseconomies of scale arising from managerial problems. (Large
banks, may, however, realize economies of scale arising from advertising and
name recognition, quite distinct from the economies arising from the more
central functions of financial institutions.)
This view contrasts markedly with the view popularized in the last decade
under the rubric of the contestability doctrine, which holds that what is relevant
is not the actual level of competition but the presence of potential competition.
Even if there is only one firm in the market, it cannot exercise market power, lest
entrants come into the market. It is daimed that entry barriers are small for
banks and that, accordingly, the contestability doctrine applies. Neither evi-
dence nor theory has been kind to the contestability doctrine, as popular as it
has been with naive advocates of market liberalization. Theory has shown that
even small sunk costs can result in very large barriers to entry, negating the
implications of the contestability doctrine (Stiglitz 1987c). Although many sec-
tors of the economy (induding the banking sector) are too complex to provide a
dlean test of the contestability doctrine, the U.S. airline industry has provided
convincing evidence against it. Thus if governments wish to have a compettive
banking sector, they may have to take deliberate actions to promote competi-
tion, sometimes compromising other objectives of banking policies.
Condusion
There is a role for the state in financial markets; it is a role motivated by
pervasive market failures. In most of the rapidly growing economies of East Asia
government has taken an active role in creating financial institutions, in regulat-
ing them, and in directing credit, both in ways that enhance the stability of the
economy and the solvency of the financial institutions and in ways that enhance
growth prospects. Although limitations on markets are greater in developing
countries, so too, many would argue, are limitations on government. It is impor-
tant to design government policies that are attentive to those limitations.
50                                       The Role of the State in Financial Markets



The extent to which the success of the rapidly growing economies of East Asia
is attributable to extensive government intervention in financial markets, the
relative importance of particular interventions, and whether other countries can
successfully imitate these interventions remain questions for research and
debate. What is clear is that a simple ideological commitment to liberalization of
financial markets cannot be derived either from economic theory or from an
examination of a broad base of experience and cannot provide the basis for an
intelligent discussion of an absolutely central set of policy issues that face devel-
oping countries today.
Notes
1. An important caveat is that changes in governmcnt mean that those who bear the costs of misguided
government policies are often not those who perpetrated the mistakes.
2. The term "constrained" is added simply as a reminder that the costs of information or of establishing
markets have been taken into account.
3. To put the matter formally, assume that the government wishes to make sure (with probability 0.95)
that a variablex is greater than some threshold lcvd x*. It does not obseme x direcdy; rather, it observes y. a
noisy measurementof x (y = x + e). It then sets a standard for y. y such that if y > y*, the probability that
x exceeds x is 0.9S. The greater the noise (the geater the variance of e), the higher will y be.
References
Akerlof, G. A. 1970. -The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3): 488-500.
Aoki, Masahiko. 1992. 'Ex-post Monitoring of the Main Bank." Stanford University, Departncrt of
Economics, Stanford, Calif.
Arnott, Richard J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1986. "Moral Hazard and Optimal Commodity Taxation."
Journal of Public Economics 29 (February): 1-24.
- 1991. "Moral Hazard and Nonmarket Institutions: Dysfunctional Crowding Out or Pee
Monitoring?" American Economic Reirew 81(1): 179-90.
Berle, Adolf A. 1926. 'Nonvoting Stock and Bankers' Control." Harvard Law Review 39 (6): 673-93.
Dasgupta, Partha, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1988. 'Learning by Doing, Market Structure, and Industrial
and Trade Policies." Oxford Economic Papers 40: 246-68.
DeLong, J. Bradford, and Lawrence H. Summers. 1990. "Equipment, Investment, Relative Prices, and
Economic Growdh." Paper presented at NBER Conference on Economic Growth in Vail, Colo., April
12-14.
Fama, Eugene F. 1980. "Banking in the Theory of Finance"Jornalof Monetary Economics 6: 38-58.
