THEWORLD BANK Discussion Paper EDUCATION AND TRAINING SERIES Report No. EDT94 Time Trends of the Returns to Education Cross-National Evidence George Psacharopoulos June 1987 Education and Training Department Operations Policy Staff The views presented here are those of the author(s), and they should not be interpreted as reflecting those of the World Bank. I Discussion Paper Education and Training Series Report No. EDT94 TIME TRENDS OF THE RETUfIS TO EUWCATION: CROSS-NTONAL mEDCE George Psacharopoulos Research Division Education and Training Department June 1987 The World Bank does not accept responsibility for the views expressed herein, which are those of the author and should not be attributed to the World Bank or its affiliated organizations. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions are the results of research or analysis supported by the Bank; they do not necessarily represent official policy of the Bank. Copyright 0 1987 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/ The World Bank I I Abstract The paper presents evidence on the over-time behavior of the rate of return to investment in education in a Large number of countries. The emerging pattern is one of declining returns through time, a fact that is interpreted in the context of alternative theories on the relationship between education and earnings, such as human capital, screening, labor market segmentation and the maintenance of the status quo from generation to generation. The evidence lends support. to a human capital view of the world. Also, the slow rate of decline of the returns to education over time dispells fears that education might have overexpanded, especially in developing countries. TIME TREMDS OF THE RETURNS TO EDUCAON: CROSS-ATOIAL EVIDENCE by George Psacharopoulos* 1. Introduction Since the early days of the humarL capital literature, special attention has been paid on the over-time behavior of the rate of return to investment in education. 1/ The issue is Lmportant for several reasons. First, if expenditure on educatinm is treated as investment, then the yield of such investment should behave as that of more conventional forms of capital. For example, and other things being equal, the rate of return to investment in schooling should decline following educational expansion. Second, the behavior of the returns to schooling over time constitutes a partial (although by no means sufficient) test of a number of labor market theories related to educatiot. For example, a pattern of declining private returns over time would be inconsistent with labor market segmentation or radical (social class) explanations of earnings differentials. (Gordon 1972, Bowles 1972). The reason is that such theories assume a status quo or immobilitsy of labor with different educational qualifications between income classes. Similarly, declining social returns to investment in education would be inconsistent with the screening hypothesis because the more educated would be unable to persistently maintain their productivity-unrelated earnings advantage over the less educated. (Arrow, 1973). * The views expressed here are those of' the author and should not be attributed to the World Bank. 1/ For a theoretical discussion and some! empirical evidence from the United States and Israel, see Becker (1975), pp. 6-7, 75-77 and 205-2 13. -2- Third, for educational policy making, it is important to know when the returns to investment in education have fallen enough to not justify further expansion, or when the returns have increased above the alternative discount rate to recommend expansion. (Blaug, 1967). 1/ Fourth, in the theory and practice of educational planning, it is crucial to know the elasticity of substitution between different types of educated labor. (Dougherty, 1971). A pattern of near constant returns over time would be consistent with a near infinite elasticity of substitution between more and less educated manpower -- an empirical fact that would invalidate attempts to forecast the precise future needs in skilled manpower for economic development. Lastly, a pattern of declining returns to investment in education, would be consistent with the equalizing effect of educational expansion on income distribution, i.e, other things being equal, an increase in the number of more educated relative to the less educated would narrow the reward structure and hence lead to a lower index of income inequality. (Marin and Psacharopoulos, 1976). 