THEWORLD BANK
Discussion Paper
EDUCATION AND TRAINING SERIES
Report No. EDT94
Time Trends of the Returns to Education
Cross-National Evidence
George Psacharopoulos
June 1987
Education and Training Department                             Operations Policy Staff
The views presented here are those of the author(s), and they should not be interpreted as reflecting those of the World Bank.



I



Discussion Paper
Education and Training Series
Report No. EDT94
TIME TRENDS OF THE RETUfIS TO EUWCATION:
CROSS-NTONAL mEDCE
George Psacharopoulos
Research Division
Education and Training Department
June 1987
The World Bank does not accept responsibility for the views expressed
herein, which are those of the author and should not be attributed to the
World Bank or its affiliated organizations. The findings, interpretations,
and conclusions are the results of research or analysis supported by the
Bank; they do not necessarily represent official policy of the Bank.
Copyright 0 1987 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/
The World Bank



I
I



Abstract
The paper presents evidence on the over-time behavior of the rate
of return to investment in education in a Large number of countries. The
emerging pattern is one of declining returns through time, a fact that is
interpreted in the context of alternative theories on the relationship
between education and earnings, such as human capital, screening, labor
market segmentation and the maintenance of the status quo from generation
to generation. The evidence lends support. to a human capital view of the
world. Also, the slow rate of decline of the returns to education over
time dispells fears that education might have overexpanded, especially in
developing countries.






TIME TREMDS OF THE RETURNS TO EDUCAON:
CROSS-ATOIAL EVIDENCE
by
George Psacharopoulos*
1.    Introduction
Since the early days of the humarL capital literature, special
attention has been paid on the over-time behavior of the rate of return to
investment in education. 1/ The issue is Lmportant for several reasons.
First, if expenditure on educatinm is treated as investment, then
the yield of such investment should behave as that of more conventional
forms of capital.  For example, and other things being equal, the rate of
return to investment in schooling should decline following educational
expansion.
Second, the behavior of the returns to schooling over time
constitutes a partial (although by no means sufficient) test of a number of
labor market theories related to educatiot.  For example, a pattern of
declining private returns over time would be inconsistent with labor market
segmentation or radical (social class) explanations of earnings
differentials. (Gordon 1972, Bowles 1972). The reason is that such
theories assume a status quo or immobilitsy of labor with different
educational qualifications between income classes. Similarly, declining
social returns to investment in education would be inconsistent with the
screening hypothesis because the more educated would be unable to
persistently maintain their productivity-unrelated earnings advantage over
the less educated. (Arrow, 1973).
*   The views expressed here are those of' the author and should not be
attributed to the World Bank.
1/ For a theoretical discussion and some! empirical evidence from the
United States and Israel, see Becker (1975), pp. 6-7, 75-77 and
205-2 13.



-2-
Third, for educational policy making, it is important to
know when the returns to investment in education have fallen enough to
not justify further expansion, or when the returns have increased
above the alternative discount rate to recommend expansion. (Blaug,
1967). 1/
Fourth, in the theory and practice of educational planning,
it is crucial to know the elasticity of substitution between different
types of educated labor. (Dougherty, 1971). A pattern of near
constant returns over time would be consistent with a near infinite
elasticity of substitution between more and less educated manpower --
an empirical fact that would invalidate attempts to forecast the
precise future needs in skilled manpower for economic development.
Lastly, a pattern of declining returns to investment in
education, would be consistent with the equalizing effect of
educational expansion on income distribution, i.e, other things being
equal, an increase in the number of more educated relative to the less
educated would narrow the reward structure and hence lead to a lower
index of income inequality. (Marin and Psacharopoulos, 1976).
1/ This proposition is based on the assumption that economic
considerations is the only criterion for planning. Of course
other values, e.g., universal literacy or political expediency may
override the narrow economic criterion.



