WPS4123



            Differentiated Products and Evasion of Import Tariffs



                                            Beata S. Javorcik*

                                                        and

                                              Gaia Narciso**




Abstract: An emerging literature has demonstrated some unique characteristics of trade in differentiated
products. This paper contributes to the literature by postulating that differentiated products may be subject
to greater tariff evasion due to the difficulties associated with assessing their quality and price. Using
product-level data on trade between Germany and 10 Eastern European countries during 1992-2003, we
find empirical support for this hypothesis. We show that the trade gap, defined as the discrepancy
between the value of exports reported by Germany and the value of imports from Germany reported by
the importing country, is positively related to the level of tariff in 8 out of 10 countries. Further, we show
that the responsiveness of the trade gap to the tariff level is greater for differentiated products than for
homogeneous goods. A one-percentage-point increase in the tariff rate is associated with a 0.6% increase
in the trade gap in the case of homogeneous products and a 2.1% increase in the case of differentiated
products. Finally, the data indicate that greater tariff evasion observed for differentiated products tends to
take place through misrepresentation of the import prices.

Keywords: differentiated products, tariff evasion, transition countries



World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4123, February 2007


The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange
of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the
presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited
accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors.
They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they
represent. Policy Research Working Papers are available online at http://econ.worldbank.org.



* World Bank and CEPR, MSN MC3-303, 1818 H St, NW, Washington DC, 20433. Email:
bjavorcik@worldbank.org.
** Bocconi University, IEP, via Gobbi 5, 20136, Milano, Italy. Email: gaia.narciso@unibocconi.it.
The authors wish to thank Torfinn Harding, Leonardo Iacovone, Bernard Hoekman, Molly Lipscomb, Maurice
Schiff, Antonio Spilimbergo and David Tarr for their helpful comments and suggestions and Geoff Revell for
research assistance.


                                                           1

1. Introduction
         As many developing and transition countries rely on import tariffs as an important source of
revenue,1 evasion of customs duties has attracted a lot of attention from policy makers. For instance, a

report released by the state's budgetary watchdog, the Audit Chamber, found that the Russian customs

service was plagued by corruption which was costing the state billions of dollars annually (Baumgartner,

2001). An investigation by the Supreme Board of Inspection (NIK) in Poland suggested that importers

used various methods to artificially lower the value of imported goods, including fake invoices and

double invoicing (Polish News Bulletin, 2000). Revenue loss aside, there are other undesirable effects of

tariff evasion. It boosts the profitability of well-connected firms at the expense of honest producers and

importers. It may hinder the accession process to the World Trade Organization and hurt the image of the

country as an attractive location for foreign direct investment.

         The purpose of this study is to enhance our understanding of tariff evasion--concealment of

dutiable imports by private parties (individuals or private firms). It aims to do so in three ways. First, it

documents the existence of tariff evasion in transition countries by demonstrating that in 8 out of 10

Eastern European economies, the discrepancy between the export figures reported by Germany and the
import data recorded by the importing economy is systematically related to the tariff level.2 In this way, it

shows the generality of the pattern found for China by Fisman and Wei (2004). It also improves on

Fisman and Wei's work by relying on panel data rather than mostly cross-sectional information. Second,

it finds that tariff evasion is more prevalent for differentiated products, as defined by Rauch (1999). This

result is intuitive as it is more difficult to accurately assess the price of differentiated products, which

means that honest customs officers find it more difficult to detect an invoice stating an incorrect price and

corrupt customs officers have a plausible explanation for why they did not detect the problem with the
invoice.3 Third, the study shows that tariff evasion in the case of differentiated product tends to take place

by misrepresenting the price of imported goods rather than by undercounting physical quantities or

misclassifying products.

1Customs and other import duties accounted for 62% of tax revenue in the Maldives, 55% in Lesotho, 50% in
Madagascar, 42% in Bangladesh, 16% in Tajikistan and 10% in Ukraine (2004 figures from the World Bank's
World Development Indicators).
2Note that while some discrepancy in trade data may be due to lower quality of data recording in Eastern European
countries, in the absence of evasion such discrepancy would not be systematically related to the tariff rate.
3An investigation into customs import control launched by the Polish Supreme Board of Inspection showed that the
value of imported goods, as included in customs declarations, was often "ridiculously low," which went unnoticed
by customs officers. Importers used various methods to artificially lower the value of imported goods, including
fake invoices issued by both foreign suppliers and the importers or double invoicing. In most such cases, according
to the NIK report, customs officers either did not want or were unable to question the evident misrepresentation of
prices. The verification of customs value of imported goods during customs clearance procedures was in most cases
carried out according to the sole discretion of the customs officers on duty (Polish News Bulletin, 2000).


                                                          2

         Eastern Europe is a suitable environment for this study for three reasons. First, the weakness of its

institutions, including the customs service, makes it prone to tariff evasion. For instance, in a 1999 survey

51% of firms in Romania, 45% in Lithuania and 44% in Ukraine believed that there was a need to make
"additional payments" when dealing with customs.4 Second, trade liberalization taking place during the

period under study gives us a significant variation in tariff rates across time and across products. As

illustrated in Table A1 in Appendix I, during the period under study the average tariff rate in Poland

declined from 11.8% to 1.9%. The corresponding figures for Hungary were 12.9% and 5.6%, while for

Russia the change was from 12.1% to 10.4%. Third, as all but two of the countries in the sample were

preparing for their accession to the European Union during the time under study, the changes in their

tariff rates were determined by the pre-accession agreements (European Agreements) and thus are not

subject to endogeneity problems.

         Taking Fisman and Wei's work as our starting point, we analyze the sensitivity of tariff evasion

to tariff rates and identify the type of products which are subject to greater evasion. We use data on ten

Eastern European countries over the time period 1992-2003. We measure the trade gap as the difference

between the value of exports from Germany to each country in the sample as reported by Germany and

the value of imports from Germany as reported by each importing country. Considering the same trading

partner for all importers in the sample ensures that the export data are measured consistently. We choose

to focus on German exports, as Germany was a major trading partner of all countries in the sample

accounting for 31% of total imports in the Czech Republic, a quarter of imports in both Hungary and

Poland and 19% in Slovenia. The lowest share of German imports was registered in Ukraine where they

accounted for only 9% of the total (see Table A2 in Appendix I). The trade figures come from the United

Nations' COMTRADE database and are available at the product level (6-digit category in the

Harmonized System (HS) classification HS1988/92). Depending on the country, our data set includes

information on between 1,433 and 2,785 products for years between 1992 and 2003. The tariff data,

applied by each importing country to imports from Germany, measured also at the 6-digit HS level, have

been obtained from the UNCTAD's TRAINS database.

         We find a positive and significant relationship between the tariff level and the trade gap. This

relationship holds for 8 out of 10 countries as well as for the pooled sample. It is robust to including 6-

digit product dummies and country-year fixed effects. The responsiveness of the trade gap to the tariff

level is found to be the highest for Ukraine and the Russian Federation, both of which appear to have a


4The data come from the Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey (BEEPS), conducted jointly by
the World Bank and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. The statistics pertain to the
percentage of firms which answered "always," "mostly," "frequently," "sometimes" or "seldom" to the question
"How frequently do firms in your line of business have to pay some irregular "additional payments" to deal with
customs and imports?"