Greenwald, Bruce C. 1986. "Adverse Selecton in the Labour Market." Review of Economic Studies
53(3): 325-47.
Greenwald, Bruce C., and Joseph E. Stigli. 1986. "Externalities in Economies with Imperfect
Information and Incompiete Markets." QuarterlyJournal of Economics 101 (May): 229-64.
-     . 1992a. 'Imperfect Information and Macroeconomic Analysis." Presented at NBR Annual
Conference on Macreconomics, Cambridge, Mass., March.
. 1992b. "Information, Finance, and Markets: The Architecure of Allocaive Mechanisms."
Journal of Industrial and Corporate Change 1(1).
-l         1992c. "Towards a Reformulation of Monetary Theory: Competitive Banking." NBER Working
Paper 4117. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
stiglitz                                                                            51



Greenwald, Bruce C., Alfred Levinson, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1993. "Capital Market Imperfections and
Regional Economic Developmcnt." In Alberto Giovannini, Finance and Development: Issues and
Experience. Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press.
Greenwald, Bruce C., Joscph E. Stiglitz, and Andrew Weiss. 1984. "Infonnational Imperfections in the
Capitial Markets and Macro-eonomic Fluctuations." American Economic Review 74(1): 194-99.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1976. "Information and Competitive Price Systems."
American Economtc Review 66(2) 246-53.
-. 1980. 'On the Impossibility of InfarMationally Efficient Markets." American Economic Review
70(3): 393-408.
Hoff, Karla, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1993. "A Theory of Rural Credit Markets with Costly Enforcement."
Paper presented to Econometric Society meeting in Anaheim, Calif., Stanford University, January, 1993.
Jaffee, Dwight, andJoseph E. Stiglitz. 1990. "Credit Rationing." In Benjamin M. Friedman and Frank H.
Hahn, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. 1974. "Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases."
Science I1S: 1124-31.
Murdock, Kevin, and Joseph E. Sdiglitz. 1993. "The Effect of Financial Repression in an Economy with
Positive Real Interest Rates: Theory and Evidence." Stanford University, Stanford, Calif.
Rey, Patrick, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1992. "Short-Term Contracts as a Monitoring Device.' Stanford
University, Stanford, Calif.
Schwarz, Anita. 1992. "Hoow Effective Are Directed Credit Programs in the United States?" FSD Working
Paper. World Bank.
Stiglin, Joseph E. 1975a. "Incentives, Risk and Information: Notes Towards a Theory of Hierarchy."
Belljournal of Economics 6(2): S52-79.
- . 1975b. 'Information and Economic Analysis." In Michael Parkin and A. R. Nobay, eds.,
Current Economic Problems. Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press.
1 1975c. "The Theory of Screening, Education and the Distribution of Income." American
Economic Review 65(3): 283-300.
- . 1982. 'Information and Capital Markets." In William F. Sharpe and Carolyn M. Cootner, eds.,
Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Paul Cootner. Englewood Cliffs, NJ.: Prentice Hall.
-. 1985. "Credit Markets and the Control of Capital." Journal of Money, Banking and Credit,
17(1): 133-52.
-     . 1987a. "The New Kqencsian Economics: Money and Credit..' Fisher-Schultz Leure, presented
at the meetings of the Econometric Soiety, Copenhagen, August.
. 1987b. "On the Microcconomics of Technical Progress." In Jorgc M. Katz, ed. Technology
Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries. New York: Macmillan.
-.  1987c. "Technological Change, Sunk Costs, and Competition." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 3: 883-947.
* 1988. "Why Fmancial Structure Matters."Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(4): 121-26.
. 1990. "Peer Monitoring and Credit Markets." World Bank Economic Review, 4(3): 351-66.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Andrew Weiss. 1981. "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfea Information."
American Economic Review 71(3): 393-410.
. 1983. "Incentive Effects of Termination: Applications to the Credit and Labor Markes."
American Economic Review 73(5): 912-27.