-3-
II.    The Evidence
When the field of the economics of education started, over
time evidence on the returns to educationi existed only for the United
States. Although such evidence continues to be scarce today, there
have been sufficient estimates for a number of countries to dictate a
stock-taking exercise.
Tables A-1 and A-2 present the existing evidence on the
returns to education estimated within a given country for more than
one point in time. The tables correspoEd to the two basic
methodologies of estimating the returns to education, i.e., the
elaborate method, and the earnings function method (see
Psacharopoulos, 1981). The first gives returns by level of education,
whereas the second gives the returns to the average year of schooling
irrespective of the level of education.
The evidence appearing in the Appendix Tables is
indiscriminate, in the sense that no efEort has been made to render
the rates comparable between years. This is not an easy task because
the rates in each year may have been based on different samples or
methodologies. Also, the over-time changes in the social returns to
education are affected by changes in the unit (resource) cost of
education between the two years.
Bearing in mind this limitation, the overall trend in the
returns to education is an over-time decline. Out of the 71 pairs of
end year estimates in the two Appendix Tables, the returns to
education have declined in 45 cases between the earlier and later
year.



-4-
In order to have a more accurate picture of the over-time
behavior of the returns to education, Table 1 reports a set of more or
less, if not strictly, comparable estimates. All rates reported in
Table 1 are based on the same methodology, which is the Mincerian
semi-logarithmic earnings function with three arguments: Years of
schooling, years of experience, and the square of the latter. (Mincer,
1974). Also, all rates are based on a sample of similar nature in the
two years, which in most cases is the country's population census. In
all but one case (Colombia) the rates in the two years have been
estimated by the same author, which further assures consistency of
sampling and methodology in the two years.



5-
Table 1
Comparable Over-Time Returns to Investment in Education,
Selected Countries
Annual Change
Rate of Return    Years of         Rate of Return        Years of
Country                Year       (percent)       Sehooling     (percentage points)   Schooling
Developing Countries
Brazil                 1970        16.5              3.9
1980       14.5              5.7               -0.20               +.18
Chile                  1974         8.3              5.9
1980        9.6              8.1               +0.22              +0.19
Colombia               1965        17.3              2.8
1974       12.8              5.0               -0.05              +0.18
Venezuela              1975        13.7              4.6
1984       11.2              6.6               -0.28              +0.22
Cyprus                 1975        12.5              8.4
1984       11.0              9.5               -0.17              +0.12
Industrial Countries
Canada 1/              1972        16.0             10.0
1980       11.6             11.8               -.04               +0.18
France                 1962        16.3              9.4
1977       15.4             11.4               -0.06              +0.13
United Kingdom         1972         9.7             10.5
1975        8.0             10.5               -0.57               0.00
United States 2/       1950         7.1              9.7
1960       10.5             10.6               +0.34              +0.09
1970        8.4             12.1               -0.21              +0.15
1980        6.4             12.5               -0.20              +0.04
Source:  Rates of return from Table A-2 unless iitated otherwise.  Mean years of schooling
for Brazil, Venezuela, Cyprus, Canada and the UK from the original source of the
respective rate of return estimate. Chile (1969, 1981) and Colombia (1964, 1978)
from Psacharopoulos and Arriagada (1986), Table 2. United States 1950, refers to
the median year of schooling of the population from United States Bureau of the
Census (1975), H617, 1960 onwards from United States Bureau of the Census (1986),
Table 216. France, from INSEE, "Formation Qualification Professionelle,"
respective years.
Note:  1/  Rates refer to university education computed on the basis of mean earnings of
40-44 year old workers in Dooley (1986), Table 1.
2/ Rates refer to college education computed on the basis of rental prices in
Waldorf, Kunze, Rosenblum and Tannen, (1987) Table 8.
3/  Estimated on the basis of end years corresponding to the schooling means rather
than the rate of return years on the left.