                                                      3

high level of corruption in the customs service according to the BEEPS survey mentioned earlier. It is

also interesting to note that no statistically significant relationship is found for Slovenia which is the

country with the lowest incidence of customs corruption as reported in BEEPS.

        In addition to testing the relationship between tariff levels and evasion, we ask what kind of

products are more likely to be subject to evasion. We consider Rauch's (1999) definition of differentiated

products and argue that for such products it may be easier to conceal their true value. We confirm our

hypothesis by showing that the trade gap is more responsive to the tariff level in the case of differentiated

goods than in the case of homogeneous products. This result holds for both a liberal and a conservative

definition of differentiated products and is robust to several specifications. The magnitude of the effect is

economically meaningful. A one-percentage-point increase in the tariff rate is associated with a 0.6%

increase in trade gap in the case of homogeneous products and a 2.1% increase in the case of

differentiated products.

        Finally, we consider three channels through which tariff evasion may take place. These are: (i)

misrepresenting the price of imported products; (ii) undercounting physical quantities of imported

products, and (iii) misclassification of high tariff products as a lower tariff variety. We find strong

evidence of price misrepresentation in the case of differentiated products. More specifically, our results

indicate that the gap in the unit values of exports reported by Germany and imports reported by the

destination country (which captures reporting a lower than actual price of imports) is positively correlated

with the tariff level. This effect is positive and statistically significant in the case of differentiated

products, but not for all other goods. We find little evidence of undercounting of physical quantities.

Neither do we find evidence of product misclassification when we consider misclassification within the

same 4-digit HS sector. We conclude that the difficulties associated with assessing the price of

differentiated products make them particularly prone to tariff evasion.

        Our study is related to the literature documenting evasion of import duties in developing

countries. In their 1970 volume, Little, Scitovsky and Scott pointed out that evasion of import duties

through smuggling was a major problem in Mexico, Argentina and the Philippines. Bhagwati (1964)

discussed the prevalence of under-invoicing as a method of tariff evasion. The type of corruption that

involved import duty evasion in which briber and bribee collude to rob the public was referred by Shleifer

and Vishny (1993) as "corruption with theft." Pritchett and Sethi (1994) examined the data from three

developing countries (Jamaica, Kenya and Pakistan) and found that collected and official tariff rates are

only weakly related, the variance of the collected rate increases strongly with the level of the official rate

and the collected rate increases much less than one-for-one with increases in the official rate. The

relationship between evasion and tariff rates was analyzed by Fisman and Wei (2004) who found that

import duty evasion rises with the tariff rate. Comparing the values of imports from Hong Kong as



                                                      4

reported by China with the Hong Kong data on its exports to China at the product level for 1998 they

demonstrated that a one-percentage-point increase in the tariff rate was on average associated with a three
percent increase in underreporting.5

         Our study also contributes to the emerging literature on differentiated products. In his seminal

work, Rauch (1999) classified goods into three categories. He defined homogeneous goods as products

whose price is set on organized exchanges. Goods which are not traded on organized exchanges, but

possess a benchmark price, were defined as reference priced. Finally, products whose price is not set on

organized exchanges and which lack a reference price because of their intrinsic features were labeled as

differentiated. Rauch argued that search costs tend to be higher for differentiated products relative to

homogeneous goods and showed that colonial ties and common language are more relevant for trade in

differentiated products than trade in homogeneous goods. In subsequent work, Rauch and Trinidade

(2002) found that the positive impact of ethnic Chinese networks on bilateral trade is greater for

differentiated products relative to homogeneous ones. In line with this result, Rauch and Casella (2003)

showed that the higher the degree of product differentiation the larger the impact of international ties

between wholesalers on bilateral trade. Fink, Mattoo and Neaugu (2002) provided evidence that the effect

of communication costs on trade is larger for differentiated products. Feenstra, Markusen and Rose (2001)

showed that home market effects are more pronounced for differentiated than for homogeneous products,

while Evans (2003) found that the higher the degree of product differentiation, the smaller the border

effects. In a recent paper, Besedes and Prusa (2006) showed that transactions in differentiated goods tend

to start involving smaller values than transactions of homogeneous goods and that trade relationships tend

to be longer for differentiated products than for homogeneous ones.

         While our study does not explicitly analyze the effects of customs reform, its results suggest that

a system which gives customs officials discretion and does not involve effective audits or secondary

inspections is likely to lead to tariff evasion. Corrupt behavior aside, the ability of the customs official to

evaluate invoice prices may be greatly enhanced by computerization and international agreements that

allow them to obtain verification from foreign institutions about the validity of documents presented by




5 Our work is also related to a more general literature on tax evasion. While many theoretical models have analyzed
the impact of tax rates on evasion, Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2000) concluded in their survey paper that theoretical
findings are not clear-cut, as they strongly depend on modeling assumptions. Contrasting results are provided by
empirical studies as well. Clotfelter (1983) and Feinstein (1991), who study the impact of tax rates on tax evasion by
using the U.S. Taxpayers Compliance Measurement Program data, ended up drawing opposite conclusions.
Cloetfleter found a positive relationship, while Feinstein, who employed a subset of the dataset, provided evidence
of a negative relationship.


                                                           5

importers. Our results also provide evidence in favor of having a uniform tariff structure which would
dampen the incentives to misclassify imported products.6

         This study is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 explores the

relationship between tariff rates and evasion. Section 4 presents the empirical results on tariff evasion for

differentiated products, and Section 5 examines the channels through which such evasion takes place.

Section 6 concludes.


2. Data
         Our first data source is the World Bank's World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS) database. This

database contains information on MFN and preferential tariff rates specific to pairs of countries and years,

derived from the UNCTAD's Trade Analysis and Information System (TRAINS). The tariff information

is available at the 6-digit Harmonized System level. We focus on 8 Eastern European countries acceding

to the European Union (Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania and
Slovenia) as well as on the Russian Federation and Ukraine.7 As most of these countries have preferential

trade agreements with the European Union, we use information on applied tariffs.

         As illustrated in Table 1, tariff rates differ substantially across the countries considered. Lithuania

has the lowest average tariff rate of 3.64%, as a large percentage of products are subject to zero tariff,

while Russian Federation shows the highest average tariff rate of 12.58%. Slovenia is the country with the

lowest maximum tariff rate, around 49%. A large fraction of imports is not taxed in Poland, although the

variance in Polish tariffs is very high, due to the high tariff rates applied to tobacco imports (up to 295%).

It is relevant to note that all countries in the sample undertook trade liberalization during the time period

under study and their tariff rates decreased significantly over time (see Table A1 in Appendix I).

         Our second data source is the United Nations' COMTRADE database which includes information

on trade flows, also at the 6-digit level. The data on tariffs and trade flows are available for the period

1992-2003, though the coverage differs by country (see Appendix I for more details). Using

COMTRADE data we calculate the trade gap, which is defined as the log difference between the value of

exports from Germany to each country in the sample as reported by Germany and the value of imports

from Germany as reported by each partner country.



6The theoretical arguments in favor of a uniform tariff structure are usually based on political economy
considerations and incentives for tariff evasion (see Panagariya and Rodrik 1993; Tarr 2002; Anderson and Neary
2006).
7Data constraints prevent us from including other post-Soviet transition countries in the sample. Unfortunately,
WITS does not include ad valorem equivalents of specific tariffs which may be prevalent in the countries not
acceding to the EU. However, not controlling for specific tariffs is likely to work against us finding a relationship
between trade evasion and tariff level. As specific tariffs are more likely to be imposed on agricultural products, in
our robustness checks we will exclude these products from the sample.