-.  1990. 'Banks as Social Accountants and Screening Dcvices and the General Theory of Credit
Rationing." Greek Economic Review 12: 85-118. Forthcoming in Anthony Courakis and Charles
Goodhart, eds., Essays in Monetary Economics in Honor of Sir John Hicks. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford
University Press.
Summers, Lawrence H. and Victoria P. Summers. 1989. "When Financial Markets Work Too Well: A
Cautious Case for a Securitics Transaction Tax." In Regulatory Reform of Stock and Futures Markets:
A Special Issue of the Journal of Financial Services Research. Boston, Mass.: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Weitzman, Martin. 1970. "Prices versus Quantities." Review of Economic Studies 41(October): 477-91.
52                                                  The Role of the State in Financial Markets



COMMENT ON 'THE ROLE OF THE STATE IN FINANCIAL
MARKETS," BY STIGLITZ
Jaime Jaramillo- Vallejo
J find it amusing that we begin by assuming that we have a can opener while
being stranded on a lonely island with nothing more to eat than canned
food. In his paper Stiglitz is asking us to assume that governments all over
the world-especially in developing countries-are wise, fair, and efficient
enough to carry out the kind of "perfect" intrusive intervention suggested by
him. It is as if the world of the second best had just been discovered and we had
not learned from the experience with the different forms of government inter-
vention that we have seen in this century.
On a more fundamental level, I agree that there is a need for intervention in
financial markets through prudential regulation and adequate supervision. But I
find it difficult to agree with the kind of intrusive intervention suggested by
Stiglitz, or with his reasoning for it, or with the allocation of scarce governmen-
tal resources that such intervention would entail. Moreover, while I appreciate
Stiglitz's contributions regarding information theory and market imperfections,
I do not see a dear connection between most of the specific interventions sug-
gested in the paper and the imperfections which he highlights-that is, there is a
non sequitur in this regard within the paper. Furthernore, these policy sugges-
tions do not differ in any way from what used to be the gospel of agencies such
as the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America under Raul
Prebisch in the 1950s, 1960s, 1970s, and early 1980s-a gospel that was pains-
takingly implemented without success in Latin America during several decades.
Regardless of whether or not there are market failures, the states role in
financial markets is necessary because of the "fiat" nature of monetary and
financial instruments. Today's financial economy is nothing more than a "great
big fantasy," where promises made by people, firms, or even computers are
Jaime Jaramillo-Vallejo is senior adviser to the chief, National Department of Planning, Colombia, and
former deputy division chief, Policy Development and Review Departnent, International Monetary
Fund. He would like to thank Felicia M. Knual for helpful comments.
Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993
� 1994 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development J THE WORLD BANK  53



taken so seriously that they are regarded as wealth. This fantasy eases economic
transactions and enhances efficiency only to the extent that the instruments used
in it are trusted by economic agents, and the entire system ceases to function
when faith in these instruments collapses. Monetary and financial instruments
are assets simply because they are somebody else's debt, and, given that there are
incentives to elude keeping up with financial promises, intervention is required
to ensure that the financial and monetary fantasy lives on and continues to grow
(see McKinnon 1973; Shaw 1973; World Bank 1989). This paradigm suggests a
kind of state intervention that is more directed toward leveling the playing field
and nursing and shepherding the development of the fantasy, which is in marked
contrast with most of the intrusive interventions suggested by Stiglitz.