1/ This proposition is based on the assumption that economic considerations is the only criterion for planning. Of course other values, e.g., universal literacy or political expediency may override the narrow economic criterion. -3- II. The Evidence When the field of the economics of education started, over time evidence on the returns to educationi existed only for the United States. Although such evidence continues to be scarce today, there have been sufficient estimates for a number of countries to dictate a stock-taking exercise. Tables A-1 and A-2 present the existing evidence on the returns to education estimated within a given country for more than one point in time. The tables correspoEd to the two basic methodologies of estimating the returns to education, i.e., the elaborate method, and the earnings function method (see Psacharopoulos, 1981). The first gives returns by level of education, whereas the second gives the returns to the average year of schooling irrespective of the level of education. The evidence appearing in the Appendix Tables is indiscriminate, in the sense that no efEort has been made to render the rates comparable between years. This is not an easy task because the rates in each year may have been based on different samples or methodologies. Also, the over-time changes in the social returns to education are affected by changes in the unit (resource) cost of education between the two years. Bearing in mind this limitation, the overall trend in the returns to education is an over-time decline. Out of the 71 pairs of end year estimates in the two Appendix Tables, the returns to education have declined in 45 cases between the earlier and later year. -4- In order to have a more accurate picture of the over-time behavior of the returns to education, Table 1 reports a set of more or less, if not strictly, comparable estimates. All rates reported in Table 1 are based on the same methodology, which is the Mincerian semi-logarithmic earnings function with three arguments: Years of schooling, years of experience, and the square of the latter. (Mincer, 1974). Also, all rates are based on a sample of similar nature in the two years, which in most cases is the country's population census. In all but one case (Colombia) the rates in the two years have been estimated by the same author, which further assures consistency of sampling and methodology in the two years. 5- Table 1 Comparable Over-Time Returns to Investment in Education, Selected Countries Annual Change Rate of Return Years of Rate of Return Years of Country Year (percent) Sehooling (percentage points) Schooling Developing Countries Brazil 1970 16.5 3.9 1980 14.5 5.7 -0.20 +.18 Chile 1974 8.3 5.9 1980 9.6 8.1 +0.22 +0.19 Colombia 1965 17.3 2.8 1974 12.8 5.0 -0.05 +0.18 Venezuela 1975 13.7 4.6 1984 11.2 6.6 -0.28 +0.22 Cyprus 1975 12.5 8.4 1984 11.0 9.5 -0.17 +0.12 Industrial Countries Canada 1/ 1972 16.0 10.0 1980 11.6 11.8 -.04 +0.18 France 1962 16.3 9.4 1977 15.4 11.4 -0.06 +0.13 United Kingdom 1972 9.7 10.5 1975 8.0 10.5 -0.57 0.00 United States 2/ 1950 7.1 9.7 1960 10.5 10.6 +0.34 +0.09 1970 8.4 12.1 -0.21 +0.15 1980 6.4 12.5 -0.20 +0.04 Source: Rates of return from Table A-2 unless iitated otherwise. Mean years of schooling for Brazil, Venezuela, Cyprus, Canada and the UK from the original source of the respective rate of return estimate. Chile (1969, 1981) and Colombia (1964, 1978) from Psacharopoulos and Arriagada (1986), Table 2. United States 1950, refers to the median year of schooling of the population from United States Bureau of the Census (1975), H617, 1960 onwards from United States Bureau of the Census (1986), Table 216. France, from INSEE, "Formation Qualification Professionelle," respective years. Note: 1/ Rates refer to university education computed on the basis of mean earnings of 40-44 year old workers in Dooley (1986), Table 1. 2/ Rates refer to college education computed on the basis of rental prices in Waldorf, Kunze, Rosenblum and Tannen, (1987) Table 8. 3/ Estimated on the basis of end years corresponding to the schooling means rather than the rate of return years on the left. -6- Out of the nine pairs of end-year estimates appearirng in Table 1, there are seven declines. (The less than 1 percentage point increase in the Chilean case may well be due to sample variability or particular labor market conditions in one of the two end years). In most cases the rate of decline amounts to less than one half percentage point per year. The last column of Table 1 documents the deepening of human capital stock in the countries in question by means of the change in the educational attainment of the labor force. 