                                                            6

         As can be seen in the lower panel of Table 1, there are significant differences in the trade gap

across countries. A discrepancy between the value of exports recorded by the exporting country and the

value of imports recorded by the importer is to be expected. The first reason is that export prices are

expressed in f.o.b. terms while imports are recorded including the cost of insurance and freight (c.i.f.).

The second reason is that countries tend to monitor imports more carefully than exports. Thus, in the

absence of tariff evasion one would expect the discrepancy to be negative. And indeed the reported value

of imports exceeds that of exports in 6 out of 10 countries. The largest difference is observed in Latvia,

Russia and Ukraine, which are located farther away from Germany than Poland, the Czech Republic or

Hungary and thus their imports may need to incur higher transport costs. However, as illustrated in Table

1, in 4 out of 10 countries we observe a positive gap which means that on average Germany recorded

higher exports of a particular product line than the imports recorded by a transition country. The extent of

underreporting (i.e., the positive gap) ranges from 6% in the case of Hungary to 12% in Bulgaria, 14% in
the Czech Republic and 16% in Slovenia.8



                  Table 1: Tariff rates and trade gap by country.
                                                                 Tariff rates

                                           Mean     Standard    Minimum     Maximum        Obs.
                  Country                           deviation


                  Bulgaria                  3.96      7.18         0            68        3,453
                  Czech Republic            4.26      6.44         0           168        16,187
                  Hungary                   8.50      11.72        0           150        22,725
                  Latvia                    4.51      7.65         0            88        13,122
                  Lithuania                 3.64      7.45         0            70        10,284
                  Poland                    5.19      13.79        0           295        17,817
                  Romania                   7.23      9.20         0           144        9,874
                  Russian Federation       12.58      7.80         0           100        16,575
                  Slovenia                  6.78      7.23         0          49.2        10,546
                  Ukraine                   8.85      8.98         0            70        11,825


                                                                 Trade gap

                                           Mean     Standard    Minimum     Maximum        Obs.
                  Country                           deviation


                  Bulgaria                  0.11      1.20       -6.24        7.58        3,453
                  Czech Republic            0.13      1.10       -7.28        8.04        16,187
                  Hungary                   0.06      1.31       -7.39        8.23        22,725
                  Latvia                    -5.96     2.72       -14.65       6.50        13,122
                  Lithuania                 -0.08     1.23       -7.14        8.47        10,284
                  Poland                    -0.41     2.05       -10.40       6.47        17,817
                  Romania                   -0.01     1.30       -7.40        7.52        9,874



8Note that these percentages are calculated as the exponent of the values reported in Table 1.


                                                          7

                   Russian Federation        -5.45       2.98         -15.51        9.41        16,575
                   Slovenia                  0.15        1.33         -7.17         8.90        10,546
                   Ukraine                   -2.88       3.85         -14.05        7.56        11,825
                   Notes: trade gap = ln(exports reported by Germany)pt � ln(imports reported by the
                   importing country)pt where p stands for a 6-digit HS product and t for year.



3. Tariff rates and Trade gap
         It is reasonable to expect that the incentive of importers to evade import duties increases with the

tariff rate. And indeed Fisman and Wei (2004) find a positive relationship between the trade gap and the

tariff rate in China. But does this relationship hold in other countries or are Chinese importers unique in

their ability to conceal imports? As many transition countries had significantly lower tariffs than the

average rate of 17.6% imposed by China on imports from Hong Kong in 1998, the year considered by

Fisman and Wei, does the relationship between evasion and tariff level hold in transition economies?



                   Table 2: Trade gap by tariff rate.
                   Country                                           Trade Gap
                                           Tariff below median       Tariff above median       Difference
                                                     (1)                      (2)               (2) - (1)

                   Bulgaria                         0.00                      0.23               0.23
                                              (1751 products)           (1702 products)


                   Czech Republic                   0.09                      0.19               0.10
                                              (9874 products)           (6313 products)


                   Hungary                          -0.03                     0.15               0.18
                                             (11663 products)           (11062 products)


                   Latvia                           -6.05                    -5.82               0.24
                                              (8126 products)           (4996 products)


                   Lithuania                        -0.12                     0.03               0.15
                                              (7510 products)           (2774 products)


                   Poland                           -0.25                    -0.80               -0.55
                                             (12888 products)           (4929 products)


                   Romania                          -0.08                     0.09               0.17
                                              (6002 products)           (3872 products)


                   Russian Federation               -5.60                    -5.24               0.36
                                              (9815 products)           (6760 products)


                   Slovenia                         0.14                      0.16               0.01
                                              (7829 products)           (2717 products)


                   Ukraine                          -3.16                    -2.48               0.68
                                              (6996 products)           (4829 products)



                                                             8

                    Notes: trade gap = ln(exports reported by Germany)pt � ln(imports reported by the
                    importing country)pt where p stands for a 6-digit HS product and t for year. The
                    median tariff values are calculated for each country and each year.


         To shed some light on these questions, we start by presenting simple summary statistics of the

trade gap for each country in our sample. In each country, we split the products into those with the tariff

above the median rate and those with the tariff below the median (Table 2). In all countries, except for

Poland, the trade gap is higher for products whose tariffs are above the median. For instance, while in

Bulgaria there is no trade gap for products with low protection, in the case of goods with above median

tariff rate the discrepancy increases to 26%. In Hungary, the value of exports of products with a below

median tariff rate is 3% lower than the value of imports, but in the case of above median tariff rates,

exports are underreported by 16%. These summary statistics are consistent with the idea that the gap

value is a proxy for tariff evasion. We obtain similar results when we split the sample between products

with the top 25% tariff rates versus the rest. The puzzling result regarding Poland may be explained by

the high percentage of products subject to zero tariffs. The percentage of products exempt from tariffs

increased from 12% in 1998 to 89% in 1999 and remained well above 90% in the following years.

         Next we estimate a simple model of the trade gap as a function of the tariff rate and year fixed

effects. We do so for each country c in the sample separately.

      ln Export _valueGermany     ,cpt-lnIm port_valuecpt =trade_ gapcpt = + tariffcpt +t +cpt

where p stands for a 6-digit product and t for year. Our prior is that if the gap value is a good proxy for

tariff evasion then the estimated coefficient of the tariff rate should be positive and significant.

         The results, reported in Table 3, are consistent with the summary statistics presented earlier. The

estimated coefficient on the tariff rate is positive and significant at the 1% level for all the countries but

Slovenia and Poland. The higher the tariff rate, the lower the value of imports reported by the importing

country relative to the reported exports (i.e, the higher the trade gap). A one-percentage-point increase in

the tariff level is associated with a 4.4% increase in the trade gap in Ukraine, 3.2% increase in the Russian

Federation and 0.8% increase in Hungary. These results are in line with Fisman and Wei's study which
finds a 3% increase.9

         It is interesting to note that Ukraine, the country with the highest estimated elasticity, has the

second highest prevalence of corruption in customs as reported in the BEEPS survey. Slovenia, a country

for which there is no statistically significant relationship, is ranked as the cleanest country in terms of

corruption in customs according to BEEPS. See Appendix II for more details. The insignificant




9Note that these calculations do not take into account the direct effect an increase in a tariff rate may have on the
volume of imports.


