WPS7946


Policy Research Working Paper                        7946




                              Death Scares
     How Potential Work-Migrants Infer Mortality Rates
                   from Migrant Deaths

                                Maheshwor Shrestha




Social Protection and Labor Global Practice Group
January 2017
Policy Research Working Paper 7946


  Abstract
 This paper studies how potential work migrants infer                                is stronger when there have been more migrant deaths in
 mortality rates from incidents of migrant deaths. In the                            recent months. Using relevant elasticities, this study finds
 context of migrant workers from Nepal to Malaysia and                               that the migration response implies large changes in mor-
 the Persian Gulf countries, the study finds that the death                          tality rates perceived by potential migrants. Models of
 of a migrant from a district lowers migration outflows in                           learning fallacies better explain the observed responses
 subsequent months. Furthermore, this migration response                             than a standard model of rational Bayesian learning.




  This paper is a product of the Social Protection and Labor Global Practice Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World
  Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world.
  Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted
  at mshrestha1@worldbank.org.




          The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
          issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
          names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
          of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
          its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.


                                                        Produced by the Research Support Team
    Death scares: How potential work-migrants infer mortality
                                  rates from migrant deaths
                                            Maheshwor Shrestha∗




      JEL Codes: F22, D83, O15, O12
      Keywords: Migration, The law of small numbers, Nepal


   ∗ The World Bank. Email: mshrestha1@worldbank.org. I am extremely grateful to my PhD advisers Esther Duflo,

Abhijit Banerjee, and Benjamin Olken for their advice and guidance throughout this project. I also thank David Autor,
Jie Bai, Seema Jayachandran, Tavneet Suri, Swarnim Wagle, and participants of the development and applied-micro
lunches at MIT for helpful discussions and feedback. I am grateful to the Department of Foreign Employment and
Foreign Employment Promotion Board in Nepal for providing me access to their database. This paper was written as
part of the dissertation submitted to the Department of Economics at MIT.
1       Introduction
Media reports abound on numbers of migrants dying on their way to the destination countries or
during their stay abroad. Within the first nine months of 2016, over 3,600 migrants have died in the
Mediterranean Sea while on their way to Europe (International Organization for Migration, 2015). In
2014, about 445 people died while trying to cross the US-Mexico border (Carroll, 2015). The large
death toll is not just the plight of those who try to migrate illegally or those who are forced to move.
The Guardian reports that almost 1,000 workers, all of whom were legal migrants from Nepal, India
and Bangladesh, died in Qatar in 2012 and 2013 (Gibson, 2014). Do potential migrants know the
mortality rate abroad and choose to migrate anyway? If not, how do they infer the mortality rate
from incidences of migrant death that they observe around them?
    Depending upon how they process the information, learning from observed deaths may lead to an
overestimate or an underestimate of the actual mortality rate. In this paper, I study how migration
decision is affected by the death of migrants in the context of Nepali work-migrants to Malaysia and
the Persian Gulf countries. I combine these estimates of migration responsiveness to death events,
along with the estimate of the value of statistical life (VSL) and elasticities from Shrestha (2017) to
infer how much each death changes a potential migrant’s perceived mortality rate abroad.
    If potential migrants have full information about the risk of death, or if they believe so, then their
decision to migrate will have already factored in the (perceived) probability of death during migration.
They will take realizations of death as conveying zero information and will not change their migration
decision in response to incidences of death.1 This presents a simple test of whether potential migrants
are fully informed about the risk of death upon migration: if migration decision responds to death
incidents, then potential migrants are not fully informed about the risk of death from migration.
    I find that death of a migrant worker significantly lowers migration. Specifically, I study the effect
of a migrant death in a district-destination cell on migration flows from the district in the subsequent
months. After controlling for potential confounds with district-destination fixed effects, district-month
fixed effects and destination-month fixed effects, one migrant death reduces monthly migrant flow from
that district to the same destination (as the deceased migrant) by 1.2 percent for up to a year after the
death. This clearly indicates that potential migrants do not consider themselves fully informed (and
rational) on the mortality risk abroad. I also find some increase in migrant flow from the district to
other destination countries. However, the amount of substitution to other destination does not fully
offset the negative effect. Overall, one migrant death (in any destination) in a district reduces total
monthly migration outflow from that district (to any destinations) by 0.9 percent for the subsequent
year.
    The size of the effect, even without considering the spillover effects on the neighboring districts, is
notably large. During the period of this study, 550 work migrants died annually, which led a reduction
in migrant flow of almost 18,000 individuals (from the districts of the deceased) over the period of
a year. The forgone income of this reduction is at least $57 million, which translates to 0.3 percent
of the average annual national GDP for that period.2 The forgone income, accounting for spillover
   1 With the obvious caveat that the deceased do not affect the ability of the potential migrants to undertake migration

(that is, the deceased are not family or close relatives).
   2 The forgone income includes the monetary cost of migration, but does not include any non-monetary cost of

migration. It also does not adjust for the cost of living abroad (which, in many cases, is already netted into the income).