-6-
Out of the nine pairs of end-year estimates appearirng in
Table 1, there are seven declines. (The less than 1 percentage point
increase in the Chilean case may well be due to sample variability or
particular labor market conditions in one of the two end years). In
most cases the rate of decline amounts to less than one half
percentage point per year. The last column of Table 1 documents the
deepening of human capital stock in the countries in question by means
of the change in the educational attainment of the labor force. 2/
The evidence on the over-time behavior of the returns to
education is consistent with what Tinbergen (1975) described as the
"race between technology and education," namely, educational expansion
shifts the supply curve of educated persons to the right, whereas
technological advances also shift the demand curve for skilled persons
in the same direction. Therefore, the eventual observed intersection
between supply and demand over time is an empirical matter.
Figure 1 presents the outcome of such race for one
industrial and one developing country. Thus, in the United States
during the decade of the fifties, demand shifts dominated supply
shifts and the returns to education increased between 1950 and 1960.
Thereafter, however, the expansion of education has dominated demand
with the result of a falling rate of return pattern. The Venezuelan
case is also one of falling returns between 1975 and 1984.
2/   It is reminded that the translation of an increase in enrollments
(flow measure) to a higher level of educational attainment of the
labor force (stock measure) is a very slow process. (For a
documentation of this point see Psacharopoulos and Arriagada,
1986).



-7-
r    RATE oF                   5;
(% ~)  aE%tru/-
8/,  Rrz-r N                                 S
loI              I                
D
DIS
D
9                1                1 3
MEAN YEARS oF SCHOOLiNN
RATE OF
(/o)  |RETUjN
14~~~~~~17
IL                ~~~~~~~D
VENEZUELA                                   4
o          -D
4           5                          7
MENN YEARS oF  SCkiOOL)NC
FiGURE I  THE RkCE 5ET.WEEN  EDUCATiON AND TECHNo%.oGY
IN T7O covN�tES



-8-
III.     Conclusion
The evidence presented above lends support to the economic
interpretation of the over-time behavior returns to education, i.e.,
the rates decline over time following educational expansion.
Is the magnitude of the decline such as to raise doubts
about the economic profitability of further educational expansion?
The answer to this question must be negative on two main grounds:
First, the returns to education, especially in developing countries,
continue to be above a reasonable measure of the opportunity cost of
capital, say 10 percent. The decline of the returns to education
recorded above has taken place during a period of rapid global
educational expansion.
Also, the evidence seems to be more consistent with the human
capital theory of the relationship between education and earnings,
rather than the alternative theories of screening, segmentation, or
the maintenance of the status quo from generation to generation.



-9-
Arrow, K., "Higher Education as a Filter," Journal of Public Economics,
July 1973.
Becker, G., Human Capital, 2nd ed. (NBER), 1975.
Blaug, M., "Approaches to Educational Planning," Economic Journal, No. 306,
June 1967: 262-87.
Bowles, S., "Schooling and Inequality from Generation to Generation,"
Journal of Political Economy, May-June (Supplement) 1972.
Demetriades, E. and Psacharopoulos, G., "Educational Expansion and the
Returns to Education: Evidence from Cyprus," International Labour
Review, 1987 (Forthcoming).
Dooley, M.D., "The Overeducated Canadian? Changes in the Relationship
Among Earnings, Education and Age for Canadian Men: 1971-81," Canadian
Journal of Economics, 19, (1), 1986: 142-159.
Dougherty, C.R.S., Optimal Allocation of Investment in Education, in
Chenery, H.B. (Ed.) Studies in Development Planning, Harvard
University Press, 1971.
Gordon, D., Theories of Poverty and Unemployment, Lexington, 1972.
Hansen, W. L., "Total and Private Returms to Investment in Schooling,"
Journal of Political Economy, ApriL 1963.
Hines, F., Tweeten, L. and Redfern, M., "Social and Private Rates of
Return to Investment in Schooling by Race-sex Groups and Regions,"
Journal of Human Resources, vol. 3, 1970.
Mincer, J., Schooling, Experience and Earnings, Columbia University Press,
1974.
Mingat, A. and Jarousse J.P., "Earnings Functions, Generation Effects
and Filtering: A Test on French Data," Centre National de la Recherche
Scientifique, IREDU, Faculte des Science Mirande, B.P. 138, Dijon
France (Mimeo), 1986.
Marin, A. and Psacharopoulos G., "Schooling and Income Distribution," The
Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. LVIII, No. 3, August 1976.
Psacharopoulos, G., "Returns to Education: An Updated International
Comparison," Comparative Education, vol 17, No. 3, 1981:321-41.
Psacharopoulos, G., "Returns to Education: A Further International Update
and Implications," Journal of Human Resources, Fall 1985.