                                                               9

coefficient found in the case of Poland is likely to be driven by the high percentage of products which are

subject to zero tariff.




                                                     10

Table 3: Trade gap and tariff rate by country.

                       (1)              (2)           (3)           (4)             (5)            (6)             (7)            (8)        (9)      (10)

                   Bulgaria       Czech
                                  Republic        Hungary       Latvia          Lithuania     Poland           Romania        Russia     Slovenia  Ukraine

                                                                                       Trade Gap


Tariff             0.009          0.015           0.008         0.022           0.013         0.000            0.01           0.032      -0.004    0.044

                   (0.003)***     (0.003)***      (0.001)***    (0.004)***      (0.003)***    (0.001)          (0.003)***     (0.004)*** (0.004)   (0.005)***


Observations       3453           16187           22725         13122           10284         17817            9874           16575      10546     11825

Adj. R-squared     0.004          0.009           0.007         0.005           0.010         0.674            0.005          0.011      0.0001    0.011

All models include year fixed effect and a constant. Standard errors, clustered on 6-digit products, are listed in parentheses.
* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.



         4. Trade gap, tariff rates and differentiated products
                   As mentioned earlier, differentiated products may lend themselves more readily to tariff evasion

         than homogeneous goods as their price depends on many attributes some of which may not be easily

         verifiable by a person unfamiliar with the product. Therefore, in the case of differentiated products it is

         more difficult for honest customs officers to detect an invoice stating an incorrect price and corrupt

         customs officers have a plausible explanation for why they failed to detect the problem with the invoice.

                   In our analysis, we use the classification of differentiated products developed by Rauch (1999).

         Rauch defined differentiated products as those not having a reference price or those whose price is not

         quoted on organized exchanges. Wheat and diamonds are classified as homogeneous goods, while coats

         and jackets are considered to be differentiated products. Rauch suggested two definitions, a conservative

         and a liberal one, in order to account for the ambiguities arising in the classification. The conservative

         definition minimizes the number of commodities that are classified as homogeneous goods, while the

         liberal definition maximizes this number. We employ both classifications, although the results do not

         differ substantially between the two. Rauch's definitions are based on the 4-digit SITC Rev. 2

         classification, and we use the concordance provided by WITS to make it compatible with the 6-digit HS

         1988/92 classification used in our data set.

                   Table 4, which reports the average trade gap for differentiated and homogeneous goods, confirms

         our prior about differentiated products lending themselves more readily to tariff evasion. For all countries

         but Latvia and the Czech Republic, the trade gap is larger for differentiated products than for

         homogeneous goods. For instance in Bulgaria, there is hardly any discrepancy for homogeneous products

         (-2.6% in the case of the conservative and -1.6% in the case of the liberal definition), but a significant

         trade gap is found for differentiated products (16.6% and 17.6% for the conservative and liberal

         definition, respectively). In the case of Hungary, the gap increases from 3% for homogeneous goods to




                                                                                 11

6.7% for differentiated products when the conservative definition is used. The corresponding figures for

the liberal definition are 2.2 and 7.4%.



           Table 4: Average tariff rates and trade gap by type of product.
                                                                       Tariff rate
                                        Homogeneous        Differentiated       Homogeneous         Differentiated
                                                 Conservative                                 Liberal


           Bulgaria                        6.352               3.277                 5.592              3.359
           Czech Republic                  4.953               3.965                 4.726              4.012
           Hungary                         10.753              7.725                10.254              7.736
           Latvia                          5.256               4.331                 4.938              4.375
           Lithuania                       4.381               3.447                 3.603              3.651
           Poland                          8.671               4.132                 7.811              4.132
           Romania                         9.858               6.372                 8.937              6.513
           Russian Federation              9.222               13.717               10.120             13.655
           Slovenia                        5.674               7.168                 5.575              7.320
           Ukraine                         7.878               9.096                 7.763              9.211


                                                                       Trade Gap
                                        Homogeneous        Differentiated       Homogeneous         Differentiated
                                                 Conservative                                 Liberal


           Bulgaria                        -0.026              0.154                -0.016              0.162
           Czech Republic                  0.141               0.125                 0.115              0.138
           Hungary                         0.030               0.065                 0.022              0.071
           Latvia                          -5.906              -5.978               -5.937             -5.973
           Lithuania                       -0.222              -0.043               -0.210             -0.036
           Poland                          -0.466              -0.388               -0.473             -0.379
           Romania                         -0.060              0.005                -0.076              0.016
           Russian Federation              -5.712              -5.366               -5.717             -5.338
           Slovenia                        0.114               0.157                 0.108              0.163
           Ukraine                         -2.949              -2.869               -2.951             -2.863
           Notes: trade gap = ln(exports reported by Germany)pt � ln(imports reported by the importing country)pt
           where p stands for a 6-digit HS product and t for year.


         Note that the upper panel in Table 4 indicates that for 7 out of 10 countries in the sample, the

tariff rate on differentiated products is lower than the tariff rate on homogeneous goods. This allows us to

have some confidence that the reported differences in trade gap between differentiated and homogeneous

products are likely to be driven by evasion rather than differences in tariff rates.

         To test whether differentiated products are more likely to be subject to underreporting, we pool

all countries in the sample and regress the trade gap on the tariff rate, the differentiated product dummy




                                                              12

and the interaction between the tariff rate and the differentiated product dummy. Our specification is as

follows:
                         trade _ gapcpt = 0 + 1tariffcpt + 2differentiated _ productp +
                         + 3tariffcpt *differentiated _ productp +ct +cpt

where trade _ gapcpt is the gap value for the country c importing product p at time t; tariffcpt is the tariff

rate imposed by country c on imports of product p from Germany at time t, differentiated _ productp is

the differentiated product dummy based on Rauch's conservative or liberal definition, depending on the

specification. To control for importing country-specific changes that may occur in a particular time

period, such as a reform of the customs service or a decline in the incidence of corruption, we include

country-year fixed effects. Thus to the extent that the introduction of computerization or an increase of

salaries in the customs service affects tariff evasion across the board, it will be captured by these fixed

effects. Finally, we cluster standard errors at the 6-digit product level.

         In line with the evidence shown in the previous section, we expect the estimated coefficient for

the tariff rate to be positive and significant. The higher the tariff rate, the higher the incentive for tax

evasion, and the higher the expected gap. We are, however, primarily interested in the interaction

between the tariff rate and the differentiated product dummy. Our prior is that the effect of the tax rate is

higher for differentiated products relative to homogeneous ones. This is because differentiated product

may make it easier for importers or corrupt customs officials to misrepresent the price of the imports.

Classifying homogeneous goods is relatively straightforward and there is little variation in prices, thus

misrepresenting the price could easily be detected. With differentiated products the wide range of

potential uses, product characteristics and quality levels make the assessment of price more difficult, thus

creating more room for tax evasion. Therefore, we expect the estimated coefficient 3 to be positive.