2/ The evidence on the over-time behavior of the returns to education is consistent with what Tinbergen (1975) described as the "race between technology and education," namely, educational expansion shifts the supply curve of educated persons to the right, whereas technological advances also shift the demand curve for skilled persons in the same direction. Therefore, the eventual observed intersection between supply and demand over time is an empirical matter. Figure 1 presents the outcome of such race for one industrial and one developing country. Thus, in the United States during the decade of the fifties, demand shifts dominated supply shifts and the returns to education increased between 1950 and 1960. Thereafter, however, the expansion of education has dominated demand with the result of a falling rate of return pattern. The Venezuelan case is also one of falling returns between 1975 and 1984. 2/ It is reminded that the translation of an increase in enrollments (flow measure) to a higher level of educational attainment of the labor force (stock measure) is a very slow process. (For a documentation of this point see Psacharopoulos and Arriagada, 1986). -7- r RATE oF 5; (% ~) aE%tru/- 8/, Rrz-r N S loI I D DIS D 9 1 1 3 MEAN YEARS oF SCHOOLiNN RATE OF (/o) |RETUjN 14~~~~~~17 IL ~~~~~~~D VENEZUELA 4 o -D 4 5 7 MENN YEARS oF SCkiOOL)NC FiGURE I THE RkCE 5ET.WEEN EDUCATiON AND TECHNo%.oGY IN T7O covN�tES -8- III. Conclusion The evidence presented above lends support to the economic interpretation of the over-time behavior returns to education, i.e., the rates decline over time following educational expansion. Is the magnitude of the decline such as to raise doubts about the economic profitability of further educational expansion? The answer to this question must be negative on two main grounds: First, the returns to education, especially in developing countries, continue to be above a reasonable measure of the opportunity cost of capital, say 10 percent. The decline of the returns to education recorded above has taken place during a period of rapid global educational expansion. Also, the evidence seems to be more consistent with the human capital theory of the relationship between education and earnings, rather than the alternative theories of screening, segmentation, or the maintenance of the status quo from generation to generation. -9- Arrow, K., "Higher Education as a Filter," Journal of Public Economics, July 1973. Becker, G., Human Capital, 2nd ed. (NBER), 1975. Blaug, M., "Approaches to Educational Planning," Economic Journal, No. 306, June 1967: 262-87. Bowles, S., "Schooling and Inequality from Generation to Generation," Journal of Political Economy, May-June (Supplement) 1972. Demetriades, E. and Psacharopoulos, G., "Educational Expansion and the Returns to Education: Evidence from Cyprus," International Labour Review, 1987 (Forthcoming). Dooley, M.D., "The Overeducated Canadian? Changes in the Relationship Among Earnings, Education and Age for Canadian Men: 1971-81," Canadian Journal of Economics, 19, (1), 1986: 142-159. Dougherty, C.R.S., Optimal Allocation of Investment in Education, in Chenery, H.B. (Ed.) Studies in Development Planning, Harvard University Press, 1971. Gordon, D., Theories of Poverty and Unemployment, Lexington, 1972. Hansen, W. L., "Total and Private Returms to Investment in Schooling," Journal of Political Economy, ApriL 1963. Hines, F., Tweeten, L. and Redfern, M., "Social and Private Rates of Return to Investment in Schooling by Race-sex Groups and Regions," Journal of Human Resources, vol. 3, 1970. Mincer, J., Schooling, Experience and Earnings, Columbia University Press, 1974. Mingat, A. and Jarousse J.P., "Earnings Functions, Generation Effects and Filtering: A Test on French Data," Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, IREDU, Faculte des Science Mirande, B.P. 138, Dijon France (Mimeo), 1986. Marin, A. and Psacharopoulos G., "Schooling and Income Distribution," The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. LVIII, No. 3, August 1976. Psacharopoulos, G., "Returns to Education: An Updated International Comparison," Comparative Education, vol 17, No. 3, 1981:321-41. Psacharopoulos, G., "Returns to Education: A Further International Update and Implications," Journal of Human Resources, Fall 1985. - 10 - Psacharopoulos, G. and Arriagada, A.M., "The Educational Composition of the Labour Force: An International Comparison," International Labour Review, vol. 125, No. 5, pp. 561-574, September-October 1986. Psacharopoulos, G., "Economic Development and Investment: The Role of the Work Force," Journal of Educational Planning and Administration, (India), May 1987a. Psacharopoulos, G. and