From another viewpoint, the real world is far from the black-and-white picture
of "perfect" competition, "perfect" government intervention, and market "fail-
ures." And in a world of gray tones with monopolistic competition, ordinary
governments, budgetary and human constraints, and some market imperfections,
we are better off relying on competition and private microeconomic decisions
within certain prudential guidelines, steering clear of financial repression.
just as "perfect" competition does not exist and market "failures" are always
present, experience suggests that relying heavily on the wisdom and goodness of
government in microeconomic decisions is a major mistake-witness Africa,
Eastern Europe, Latin America, and South Asia. The failure of governments to
exercise discretion is perhaps more prevalent and damaging in developing coun-
tries than the so-called market failures and imperfections themselves. As a mat-
ter of fact, government failure has been present in all of the financial crises of
recent decades, either because regulations were faulty or because supervision
was poor. In Colombia the financial crisis of the early 1980s came at a time
when the authorities were actively pursuing the kinds of policy suggested by
Stiglitz in his paper. They were so involved with those policies that they failed to
stop the conflicts of interest that brought about the crisis (see Montenegro
Trujillo 1983 and Caballero ArgAez 1987). Furthermore, as Lawrence Summers
indicated in his keynote address at the 1991 meeting of this conference (Sum-
mers 1992), the kind of intervention that so lures Stiglitz has already been tried
extensively. It has been mildly successful in East Asia but nowhere else; rather, it
has led everywhere to a burst of corruption and other undesirable effects.'
Remedying the ill effects has not been easy.
On the specific policy advice offered by Stiglitz, I found it surprising that a
recommendation for financial repression would ignore completely a number of
issues that experience suggests as very relevant. Let me mention a few.
Although aggregate savings may not be sensitive to interest rates, can we say
the same thing about disintermediation and financial savings? How does
one transform savings in the form of minor physical assets-such as
chickens or hogs in developing countries and full cupboards in Eastern
Europe-into physical productive capital?
54                                                             Comment



.
*What is the impact on investment and growth of high spreads between
lending and deposit interest rates-spreads that reach 70 percentage points
in Slovenia and 90 in Peru? Within this context, should Stiglitz not supply us
with the data to back his statement that there is empirical evidence that
financial repression has a positive impact on growth? Recent empirical work
by King and Levine (1993) would indicate quite the contrary.
* What prevents banks from distributing profits stemming from wide spreads
instead of capitalizing them as Stiglitz hopes would happen? Would capital-
ization not require, in any case, strict ruler on capital adequacy and their
rigorous enforcement? Why, then, is a wide spread needed?
* What are the efficiency gains of using implicit taxes and subsidies through
the financial sector instead of using explicit and transparent ones? In what
way are the distributive effects of an indirect system preferable? Moreover,
do these effects not bias income and wealth distribution? Is the use of
implicit taxes and subsidies neutral from a political viewpoint?
* Why would credit rationing and allocation stemming from financial repres-
sion yield better results than the kind of credit rationing that Stiglitz sees as a
market failure? Does experience not suggest quite the opposite as a result of
the favoritism and corruption that is bred by repression?
* Within the credit allocation system suggested by Stiglitz, would it not pay
firms to use bank credit more intensively than their own capital? Why
would this outcome be desirable? Is this not what happened in France?z
Was not this one of the key factors that killed the budding capital markets of
Latin America in the 1950s and 1960s? The importance of these markets
may be overstated on average terms, but not on marginal terms.
Moreover, there is a political dimension underlying all this discussion in
developing countries. When we pushed through the financial and exchange
liberalization in Colombia, we did so because we believed that the basic eco-
nomic human rights of a large segment of the population-particularly the low-
and middle-income groups-were being "overlooked" to the extent that there
was favoritism in the intervention in these markets. Furthermore, my own coun-
try may be a good example of how intrusive state invention in the economy can
eventually be used to effectively curtail true democracy by managing the benefits
of the intervention. Can we as economists and public servants ignore blatantly
the imnpact of our policy prescriptions on basic economic human rights and the
development of democracy? I, as a public servant of a developing country,
would be very concerned if the officials from the U.S. administration were to
start peddling economic policies that were to hamper democracy.
Despite Stiglitz's contribution, I feel that much remains to be done in terms of
working through the real relevance of the market failures highlighted by him and
the actual intervention needed to deal with them. In the meantime we must
emphasize intervention through prudential regulations and supervision to keep
the monetary fantasy alive and growing, using regulations that factor in the
Jaramillo-Vallejo                                                55



limitations facing the authorities and the country, focusing on controls that can
be enforced casily and precisely, and creating incentives so that financial institu-
tions and other private agents act prudently. And, from this viewpoint, I feel
that most of Stiglitz's policy prescriptions do not fulfill these requirements.