                                                            2
effects amounts to 2.7 percent of the national GDP.
   The migration response to migrant death suggests that potential migrants update their beliefs
on mortality rate abroad after they observe a migrant death in their district. A rational Bayesian,
who believes that migrants deaths are generated by an i.i.d process, will also update their beliefs in
response to migrant deaths. However, for such a rational Bayesian, the sequencing of migrant deaths
in previous periods does not affect the extent of updating in response to a current signal. Contrary to
this prediction, the migration response to a migrant death in a district-destination cell is much larger
if there have been more deaths in the past 6 months in the cell. In fact, the migration response to
deaths is almost completely driven by district-destination cells that have experienced more than one
migrant death in the past 6 months. Interestingly, the migration response is not sensitive to changes
in the actual underlying death rates in the destination countries. This indicates that the updating
rule that potential migrants use to form their beliefs on mortality rate depends upon the sequencing
of migrant deaths in the recent past.
   This suggests that potential migrants are committing a fallacy in their updating behavior. One
possibility is that potential migrants are using some heuristic rule to form their beliefs (à la Kahneman
and Tversky, 1974; Tversky and Kahneman, 1973). It could be that they think recent deaths represent
the scenario more accurately, or that the past few months of migrant deaths is what is on the top
of their mind while making their migration decision. Another possibility, not necessarily mutually
exclusive, is that the potential migrants expect the probability rules to apply exactly even for the
‘small’ samples of migrants from a district (à la Tversky and Kahneman, 1971; Rabin, 2002). Indeed,
in his mathematical formulation of this fallacy, Rabin (2002) shows that such individuals, even when
they are Bayesian in updating their beliefs, tend to over-infer from short sequence of signals and
conclude that the true rate generating the sequence of signals to be more extreme than the truth. The
finding that the amount of updating, and hence the migration response, depends upon the number of
recent migrant deaths is consistent with Rabin’s prediction.
    Furthermore, I compute the change in perceived mortality risk for potential migrants following a
single death event to show that the amount of updating is, in fact, too high. Using the estimates
of earnings elasticity of migration from Shrestha (2017), I find that earnings need to go up by 15
percent to offset the migration response of a single death event. Further, using the estimate of the
VSL from the same study, I find that the change in earnings translates to an increase in perceived
two-year mortality rate of migration by 6.7 per thousand. This amount of updating from a single
migrant death in the district is too high relative to the true rate of 1.3 per thousand. It is also too
high compared to the updating behavior of a rational Bayesian, who believes the migrant deaths are
generated by an i.i.d binomial process.
   Moreover, this paper presents a context where fallacious learning, albeit about extreme and rare
events, could have large welfare costs. Many studies find migration to be welfare improving for the
marginal migrant and their family (see Bryan, Chowdhury, and Mobarak, 2014; McKenzie, Stillman,
and Gibson, 2010, for a few examples). These studies also find the levels of migration to be sub-
optimally low. This paper, through a stark example, shows how fallacious learning could potentially
lead to lower levels of migration.
   The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the migration process in



                                                   3
context of Nepal and the data sources, Section 3 outlines the empirical strategy, Section 4 discusses
the effect of migrant deaths on subsequent migrant flow, Section 5 calculates the change in perceived
mortality rate induced by the death and compares it with the updating behavior of a rational Bayesian,
and Section 6 concludes.