         The results, reported in Table 5, support our hypothesis that the positive relationship between the

tariff rate and trade evasion is stronger for differentiated products. In the first column of Table 5, we

confirm that the positive correlation between tariff levels and the trade gap holds in the pooled sample. In

the second column, we employ the conservative definition of differentiated products and find that the

estimated coefficient on the interaction term is positive and significant at the 1% level. This finding

confirms our prior that the response of tariff evasion to the tariff rate is higher for differentiated products.

Note that the differentiated product dummy itself is not significant suggesting that differentiated products

differ in terms of the trade gap response to the tariff level but not in terms of the trade gap in general. As

in the country regressions, the tariff coefficient remains positive and statistically significant, indicating

that an increase in the tariff rate leads to an increase in the gap value, and hence to an increase in the

evasion and underreporting of imports. The results hold when we consider the liberal definition of


                                                      13

differentiated products (see column 3). Again, the responsiveness of evasion to an increase in the tariff

rate is greater for differentiated products. The estimated coefficient of the interaction term is positive and

statistically significant at the 1% level. The magnitude of the effect is economically meaningful. A one-

percentage-point increase in the tariff rate is associated with a 0.6% increase in evasion in the case of
homogeneous products and a 2.1% increase in the case of differentiated products10.

         A potential concern is that our results may be driven by agricultural products which are

homogeneous in nature and may be subject to non-tariff barriers. To check this possibility, in columns 4-6

we replicate the previous specifications excluding agricultural products (HS codes 010111 to 530599).

The same results hold: the estimated coefficient of the tariff rate is still positive and statistically

significant. Similarly, the interaction term between the tariff rate and the differentiated product dummy,

both in the liberal and conservative definition, has a positive and highly significant impact on the trade

gap.




10These magnitudes refer to the specification in column 2.


                                                        14

       Table 5: Trade, tariff rates and differentiated products.
                                          (1)            (2)             (3)          (4)             (5)           (6)
                                                                           Trade Gap


       Tariff                        0.012           0.006          0.007         0.012           0.005         0.006
                                     (0.001)***      (0.001)***     (0.001)***    (0.001)***      (0.001)***    (0.001)***


       Tariff*Conservative                           0.015                                        0.016
       dummy                                         (0.002)***                                   (0.002)***


       Tariff*Liberal dummy                                         0.014                                       0.015
                                                                    (0.002)***                                  (0.002)***


       Conservative dummy                            -0.009                                       0.009
                                                     (0.03)                                       (0.032)


       Liberal dummy                                                0.015                                       0.032
                                                                    (0.029)                                     (0.03)


       Agricultural products         Included        Included        Included     Excluded        Excluded      Excluded


       Observations                  132408          132408         132408        127893          127893        127893
       Adjusted R-squared            0.59            0.59           0.59          0.59            0.59          0.59
       All regressions include country-year fixed effects and a constant. Standard errors, clustered on 6-digit product, are
       listed in parentheses.
       * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.


          As a robustness check, we introduce country-year fixed effects together with 6-digit product fixed

effects thus controlling for country-specific changes in the performance of the customs service as well as

unobservable product characteristics (see Table 6). The estimated coefficient of the interaction term is

still positive and statistically significant at the 1% level in all specifications, both with and without

agricultural products and both for the liberal and the conservative definition of differentiated products.

The estimated elasticity of the trade gap with respect to the tariff rate is positive and significant in 4 out of

6 specifications.




                                                               15

        Table 6: Trade gap, tariff rates and differentiated products. Controlling for country-year fixed effects
        and 6-digit product fixed effects.
                                   (1)           (2)           (3)           (4)            (5)           (6)
                                                                       Trade Gap


        Tariff                     0.008         0.002         0.003         0.007          0.001         0.002
                                   (0.001)***    (0.001)**     (0.001)***    (0.001)***     (0.001)       (0.001)


        Tariff*Conservative                      0.013                                      0.014
        Dummy                                    (0.002)***                                 (0.002)***


        Tariff*Liberal                                         0.012                                      0.013
        Dummy                                                  (0.002)***                                 (0.002)***


        Agricultural products      Included      Included      Included      Excluded       Excluded      Excluded


        Observations               132408        132408        132408        127893         127893        127893
        Adjusted R-squared         0.6           0.6           0.6           0.6            0.6           0.6
        All regressions include country-year and 6-digit product fixed effects as well as a constant. Robust standard
        errors are listed in parentheses.
        * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.


        As another robustness check, we estimate a model in first differences. This will allow us to

eliminate the time-invariant effects specific to a particular product imported by a particular country. To

control for importing country-specific time trends, e.g., an improvement in the quality of the customs

services over time, we include importing-country fixed effects. Our estimating equation takes the

following form:

            trade_ gapcpt =0 +1tariffcpt +2tariffcpt *differentiated _dummyp +c +cpt

        Again, the estimation results confirm our earlier findings (see Table 7). The interaction term is

positive and statistically significant for both the liberal and the conservative definition of differentiated

products. The coefficient on tariff level, however, loses its significance.




                                                             16

     Table 7: Trade gap, tariff rates and differentiated products. Specification in first differences.
                                             (1)            (2)          (3)          (4)            (5)          (6)
                                                                              Trade Gap


      Tariff                                 0.001          -0.005       -0.004       0.002          -0.004       -0.002
                                             (0.002)        (0.005)      (0.004)      (0.002)        (0.005)      (0.004)


      Tariff*Conservative dummy                             0.012                                    0.010
                                                            (0.005)**                                (0.005)*


      Tariff*Liberal dummy                                               0.010                                    0.008
                                                                         (0.005)**                                (0.005)*


     Agriculture                             Included       Included     Included     Excluded       Excluded     Excluded


     Observations                            102989         102989       102989       99883          99883        99883
     Adjusted R-squared                      0.0003         0.0003       0.0003       0.0003         0.0003       0.0003
     All regressions include country fixed effects and a constant. Robust standard errors are listed in parentheses.
     * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.



5. Channels of tariff evasion
         In the light of the above findings, it is natural to ask how tariff evasion takes place. There are

three potential channels through which importers may attempt to avoid or minimize the tariff payment: (i)

misrepresenting the price of imported products; (ii) undercounting physical quantities of imported

products, and (iii) misclassification of high tariff products as a lower tariff variety. In this section, we

explore each of these evasion methods.


5.1 Misrepresenting the price of imported products

         To examine the prevalence of misrepresenting the price of imports, we calculate the difference

between the unit value of exports reported by Germany and the unit value of imports recorded by the

importing country:

         value_ gapcpt = ln(Export _ quantityGermany
                                     Export _valueGermany       ,cpt  ) -ln(Im Im port _valuecpt          )
                                                                  ,cpt           port _ quantitycpt

As before, the gap is calculated at the level of 6-digit HS product for each importing country and each

year.




                                                               17

Table 8: Unit value gap. Homogeneous versus differentiated products.