To sum up, I wonder whether the following quote from Stiglitz's own paper
could not be applied squarcly to his paper and his policy advice:
[It] . . . is based neither on a sound economic understanding of how
[financial] markets work nor on the potential scope for government
interventions. Often, too, it lacks an understanding of the historical
events and political forces that have led governments to assume their
present role. Instead, it is based on an ideological conception of mar-
kets that is grounded neither in fact nor in economic theory. (Stiglitz,
in this volume)
Note
1. Conventional wisdom would suggest that the key reasons for the mild success of intcrvention in East
Asia are the authoritarian character of their political regimes and the cultural habit of obedience (see
World Bank 1993). By the same token, one should expect corruption to be morc noticeable in those
countrics with a free press and with a cultural tendency to question the leadership.
2. See Stiglitz, in this volumc.
References
Caballero Arg4cz, Carlos. 1987. SO Ainos de Economia-De la Crisis del 30 a la del 80.' Asociaci6n
Bancaria de Colombia, BogotA.
King, Robert, and Ross Levine. 1993. "Finance, Entrepreneurship, and Growth." World Bank
Conference on National Policies and Long-Term Growth, Washington, D.C., February.
McKinnon, Ronald 1. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, D.C.:
Brookings Institution.
Montenegro Trujillo, Armnando. 1983. 'La Crisis del Sector FinanSero Colombiano." Ensayos de
Politica Econ6mica-Banco de la Republica (December): 51-88.
Shaw, Edward S. 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Summers. Lawrence H. 1992. 'Knowledge for Effective Action." Proceedings of the World Bank Annual
Conference on Development Economics 7-14.
World Bank. 1989. World Development Rep ort 1989. New York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank. 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New York: Oxford
University Press.
56                                                                               Comment



.
COMMENT ON "THE ROLE OF THE STATE IN FINANCIAL
MARKETS," BY STIGLITZ
Yung Cbul Park
M        any policymakers in Korea, as well as those who have long been
uncomfortable with liberal financial doctrine, will be relieved by Pro-
fessor Stiglitz's support for repressive financial policies. Almost every
financial activity in Korea, including access to the banking sector, the deter-
mination of interest rates, and the allocation of credit, has been heavily regu-
lated by the government. Financial experts and international organizations have
argued that unless Korea's financial markets were substantially deregulated and
opened to competition, the economy would crumble under the accumulated
inefficiencies of the financial sector. Korea's economic performance for at least
the past two decades, however, suggests that this argument is suspect, although
it is possible that economic growth could have been higher under a more deregu-
lated financial regime.
I agree with most of the points made in the paper, but drawing on my experi-
ence in designing financial policies, I would like to touch on several issues that
are not discussed.
First, the structure of competition in the banking sector is largely influenced
and often shaped by the structure of its nonfinancial sectors. An economy whose
manufacturing sector is dominated by a few large conglomerates or industrial
groups is a case in point. It is particularly important for each of these groups to
establish a long-term relationship with a bank and to rely on its bank for long-
term credit at the nascent stage of its financial development. In such an economy
it is not difficult to imagine that the banking sector will be dominated by a few
large banks that could collectively meet the financial needs of the industrial
groups. Furthermore, in the absence of government intervention, these large
banks are quite likely to be owned and controlled by the industrial groups.
Other factors also inhibit competition and invite government control over finan-
Yung Chul Park is professor of economics at Korea University and president of the Korea Institute of
Fmance.
Pmrceedings of the Wbr/d Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993
� 1994 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development J THE WORLD BANK  57



cinl markets. For instance in many developing countries, trade, labor, and agri-
culture are all heLivily regulated nnd protected. A competitive financial regime
may not be compatible with controlled sectors and may not even be possibic.