Arriagada, A.M., "Earnings and Education Among the Self-employed in Colombia," EDT Series No. 70, 1987. Psacharopoulos, G., "Earnings and Education in Brazil: Evidence from the 1980 Census," EDT Series No. 90, 1987. Psacharopoulos, G. and Steier, F., "Education in the Venezuelan Labor Market, 1974-1985," EDT Series No. 93, 1987. Shapiro, D.M. and Stelcner, M., "Earnings Regressions and Decompositions of Earnings Differentials," Earnings Disparities in Quebe After Bill 101, Concordia University, Working Paper No. 14, 1985. Tinbergen J., Income Distribution: Analysis and Policies, North-Holland, 1975. Waldorf, W.H., Kunze, K., Rosenblum, L.S. and Tannen, M.B., "New Measures of the Contribution of Education and Experience to U.S. Productivity Growth," Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor, 1987 (Mimeo). United States, Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1970, US Printing Office, 1975. United States, Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States, US Printing Office, 1986. Table A-1 The Returns to Investment in Education by Year (pertent) Social Private Country Year Prim. Sec. Higher Prim. Sec. Higher Africa Kenya 1971 19.2 1980 13.0 Malawi 1978 15.1 1982 15.2 Upper Volta 1970 25.9 60.6 1975 27.7 30.1 22.0 1982 20.1 14.9 21.3 Asia India 1952 44.0 1.0.0 57.0 30.0 1960 17.0 11.0 9.0 23.0 12.0 11.0 1965 13.4 15.5 10.3 17.3 18.8 16.2 1978 29.3 15.7 1.0.8 33.4 19.8 13.2 Iran 1972 34.0 11.5 15.0 1976 15.2 17.6 L3.6 Pakistan 1975 20.0 11.0 27.0 1979 14.6 6.7 9.4 Philippines 1971 8.5 9.5 1977 8.5 16.0 South Korea 1967 9.0 5.0 1969 11.0 9.5 1971 14.6 9.3 1973 12.2 8.8 1980 8.1 11.7 Taiwan 1970 26.5 15.0 17.6 18.4 1972 12.3 17.7 12.7 15.8 Thailand 1970 30.5 13.0 11.0 1972 63.2 30.9 18.4 Continued Table A-1 (Continued) Social Private Country Year Prim. Sec. Hither Prim. Sec. Higher Latin America Brazil 1970 23.5 13.1 24.7 13.9 1980 Colombia 1973 20.7 1976 24.9 Peru 1972 46.9 19.8 16.3 1974 34.3 9.0 15.0 1980 41.4 3.3 16.1 venezuela 1957 82.0 17.0 23.0 18.0 27.0 1975 16.4 14.6 11.2 24.5 20.2 21.5 1984 17.5 10.5 8.7 24.3 12.4 15.0 OECD/Europe Australia 1969 14.0 13.9 1976 8.1 21.1 Cyprus-1 1975 15.0 11.2 14.8 1979 8.6 8.1 14.1 1984 15.5 4.5 14.1 Cyprus-2 1975 10.5 9.7 11.6 8.6 1979 6.8 7.6 7.0 5.6 Greece 1962 6.3 13.7 7.2 14.0 1977 5.5 4.5 6.0 5.5 France 1962 14.3 11.5 9.3 1969 16.2 12.0 9.6 1976 13.5 10.8 9.3 Germany 1964 4.6 1978 10.5 Continued Table A-1 (Conltinued) Social Private Country Year Prim. Sec. Higher Prim. Sec. Higher OECD/Europe Great Britain 1971 11.0 7.0 14.0 27.0 1972 3.6 8.2 11.7 9.6 1973 8.0 8.0 6.0 16.0 1975 7.0 7.0 9.0 22.0 1977 8.0 6.0 9.0 17.0 1978 9.0 7.0 11.0 23.0 Japan 1967 10.5 1973 4.6 6.4 5.9 8.1 1976 8.6 6.9 10.4 8.8 1980 5.7 8.3 United States 1939 18.2 10.7 16.0 14.5 1949 14.2 10.6 14.5 10.1 1959 10.1 11.3 19.5 13.6 1969 10.7 10.9 18.8 15.4 1970 11.3 8.8 1971 12.5 8.0 1972 11.3 7.8 1973 12.0 5.5 1974 14.8 4.8 1975 12.8 5.3 1976 11.0 5.3 Source: Unless stated otherwise, PsLcharopoulos (1985), Appendix Table A-1. India 1952 and L960, Psacharopoulos (1987a), Appendix. Venezuela 1975 andl 1984, Psacharopoulos and Steier (1987). Cyprus 1984, DemetrLades and Psacharopoulos (1987). United States, private rates, 1939, Becker (1975), p. 206; 1949, Hansen (1963), Table 5; 1959, Hines (1970). Table A-2 The Coefficient on Years of Schooling: Mincerian Rate of Return, by Year Country Year Coefficient (percent) Asia India 1954 9.4 1970 6.7 1978 7.4 1980 9.7 Hong Kong 1976 6.3 1981 6.1 Malaysia 1970 14.0 1978 22.8 South Korea 1976 6.5 1980 11.1 Latin America Brazil 1970 16.5 1980 14.5 Chile 1974 8.3 1975 9.8 1976 10.0 1977 11.3 1978 8.6 1979 8.8 1980 9.6 Colombia 1965 17.3 1971 16.7 1973 17.6 1974 12.8 1975 15.4 1977 14.4 1978 14.4 1984 11.0 Guatemala 1975 10.8 1977 11.3 Venezuela 1975 13.7 1984 11.2 Continued Table A-2 (Continued) The Coefficient on Years of Schooling: Mincerian Rate of Return, by Year Country Year Coefficient (percent) OECD/Europe Canada 1970 7.8 1980 8.6 Cyprus 1975 12.5 1979 9.8 1981 5.2 1984 11.0 France 1962 16.3 1970 19.2 1977 15.4 Germany 1974 12.1 1977 12.6 Greece 1960 9.2 1964 8.6 1977 5.8 United Kingdom 1972 9.7 1975 8.0 United States 1959 10.7 1969 7.8 1973 8.2 Source: Unless otherwise stated, Psacharopoulos (1985), Appendix Table B.1. Brazil, Psacharopoulos (1987b). India, Psacharopoulos (1987a), Appendix. Cyprus 1984, Demetriades and Psacharopoulos (1987). Colombia, 1974 and 1984, Psacharopoulos, Arriagada and Velez (1987), Table 4. Venezuela, Psacharopoulos and Steier (1987). France, MiLngat and Jarousse (1986), Table 2. Canada (Quebec), Shapiro and Stelener (1985), Tables Rl and AII R-1.