- 10 -
Psacharopoulos, G. and Arriagada, A.M., "The Educational Composition of the
Labour Force: An International Comparison," International Labour
Review, vol. 125, No. 5, pp. 561-574, September-October 1986.
Psacharopoulos, G., "Economic Development and Investment: The Role of the
Work Force," Journal of Educational Planning and Administration,
(India), May 1987a.
Psacharopoulos, G. and Arriagada, A.M., "Earnings and Education Among the
Self-employed in Colombia," EDT Series No. 70, 1987.
Psacharopoulos, G., "Earnings and Education in Brazil: Evidence from the
1980 Census," EDT Series No. 90, 1987.
Psacharopoulos, G. and Steier, F., "Education in the Venezuelan Labor
Market, 1974-1985," EDT Series No. 93, 1987.
Shapiro, D.M. and Stelcner, M., "Earnings Regressions and Decompositions of
Earnings Differentials," Earnings Disparities in Quebe After Bill
101, Concordia University, Working Paper No. 14, 1985.
Tinbergen J., Income Distribution: Analysis and Policies, North-Holland,
1975.
Waldorf, W.H., Kunze, K., Rosenblum, L.S. and Tannen, M.B., "New Measures
of the Contribution of Education and Experience to U.S. Productivity
Growth," Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor, 1987
(Mimeo).
United States, Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United
States, Colonial Times to 1970, US Printing Office, 1975.
United States, Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United
States, US Printing Office, 1986.



Table A-1
The Returns to Investment in Education by Year (pertent)
Social                    Private
Country           Year      Prim.   Sec.   Higher    Prim.   Sec.  Higher
Africa
Kenya             1971               19.2
1980              13.0
Malawi            1978               15.1
1982              15.2
Upper Volta       1970      25.9    60.6
1975     27.7    30.1   22.0
1982     20.1    14.9   21.3
Asia
India             1952               44.0   1.0.0               57.0   30.0
1960     17.0    11.0    9.0         23.0    12.0   11.0
1965     13.4    15.5   10.3         17.3    18.8   16.2
1978     29.3    15.7   1.0.8        33.4    19.8   13.2
Iran              1972      34.0    11.5   15.0
1976     15.2    17.6   L3.6
Pakistan          1975                                 20.0    11.0   27.0
1979                                 14.6     6.7    9.4
Philippines       1971                        8.5                        9.5
1977                       8.5                       16.0
South Korea       1967                9.0    5.0
1969              11.0    9.5
1971              14.6    9.3
1973              12.2    8.8
1980               8.1   11.7
Taiwan            1970               26.5   15.0                17.6   18.4
1972              12.3   17.7                 12.7   15.8
Thailand          1970      30.5    13.0   11.0
1972     63.2    30.9   18.4
Continued



Table A-1 (Continued)
Social                    Private
Country           Year      Prim.   Sec.   Hither    Prim.   Sec.  Higher
Latin America
Brazil            1970               23.5   13.1                24.7   13.9
1980
Colombia          1973                                                  20.7
1976                                                 24.9
Peru              1972      46.9    19.8   16.3
1974     34.3      9.0   15.0
1980     41.4      3.3   16.1
venezuela         1957      82.0    17.0   23.0                 18.0   27.0
1975     16.4    14.6   11.2         24.5    20.2   21.5
1984     17.5    10.5    8.7         24.3    12.4   15.0
OECD/Europe
Australia         1969                                          14.0   13.9
1976                                          8.1   21.1
Cyprus-1          1975                                 15.0    11.2   14.8
1979                                  8.6     8.1   14.1
1984                                 15.5     4.5   14.1
Cyprus-2          1975               10.5    9.7                11.6    8.6
1979               6.8    7.6                 7.0    5.6
Greece            1962                6.3   13.7                 7.2   14.0
1977               5.5    4.5                 6.0    5.5
France            1962                                 14.3    11.5    9.3
1969                                 16.2    12.0    9.6
1976                                 13.5    10.8    9.3
Germany           1964                                                   4.6
1978                                                 10.5
Continued