My second point is related to the consequences of maiintaining low intercst
rntes, which, according to Stiglitz, promotcs econiomic growth whilc increasing
profits. In ninny countries, including Japan and Korea, banks that are subject to
regulated lending rates below the equilibrium rate charge a compensating bal-
ance ns a conditioni of the loan. As a result, the difference between the regulated
ratc ind the equilibrium ratw has been borne in part by the borrowers. If the use
of compensating balances is as prevalent as it is in Korea, it will bc difficult to
assess the extent to which borrowers benefit from the low interest rates.
The third point is rclated to the effectiveness of indirect control mechanisms in
the form of incentives and rcstrictions. Onc difficulty with prefercntial regula-
tion is that it may not lessen the moral hlazard problem. The public anticipates
that it is the government's responsibility to keep the financial system safe and
individual banks sound and therefore believes that the government would not let
a bank, particularly a large one, fail. Worse yet, the exercise of indirect control
by the government is often perceived as ensuring the health of the financial
industry. Given thcse perceptions, it is unlikely that the net worth requirement
and deposit insurance system that adjust premiums on the basis of the quality of
each bank's portfolio could make banks more prudent in their lending activities.
Another issue is how to phase out a direct control system and replace it with an
indirect one. Unless a new system is installed overnight, which is highly unlikely,
the government will drag its feet in changing the system and will vacillate
between a greater or a lesser degree of governmental control.
The last point is a rather casual explanation of why Korea's repressive finan-
cial system did not undermine its growth potential to the extent claimed in the
literature. In my view the economy was able to avoid much of the inefficiency
problem because export performance was the main criterion for bank loans.
Firms that compete and succeed internationally are likely to be more efficient
than those that operate in regulated and sheltered domestic markets, and most
of the loanable funds were in fact allocated to these firms.
58                                                                Comment



.
FLOUR DISCUSSION OF THE STIGLITZ PAPER
A       participant from the Brookings Institution asked Yung Chul Park (dis-
cussant) to speculate on what Korea's economy might have looked like
J?    today had the policy of financial repression not been followed during
the past twenty to thirty years. Would the growth rate for that period have been
lower without the policy? If so, why? Would the economy have been less export-
oriented? Would there have been, for example, more investment in housing?
Park said his sense was that financial policics would not have made much
difference so long as the manufacturing and service sectors were efficient. He
thought that the efficiency of Korea's trade and industrial policies was far more
important than its financial policies.
Stiglitz, however, said that he believed the Korean government's intervention
in the financial market had boosted economic growth. The government had not
allowed a great number of real estate loans, for example. Had more capital gone
into real estate and less into manufacturing, there might have been significantly
less growth. One could well ask whether using the allocation of financial
resources to promote exports is the best approach, said Stiglitz, but it was
certainly effective in Korea, and not many countries have used other instruments
as effectively.
A participant from Harvard noted that Sriglitz had mentioned in passing the
possibility of government failures but that most of his research and discussion
focused on market failures. Advocates of privatization would not be surprised to
learn that private markets were imperfect, but government intervention is gener-
ally believed to be even worse because of either corruption or inappropriate
objectives and interventions. The participant wondered whether Stiglitz should
devote more of his considerable prowess to theorizing about what governments
actually do, what objectives they actuallv ' ther, and what kind of corruption
emerges and compare that reality with the optimal poUicy designs he discusses.
Another participant observed that in Latin America, which has a far more liberal
This session was chaired by Jessica P. Einhom, vice-president and treasurer, the World Bank.
Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993
� 1994 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE  wopim &wNx  59



financial sector than Southeast Asia, there are more complaints about govern-
ment corruption than in Southeast Asia. One participant questioned whether, if
we compared the fifteen years of financial liberalization that started in 1975
with the fifteen years before 197S, we would find that savings and productivity
in the world economy were down.