2     Context and Data
2.1     Migration from Nepal
Historically, migration of Nepali workers outside the country was low and was limited mostly to India.
As Table 1 shows, before 2001, the migrant-to-population ratio hovered slightly above 3 percent. This
was driven mostly by migration to India with which Nepal maintains an open border. The open
border between Nepal and India has historically allowed Nepali workers to migrate to Indian cities
for work for all or most part of the year. Migrating to other destinations for work has been, however,
quite restricted historically. Being recruited to the Indian or British army was one of the very few
options available to Nepali commoners to migrate abroad. Only since the mid-1990s, the Government
of Nepal allowed private recruitment of workers to certain countries upon clearance from the Ministry
of Labor.
    Work-related migration to destinations outside India surged after 2001. Between 2001 and 2011,
the share of non-India migrants exploded six-fold with only a small change in the share of India
migrants. This surge was driven by migration of Nepali workers, almost all male, to Malaysia and
the Persian Gulf countries, particularly Qatar, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, Bahrain, and
Kuwait. By 2011, these six countries alone hosted 0.9 million male Nepali workers, which is 83 percent
of all male migration from Nepal to destinations outside India.3 The outflow of male Nepali workers
had continued to increase in the recent years. Figure 1 shows that in 2013 alone, over 0.4 million
Nepali worker received permits from the Government of Nepal to work in these destination countries.
This number represents 7 percent of the adult working age (15-45) male population in the country.
    Consequently, Nepali workers became one of the largest suppliers of low-skill labor to these desti-
nation countries.4 In 2013, Nepali workers were 17 percent of the total population in Qatar, making it
the second largest population group behind Indian workers.5 Similarly, Nepali workers are expected to
be one of the largest minorities in other destination countries as well. As a result, remittance income
from abroad has become extremely important to the Nepali economy. Remittance income as a share
of national GDP increased from a mere 2.4 percent in 2001 to an overwhelming 32 percent by 2015
(The World Bank).
    Migration of Nepali workers to these destination countries is different from typical international
migration. Almost all of the migration is meant to be temporary. Work migrants to Malaysia usually
go with an employment contract for 3 years, and migrants to the Persian Gulf countries usually go
with an employment contract for 2 years. Their visa is always tied to work, and in many cases to a
   3 This figure includes those who migrated for non-work related reasons. The six countries account for over 90 percent

of all male migrants to non-India destinations who migrate specifically for work.
   4 An average migrant to these destinations has 7 years of schooling, and are 27 years old. Only 1 percent of them are

aged above 45.
   5 http://www.bqdoha.com/2013/12/population-qatar.




                                                           4
specific employer. Family members do not accompany the migrants unless they have a work-visa of
their own. It is rare for these migrants to settle permanently in the destination countries.
   The process of finding jobs in these destination countries is heavily intermediated. Potential mi-
grants typically contact (or are contacted by) independent local agents that link them to recruitment
firms, popularly known as “manpower companies”, in Kathmandu. These local agents are typically
fellow villagers with good contacts to the manpower companies and gather people for foreign employ-
ment from their own or neighboring villages. In addition, most of them also help potential migrants
obtain passports and other related travel documents. The manpower companies in Kathmandu receive
job vacancies from firms (or employment agencies) abroad. The manpower companies are responsible
for screening (if at all) and matching individuals with demands for workers from abroad, processing
contracts, obtaining medical clearances, arranging for travel, visa and other paperworks including
obtaining necessary clearances from the Department of Foreign Employment (DoFE) for employment
abroad.


2.2    Data on migration flows
The data on migration outflow comes from the Department of Foreign Employment (DoFE) that
keeps a record of permits issued for work abroad. DoFE, a department under the Ministry of Labor,
was established in December 2008 specifically to handle the processing and issuing of labor permits
for Nepali workers with an employment contract in these destination countries. As discussed above,
obtaining labor permits is mandatory for every work migrant from Nepal to these destination countries.
I have individual level data (without personal identifiers) on all these registered work-migrants from
2009 to 2013. I observe the date of permit, district of residence, destination country, age, gender,
contracted wages, fees paid, and occupation for each permit issued. I restrict my analysis to top 6
countries (Malaysia, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, Kuwait and Bahrain) that cover
more than 98 percent of all the permits issued by DoFE.
   The sample I use consists of 1.34 million permits issued from January 2009 to December 2013.
These migrants are predominantly male (98 percent) and quite young. Almost all migrants are aged
18-45 with an average age of 27 years. During this period, Malaysia led other countries as the most
popular destination choice with over 9,000 permits being issued every month. As Figure 2 shows,
outflow of migrants is increasing in recent years for most destinations. By 2013, over 1,100 migrants
were leaving the country per day with 40 percent going to Malaysia, 25 percent to Qatar and 20
percent to Saudi Arabia.
   I aggregate this data up to the level of district-destination-month cells by taking the counts of
migrants (for total outflow), and means for wages, fees and occupation choices. As Table 2 shows,
the average migrant outflow per district per month per destination is 50 (top panel, column 1). The
average reported monthly wage in the data is $230 with average fees paid to intermediaries of $580.
The average monthly wages rose from $200 in 2009 to $270 in 2013, which, combined with the rise
in US dollar exchange rate, led to an increase of 60 percent over the period (middle panel, columns 3
and 5). Similarly, fees charged fell (in Nepali rupees) by 18 percent over the duration (middle panel,
columns 4 and 5). A large share (53 percent) of the migrants reported their occupation as ‘labor’
which probably refers to manual work possibly in construction sectors. Since it is not possible to