Table A-1 (Conltinued)
Social                    Private
Country           Year      Prim.   Sec.   Higher    Prim.   Sec.  Higher
OECD/Europe
Great Britain    1971                11.0    7.0                14.0   27.0
1972               3.6    8.2                11.7    9.6
1973               8.0    8.0                 6.0   16.0
1975               7.0    7.0                 9.0   22.0
1977               8.0    6.0                 9.0   17.0
1978               9.0    7.0                11.0   23.0
Japan             1967                                                 10.5
1973               4.6    6.4                 5.9    8.1
1976               8.6    6.9                10.4    8.8
1980                       5.7                        8.3
United States    1939                18.2   10.7                16.0   14.5
1949              14.2   10.6                14.5   10.1
1959              10.1   11.3                19.5   13.6
1969              10.7   10.9                18.8   15.4
1970                                         11.3    8.8
1971                                         12.5    8.0
1972                                         11.3    7.8
1973                                         12.0    5.5
1974                                         14.8    4.8
1975                                         12.8    5.3
1976                                         11.0    5.3
Source:   Unless stated otherwise, PsLcharopoulos (1985), Appendix
Table A-1. India 1952 and L960, Psacharopoulos (1987a),
Appendix. Venezuela 1975 andl 1984, Psacharopoulos and Steier
(1987). Cyprus 1984, DemetrLades and Psacharopoulos (1987).
United States, private rates, 1939, Becker (1975), p. 206;
1949, Hansen (1963), Table 5; 1959, Hines (1970).



Table A-2
The Coefficient on Years of Schooling:
Mincerian Rate of Return, by Year
Country                   Year                  Coefficient
(percent)
Asia
India                     1954                      9.4
1970                      6.7
1978                      7.4
1980                      9.7
Hong Kong                 1976                      6.3
1981                      6.1
Malaysia                  1970                     14.0
1978                     22.8
South Korea               1976                      6.5
1980                     11.1
Latin America
Brazil                    1970                     16.5
1980                     14.5
Chile                     1974                      8.3
1975                      9.8
1976                     10.0
1977                     11.3
1978                      8.6
1979                      8.8
1980                      9.6
Colombia                  1965                     17.3
1971                     16.7
1973                     17.6
1974                     12.8
1975                     15.4
1977                     14.4
1978                     14.4
1984                     11.0
Guatemala                 1975                     10.8
1977                     11.3
Venezuela                 1975                     13.7
1984                     11.2
Continued



Table A-2 (Continued)
The Coefficient on Years of Schooling:
Mincerian Rate of Return, by Year
Country                  Year                 Coefficient
(percent)
OECD/Europe
Canada                   1970                     7.8
1980                     8.6
Cyprus                   1975                    12.5
1979                     9.8
1981                     5.2
1984                    11.0
France                   1962                    16.3
1970                    19.2
1977                    15.4
Germany                  1974                    12.1
1977                    12.6
Greece                   1960                     9.2
1964                     8.6
1977                     5.8
United Kingdom           1972                     9.7
1975                     8.0
United States            1959                    10.7
1969                     7.8
1973                     8.2
Source:  Unless otherwise stated, Psacharopoulos (1985), Appendix
Table B.1. Brazil, Psacharopoulos (1987b). India,
Psacharopoulos (1987a), Appendix. Cyprus 1984,
Demetriades and Psacharopoulos (1987). Colombia, 1974
and 1984, Psacharopoulos, Arriagada and Velez (1987),
Table 4. Venezuela, Psacharopoulos and Steier (1987).
France, MiLngat and Jarousse (1986), Table 2. Canada
(Quebec), Shapiro and Stelener (1985), Tables Rl and AII
R-1.