                         Mean               St. Dev        Homogeneous      Differentiated Homogeneous    Differentiated
                                                                     Conservative                     Liberal


Bulgaria                  0.29               1.06              -0.146           0.417          -0.120         0.445
Czech Republic            0.21               0.80              0.021            0.288           0.036         0.301
Hungary                   0.18               0.84              0.006            0.246           0.013         0.260
Latvia                   -5.83               2.44              -5.920           -5.803         -5.920        -5.795
Lithuania                 0.23               0.91              -0.027           0.312           0.004         0.323
Poland                   -0.37               1.97              -0.495           -0.329         -0.457        -0.332
Romania                   0.33               1.05              0.018            0.448           0.034         0.472
Russian Federation       -5.25               2.72              -5.524           -5.160         -5.524        -5.133
Slovenia                  0.14               0.86              -0.146           0.235          -0.129         0.256
Ukraine                  -2.78               3.64              -2.995           -2.730         -2.992        -2.714




                Table 9: Unit value gap by tariff rate.
                Country                                         Unit Value Gap
                                      Tariff below median     Tariff above median         Difference
                                               (1)                     (2)                 (2) � (1)

                Bulgaria                      0.15                    0.43                  0.27
                                        (1713 products)         (1700 products)


                Czech Republic                0.18                    0.25                  0.07
                                        (9283 products)         (6065 products)


                Hungary                       0.14                    0.23                  0.09
                                     (11129 products)          (10720 products)


                Latvia                       -5.90                    -5.70                 0.20
                                        (7940 products)         (4918 products)


                Lithuania                     0.19                    0.35                  0.15
                                        (6639 products)         (2438 products)


                Poland                       -0.20                    -0.80                 -0.60
                                        (12636 products)        (4873 products)


                Romania                       0.25                    0.46                  0.20
                                        (5114 products)         (3312 products)


                Russian Federation           -5.29                    -5.20                 0.10
                                        (9625 products)         (6495 products)


                Slovenia                      0.08                    0.30                  0.22
                                        (7642 products)         (2655 products)


                Ukraine                      -3.01                    -2.45                 0.56
                                        (6820 products)         (4711 products)




                                                            18

         In the absence of evasion, we would expect the unit value gap to be negative, as import statistics

include the cost of freight and insurance, neither of which is captured by the export data. However, as

indicated in Table 8, in 6 out of 10 countries the average unit value gap is positive. It is even more

striking that in all countries, the average unit value gap is larger for differentiated products. This is true

for both the conservative and the liberal definition of differentiated products. Further, Table 9 suggests

that in all but one country (Poland) the unit value gap is larger for products with the above median tariff

rate.

         To test this relationship more formally, we regress the unit value gap on the tariff rate,

differentiated product dummy and the interaction between the two variables. To save space, we present

only the specification estimated with country-year and product fixed effects and the specification in first
differences. We restrict our attention to the sample excluding agricultural products.11



   Table 10: Unit value gap.
                                          (1)            (2)              (3)           (4)           (5)           (6)
                                                       Levels                                  First differences
   Tariff                               0.000          -0.001           -0.001      0.003       -0.004          -0.003
                                       (0.001)        (0.001)          (0.001)*     (0.002)     (0.005)         (0.004)


   Tariff*Conservative dummy                           0.002                                    0.012
                                                      (0.001)*                                  (0.005)**


   Tariff*liberal dummy                                                 0.003                                   0.010
                                                                      (0.001)**                                 (0.005)**


   Country-year fixed effects            Yes            Yes              Yes            No            No            No
   Product fixed effects                 Yes            Yes              Yes            No            No            No
   Country fixed effects                  No             No              No             Yes          Yes            Yes
   Agricultural products              Excluded       Excluded         Excluded        Excluded    Excluded       Excluded


   Observations                        121963         121963           121963       94658       94658           94658
   Adjusted R-squared                    0.66           0.66             0.66       0.0001      0.0002          0.0002
   All regressions include a constant. Robust standard errors are listed in parentheses.
   * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.




         As evident in Table 10, we find no evidence of price misrepresentation (i.e., reporting unit values

of imports as being lower than what they really are) being responsive to the tariff rate in general. On the

contrary, in one case we find a negative and statistically significant coefficient on the tariff rate. However,

we do find evidence suggesting that price misrepresentation is positively correlated with the tariff rate in

the case of differentiated products. The results suggest that a one-percentage-point increase in the tariff


11Including agricultural products in the sample would not change the conclusions of this study.


                                                                19

 rate is associated with a 0.2% increase in the unit value gap. When we estimate a model in first

 differences, we confirm these findings and find an even larger effect: a one-percentage-point increase in

 the tariff rate is associated with a 1.2% increase in the value gap. The estimated coefficient is significant

 at the 5% level.


 5.2 Undercounting quantities of imported products

          Next we turn to another potential channel of tariff evasion, namely undercounting the quantities

 of imports, and we calculate the difference between the quantity of exports reported by Germany and the

 quantity of imports recorded by the importing country.

          The summary statistics presented in Table 11 suggests that this channel of tariff evasion is much

 less prevalent. In 9 out of 10 countries, the quantity gap is negative suggesting that the quantities recorded

 by the importing country are larger than those recorded by Germany. The negative value is consistent

 with the stylized fact that countries tend to monitor their imports more carefully than exports.


Table 11: Quantity gap. Homogeneous versus differentiated products.

                         Mean           St. Dev           Homogeneous     Differentiated Homogeneous  Differentiated
                                                                   Conservative                   Liberal


Bulgaria                 -0.18           1.53                0.119            -0.273       0.104         -0.294
Czech Republic           -0.07           1.34                0.125            -0.159       0.082         -0.157
Hungary                  -0.13           1.52                0.024            -0.188       0.007         -0.195
Latvia                   -0.14           1.55                0.000            -0.178       -0.027        -0.181
Lithuania                -0.33           1.49                -0.202           -0.370       -0.219        -0.375
Poland                   -0.04           0.98                0.032            -0.056       -0.014        -0.044
Romania                  -0.38           1.63                -0.076           -0.488       -0.112        -0.502
Russian Federation       -0.21           1.70                -0.184           -0.216       -0.190        -0.216
Slovenia                 0.01            1.59                0.263            -0.078       0.239         -0.093
Ukraine                  -0.12           1.73                0.052            -0.162       0.045         -0.174




                                                          20

                 Table 12: Quantity gap by tariff rate.
                 Country                                  Quantity Gap
                              Tariff below median      Tariff above median      Difference
                                       (1)                      (2)             (2) - (1)

                 Bulgaria             -0.17                    -0.20              -0.02
                                 (1713 products)        (1700 products)

                 Czech                -0.08                    -0.06              0.02
                 Republic       (9283 products)         (6065 products)


                 Hungary              -0.18                    -0.08              0.10
                               (11129 products)         (10720 products)


                 Latvia               -0.16                    -0.12              0.04
                                (7940 products)         (4918 products)


                 Lithuania            -0.33                    -0.34              -0.01
                                (6639 products)         (2438 products)


                 Poland               -0.05                    0.00               0.05
                               (12636 products)          (4873 products)


                 Romania              -0.37                    -0.40              -0.03
                                (5114 products)         (3312 products)

                 Russian              -0.31                    -0.06              0.24
                 Federation     (9625 products)         (6495 products)


                 Slovenia             0.07                     -0.15              -0.22
                                (7642 products)         (2655 products)


                 Ukraine              -0.18                    -0.03              0.15
                                (6820 products)         (4711 products)


         While the quantity gap is always negative for differentiated products, it is positive in the majority

of countries when homogeneous products are considered. This is true in 7 out of 10 countries in the case

of the conservative definition and in 5 out of 10 countries in the case of the liberal definition. It is may be

easier to undercount quantities of homogeneous goods as they tend to be sold by weight rather than by

piece. As expected, the quantity gap is larger for products with the above median tariff. This is true in 6

out of 10 countries considered (see Table 12).