Stiglitz said that Alfred Hirschman, in his well-known book Shifting Involve-
ments, talks about the constant search for balance between the public and
private sectors and the continual debate about their appropriate roles. Stiglitz
was trying to identify some problems with unfettered market solutions and to
argue that some forms of government intervention might address those prob-
lems. That does not mean that every government intervention, no matter how
badly designed, is going to improve things.
There is considerable evidence, Stiglitz went on, t-at in an array of countries,
especially in East Asia, strong government intervention had improved the effec-
tive allocation of society's resources and, more broadly, had promoted accu-
mulation and growth. In a major project carried out in the past year, the World
Bank tried to identify the salient properties of the successful interventions that
guided the "East Asian miracle." Analysts looked at what the governments had
done that was so successful. For example, what structures within government
reduced corruption and other problems that plagued many Latin American
counties when they tried similar policies? A number of lessons were learned,
said Stiglitz, about which government interventions were welfare enhancing and
which government structures reduced the likelihood of corruption. A broadly
based policy to allocate credit to firms that succeed in exporting, as Park dis-
cussed, was one example of an objective criterion that is relatively immune to
political influence. It is a government intervention based on well-defined rules.
The nature of government interventions, including regulatory interventions,
would be different for different countries. When one balances out the strengths
and weaknesses of a particular government and market, one might well con-
clude, for many countries, that the appropriate intervention is no intervention.
One must be careful to ask, Stiglitz continued, whether there are forms of
intervention that can address market failures. Some government interventions
are likely to be more prevalent than others. Prudential regulation is likely to be
desirable in almost all countries, although the exact design of the regulations
will differ. Obviously, more provocative interventions, such as directed credit or
financial repression, may not be suitable for many countries, and the form those
interventions take will be more controversial.
Stiglitz noted that in thie last four years of the Reagan administration, in a
country with relatively little corruption, there was considerable corruption in
government housing programs. So we cannot ignore the possibility of govern-
ment failure and government corruption, he said-but one hears the mantra of
goverrunent failure from many people, and we needn't all sing the same tune.
Governments can also succeed; the question is one of design. A reduced-form
regression saying that, on average, governments are bad or governments are
60                                                        Floor Discussion



good doesn't tell you anything; it is irrelevant. The questions are, rather:, can we
design governments to be more effective? Can we find particular programs that
make government corruption less likely and government success more likely?
A participant from the World Bank said that Stiglitz had identified the need
for government interventions to offset problems of imperfect information. He
asked Stiglitz to comment on the possibilities for learning in financial markets.
Does every transaction and transactor start out anew, or, because many agents
regularly participate in financial transactions, is there a process of maturity in
the financial market? Presumably the rationale for government intervention is
related to the question of imperfect information. Has Korea reached the stage at
which it does not need the same intensity of government regulation in financial
markets? If there were no information problems, Stiglitz said, the standard
competitive paradigm would apply as much to capital allocation as to allocation
of any other factor of production. Most of the reasons for market failure are
related to information failures. His arguments for government intervention
would be less persuasive if there were no corporate veil to create information
problems.
It may well be true that some of the conclusions reached through this new
view are similar to conclusions one reaches through very old views, said Stiglitz.
That goes back to Hirschman's point about shifting involvement. But it is to be
hoped that in revisiting this issue we have learned something in between-that
we are not returning full circle to the discredited theories of the 1950s. As Patel
said in his keynote address, we come back to some positions that are similar, but
with important differences. 'When we say that the government ought to be
involved, for example, we recognize government's limitations much more
explkcidy, and we are far more aware of how the government uses markets than
we were before. Nobody would say that the government ought to replace mar-
kets. An essential part of the new view is that governments should interact with
and use the power of markets.
Jessica Einhorn (chair) closed the discussion by quoting something she had
heard recently: you can never argue somebody out of a position that they
weren't argued into.
Floor Discusion                                                   61



I