         When we repeat our econometric exercise with the quantity gap as the dependent variable, we

find little support for undercounting being a major channel of tariff evasion. While the model in levels

produces positive coefficients on the tariff rate as well as on its interaction with the differentiated product

dummy, both coefficients lose their significance in a first difference specification (Table 13).



  Table 13: Quantity gap. Homogeneous versus differentiated products.




                                                       21

                                        (1)             (2)               (3)            (4)          (5)            (6)
                                                      Levels                                   First differences
   Tariff                          0.007           0.002            0.003           0.000       0.001           0.001
                                   (0.001)***      (0.001)*         (0.001)***      (0.001)     (0.001)         (0.001)


   Tariff*Conservative dummy                       0.012                                        -0.001
                                                   (0.001)***                                   (0.002)


   Tariff*liberal dummy                                             0.01                                        -0.001
                                                                    (0.001)***                                  (0.002)


   Country-year fixed effects           Yes             Yes              Yes        No          No              No
   Product fixed effects                Yes             Yes              Yes        No          No              No
   Country fixed effects                No              No                No        Yes         Yes             Yes
   Agricultural products              Excluded       Excluded         Excluded      Excluded    Excluded        Excluded


   Observations                        121963         121963           121963       94658       94658           94658
   Adjusted R-squared                   0.01            0.01             0.01       0.0002      0.0002          0.0002


   All regressions include a constant. Robust standard errors are listed in parentheses.
   **** significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.




5.3 Misclassification of imported products

         Finally, we turn to misclassification of products as another potential channel of tariff evasion. We

follow Fisman and Wei (2004) and include in our basic specification an additional regressor�the average

tariff on similar products which are defined as all other 6-digit products belonging to the same 4-digit HS

category. The average is weighted by the share of each product in German exports within each 4-digit HS
category.12 This additional regressor enters the estimated equation by itself as well as in interaction with

the differentiated product dummy. If misclassification takes place, we expect to see a negative coefficient

on the tariff on similar products, which would signify that holding the own tariff rate constant, a lower

tariff on similar products creates more opportunities for misreporting. If such misclassification is easier

for differentiated products, we would expect the coefficient on the interaction term to bear a negative

sign.

  Table 14: Results with tariffs on similar products.
                                           (1)            (2)             (3)           (4)         (5)           (6)
                                                            Levels                               First differences
  Tariff                                   0.006          0.000           0.000         0.004       -0.002        -0.002
                                           (0.001)***     (0.002)         (0.002)       (0.004)     (0.006)       (0.006)


  Tariff on similar products               0.003          0.001           0.002         -0.001      -0.001        0.001
                                           (0.002)        (0.002)         (0.002)       (0.004)     (0.006)       (0.005)


12The summary statistics for each importing country are presented in Appendix I Table A3.
Note that using an unweighted average would lead to similar conclusions.


                                                               22

  Tariff*Conservative dummy                               0.013                                       0.01
                                                          (0.003)***                                  (0.008)


  Tariff on similar products                              0.002                                       0.000
  *Conservative dummy                                     (0.003)                                     (0.008)


  Tariff*Liberal dummy                                                  0.013                                         0.011
                                                                        (0.003)***                                    (0.008)


  Tariff on similar products                                            0.000                                         -0.004
  *Liberal dummy                                                        (0.003)                                       (0.008)


  Country-year fixed effects               Yes            Yes           Yes            No             No              No
  Product fixed effects                    Yes            Yes           Yes            No             No              No
  Country fixed effects                    No             No            No             Yes            Yes             Yes
  Agricultural products                    Excluded       Excluded      Excluded       Excluded       Excluded        Excluded


  Observations                             123857         123857        123857         95509          95509           95509
  Adjusted R-squared                       0.6            0.6           0.6            0.00           0.0001          0.00
  Robust standard errors in parentheses. Tariff on similar products is defined as the weighted tariff on all other 6-digit
  products belonging to the same 4-digit category. Weights are equal to product export shares within the 4-digit category.
  * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.


         In contrast to the findings of Fisman and Wei, we do not find that misclassification (at least

within the same 4-digit HS category) is prevalent in transition countries. As can be seen in Table 14, tariff

on similar products does not appear to be statistically significant in any specification. Neither does its

interaction with the differentiated product dummy. Our basic result, suggesting that elasticity of missing

trade is larger for differentiated products, remains unchanged in the specification in levels. The overall

responsiveness of missing trade to the tariff rate, however, retains its significance in only one

specification. These changes in results are most likely due to a high correlation between own tariff rate

and the tariff rate on similar products (0.86).

         The lack of evidence on misclassification may be attributed to high correlation between own tariff

and tariff on similar products or to the possibility that misclassification takes place outside the same 4-

digit category. For example, when in 2000 Johnson & Johnson was importing to Russia their "2-in-1

Shower Gel" the company categorized it as a soap substitute, but customs decided to consider the product

as a cosmetic and the company had to pay a 20% instead of a 15% duty (Aris, 2000). While soap is

included in the 3401 HS category (HS 340120 is "soap in other forms"), cosmetics belong to HS 3304

("beauty, make-up, skin-care, nes").

         In sum, our analysis suggests that differentiated products may lend themselves more easily to

tariff evasion and that such evasion is likely to take place through misrepresentation of product prices

rather than undercounting of physical quantities or misclassifying products.



                                                                23

6. Conclusions
          An emerging literature building on Rauch's (1999) paper has demonstrated some unique

characteristics of trade in differentiated products. This paper contributes to the literature on differentiated

products by postulating that such products may be subject to greater tariff evasion due to the difficulties

associated with assessing the quality and thus the price of such products, which creates greater scope for

tariff evasion on the part of importers and corrupt customs officials.

          Using product-level data on German exports to 10 Eastern European countries we demonstrate

empirical support for this hypothesis. We show that the trade gap, defined as the positive discrepancy

between the value of exports reported by Germany and the value of imports from Germany reported by an

Eastern European importer, is positively correlated with the level of tariff in 8 out of 10 countries, thus

generalizing the result of Fisman and Wei (2004) found for China. Further, we demonstrate that the

responsiveness of the trade gap to the tariff level is greater for differentiated products than for

homogeneous goods. A one-percentage-point increase in the tariff rate is associated with a 0.6% increase

in trade gap in the case of homogeneous products and a 2.1% increase in the case of differentiated

products. Finally, our results indicate that the greater tariff evasion observed for differentiated products

tends to take place through misrepresentation of the import price.

          While our study does not explicitly focus on the effects of customs reform, its findings suggest

that limiting discretion of customs officials, introducing systems allowing for verification of import

documents or price comparisons with similar products and introducing effective audits of customs

officials are likely to lower tariff evasion. Our results also provide evidence in favor of having a uniform

tariff structure which would dampen the incentives and the ability to misclassify imported products.


References

Anderson, James E. and J. Peter Neary. 2006. "Welfare versus Market Access: The Implications
of Tariff Structure for Tariff Reform," Journal of International Economics, forthcoming.

Aris, Ben, 2000. "Russia: Come clean," Business Russia, Economist Intelligence Unit, October.

Baumgartner, Edward, 2001. "Russia: More harm than goods," Business Eastern Europe,
Economist Intelligence Unit, June 4.

Besedes, Tibor and Prusa, Thomas J., 2006. "Product Differentiation and Duration of US Import
Trade," Journal of International Economics, forthcoming.

Bhagwati, Jagdish, 1964. "On the Under-Invoicing of Imports," Bulletin of the Oxford University
Institute of Statistics, Vol. 2: 389-397.




                                                      24

Clotfelter, Charles T., 1983, "Tax Evasion and Tax Rates: An Analysis of Individual Returns,"
Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 65 (3) (August): 363-73.

Evans, Carolyn L., 2003. "The Economic Significance of National Border Effects," American
Economic Review, Vol. 93 (September): 1291-1312.

Feenstra, Robert, Markusen, James R. and Rose, Andrew K., 2001. "Using the Gravity Equation
to Differentiate Among alternative Theories of Trade," Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 34
(May): 430-447.

Feinstein, Martin, 1991. "An Econometric Analysis of Income Tax Evasion and its Detection,"
RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 62(1) (Spring): 14-35.

Fink, Carsten, Mattoo, Aaditya and Neagu, Cristina, 2005. "Assessing the Impact of
Communication Costs on International Trade," Journal of International Economics, Vol. 67(2)
(December): 428-445.

Fisman, Raymond and Wei, Shang-Jin, 2004. "Tax Rates and Tax Evasion: Evidence from
"Missing Imports" in China," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 112(2) (April): 471-500.

Little, Ian, Scitovsky, Tibor and Scott, Maurice, 1970. Industry and Trade in Some Developing
Countries. A Comparative Study. Published by Oxford University Press for the OECD.

Panagariya, Arvind and Dani Rodrik. 1993. "Political-Economy Arguments for a Uniform
Tariff," International Economic Review, Vol. 34(3): 685-703.

Polish News Bulletin, 2000. "Ineffective Customs Control Threatens Domestic Producers, Says
NIK Report," September 19.

Pritchett, Lant and Sethi, Geeta, 1994. "Tariff Rates, Tariff Revenue, and Tariff Reform: Some
New Facts," World Bank Economic Review. Vol. 8, No. 1 (January): 1-16.

Rauch, James E., 1999. "Networks Versus Markets in International Trade," Journal of
International Economics, Vol. 48 (June): 7-35.

Rauch, James E and Casella, Alessandra, 2003. "Overcoming Informational Barriers to
International Resource allocation: Prices and Ties," Economic Journal. Vol. 113 (January): 21-
42.

Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W., 1993. "Corruption," Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Vol. 110 (August): 681-712.

Slemrod, Joel and Yitzhaki, Shlomo, 2000. "Tax Avoidance, Evasion, and Administration,"
NBER Working Papers 7473, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.




                                                25

Tarr, David. 2002. "Arguments for and against Uniform Tariffs" in Development, Trade and the
WTO, Bernard Hoekman, Aaditya Mattoo and Philip English, eds. The World Bank:
Washington, DC.




                                             26

Appendix I

The data coverage for individual countries is as follows:

Bulgaria: 2001-2002; Czech Republic: 1996-2001; Hungary: 1992-2001; Latvia: 1996-2003; Lithuania:

1995-2000; Poland: 1994-2003; Romania: 1999-2003; Slovenia: 1999-2003; Russian Federation: 1996-

2003; Ukraine: 1996-2002.


Tariff data are not available for all years. In case of missing data we keep the tax rate constant until a new

tariff rate is available. We fill in the tax rates for a maximum of three periods.


In the WITS database, Hungarian imports are reported only if the value is above US$1000. In order to

keep a similar structure, we drop all the exports from Germany whose value is below this threshold. A

similar problem arises for Poland. No imports below US$50,000 are reported by Poland. We apply the

same strategy as before by dropping all the exports from Germany whose value is below this cutoff.




                                                         27

Table A1: Average tariff rate in the first and last year
Country                                         Tariff rates
                             First year              Last year   Difference


                                 (1)                     (2)      (2) - (1)
Bulgaria                        3.91                    4.01       0.10
                          (1706 products)        (1747 products)


Czech Republic                  6.25                    2.09       -4.15
                          (2785 products)        (2612 products)


Hungary                        12.94                    5.55       -7.39
                          (2282 products)        (2193 products)


Latvia                          3.98                    3.43       -0.54
                          (1433 products)        (1753 products)


Lithuania                       3.92                    3.54       -0.38
                          (1537 products)        (1775 products)


Poland                         11.78                    1.90       -9.88
                          (1784 products)        (1756 products)


Romania                         8.37                    6.49       -1.88
                          (1929 products)        (2013 products)


Russian Federation             12.08                   10.35       -1.73
                          (2073 products)        (1791 products)


Slovenia                       10.69                    0.74       -9.95
                          (2188 products)        (2061 products)


Ukraine                         7.86                    7.81       -0.05
                          (1756 products)        (1616 products)




                                      28

      Table A2: Average share of imports from Germany on total imports

                             Avg. share of imports from Germany on total imports



      Bulgaria                                       15%
      Czech Republic                                 31%
      Huingary                                       25%
      Latvia                                         16%
      Lithuania                                      17%
      Poland                                         25%
      Romania                                        15%
      Russian Federation                             12%
      Slovenia                                       19%
      Ukraine                                         8%




Table A3: Summary statistics for tariff on similar products

Country                     Mean        Standard
                                       deviation   Minimum    Maximum            Obs.



Bulgaria                      3.31          6.19           0          67         3453
Czech Republic                3.98          5.99           0        138         15956
Hungary                       7.78         10.72           0        150         21810
Latvia                        4.25          6.86           0          75        11754
Lithuania                     3.42          6.99           0          70        9927
Poland                        4.46         12.50           0        295         17130
Romania                       6.33          8.44           0          98        9694
Russian Federation          11.52           8.18           0        100         16243
Slovenia                      6.23          7.02           0          45        10367
Ukraine                       8.06          8.85           0          50        11682




                                          29

Appendix II

Figure A1. Prevalence of corruption in customs vs. responsiveness of trade gap to tariff level

   30.0%                                                                              0.050
   25.0%                                                                              0.040
   20.0%
                                                                                      0.030
   15.0%

   10.0%                                                                              0.020

    5.0%                                                                              0.010

    0.0%                                                                              0.000

          mania  raine                                           y
                                              land     tvia            blic
                                                    La
        Ro     Uk     BulgariaLithuania  ssia
                                       Ru    Po            Hungarh Repu    Slovenia
                                                            Czec

                       BEEPS Corruption
                       Responsiveness of evasion gap to tariff
                       Linear (Responsiveness of evasion gap to tariff)


Notes: Responsiveness of trade gap to tariff is equal to the coefficient estimated in Table 4. Statistically insignificant
coefficients are set to zero. BEEPS corruption is defined as the percentage of firms reporting that "additional
payments" are made "always," "usually" or "frequently" when dealing with customs and imports. It is the average
value for the 1999 and 2002 wave of the survey.


The exact questions used in the survey were as follows:

"How frequently do firms in your line of business have to pay some irregular "additional payments" to
deal with customs and imports?" (1999 survey)

"Thinking now of unofficial payments/gifts that a firm like yours would make in a given year, could you
please tell me how often would they make payments/gifts to deal with customs and import" (2002 survey)

The possible answers were: always, usually, frequently, sometimes, seldom, never.




                                                           30