                                                   5
classify these occupations properly, I define a category ‘non-construction’ that includes all jobs that
are definitely not in construction sector. The remaining jobs are either in construction or in other
sectors that are not classifiable. As Table 2 shows, only a third of the workers identified going to
work that can be classified as not being in the construction sector and there is a large variation across
destinations (column 6).
    Furthermore, the reported wages and fees from this source differ from the expectations of potential
workers. In Shrestha (2017), I find that potential work migrants expect to earn much higher while
abroad and pay much higher fees to migrate to these destinations. The discrepancy results from
misinformation in part of the potential migrants as well as misreporting from migrants to DoFE.
Migrants may misreport their wages and fees to DoFE as the government has regulations on minimum
wage and maximum fees for workers seeking employment abroad. Furthermore, the wages reported
to DoFE do not include overtime work, which can be a large part of migrant earnings abroad. In any
case, the wages reported here are contractual wages and potential migrants have to submit a copy of
the contract from the employer for their application to the DoFE.


2.3     Data on migrant deaths
The data on migrant deaths comes from the Foreign Employment Promotion Board (FEPB). FEPB
is a government body established to make foreign migration safe and organized. One of its main tasks
include providing financial support to the family of the deceased and helping them retrieve bodies of
the deceased workers. When a registered (received labor permits from DoFE) migrant worker dies
abroad, his family is eligible to receive a compensation (of over $1,500 for the study period) through the
FEPB. The FEPB provides compensation for any kind of death as long as the migrant had obtained
permits from DoFE, died within the duration of his contract, and the family files a claim within a
year of the date of death with necessary documents. The necessary documents would typically be
issued by local authorities after verifying that the claimant is indeed related to the deceased migrant
worker. This verification process may also aid in the transmission of the news of a migrant death in
addition to the word-of-mouth diffusion of news among potential migrants. The records at FEPB are
considered quite comprehensive counts of the death of registered migrant workers abroad.6
    The data used in this paper contains all such claims made with FEPB for deaths that occurred from
January 2009 to December 2013. For each deceased (anonymized), I observe the date of death, the
country of death, district of residence in Nepal and the cause of death reported in the death certificate.
Figure 3 shows the total number of deaths for every month in each of the major destination countries.
The figure shows an increase in the reported number of deaths in most destinations akin to the
increase in migrant outflow. Because migrant deaths are rare events, the numbers look sporadic for
countries with smaller migrant flows, and therefore a small migrant stock. I aggregate this data up to
the district-destination-month cell for analysis. Each district-destination cell experienced 0.1 deaths
in a month, with the variation across destinations resembling the migrant stocks in the destination
countries (Column 2, Table 2).
    Though considered an accurate source of information on the number of migrant deaths, this data
   6 Note that it is not the complete census of all deaths of Nepali workers abroad as it relies on the claims made by the
family of the deceased.



                                                            6
source is not suitable for analyzing effects by cause of death. The cause of death in the FEPB database
is the official cause of death listed in their death certificate issued in the destination countries. The
causes of death might have been tampered with to avoid insurance and other hassles (legal hassle for
employers, detailed medical procedure to determine the exact causes, delays in dead body repatriation
for the family of the deceased). The prevalence and variance of ‘natural’ cause of death of adult young
male across different destinations is an evidence of the dubious quality of information on the cause
of death of Nepali migrant workers (Figure 4). Hence, I do not pursue any analysis on the cause of
death.
    The data suggest very low and fairly constant mortality rate of Nepali workers abroad. I compute
death rate by using the counts from the FEPB database and estimated migrant stock in each month
in the destination countries. To estimate the migrant stock, I assume that migrants to the Persian
Gulf countries return after 2 years and migrants to Malaysia return after 2.5 years. Using this rule
in migrant outflow database from DoFE, I obtain net flow of migrants to each destination in each
month. The census of 2011 provides a snapshot of the migrant stock for June of 2011 in each of these
destinations. This, along with the net flow of migrants provides an estimate of the migrant stock in
each destination for each month.7 The estimated overall two-year mortality rate is 1.3 per thousand
migrant workers in 2013, which is slightly higher than the rate of 1.16 per thousand worker in 2010.8
Though the estimated magnitude of the rate is slightly higher in 2013 compared to 2010, the plot of
smoothened death rates suggests that migrant death rates remained fairly constant throughout the
study period (Figure 5). The figure also shows that death rates in Malaysia and Saudi Arabia are
slightly higher than death rates in Qatar and the UAE.


3     Empirical strategy
I use a triple difference estimator to estimate the effect of death of a particular individual from origin
district o in destination country d in month t in the outflow of migrants (and other outcomes) from
the district to the same destination in the months following month t. In an event study framework, I
estimate

                                                                12
                                 yodt = αod + γot + ξtd +              τi Dod,t−i + εodt                             (1)
                                                               i=−12

where yodt is the outcome for origin (district)- destination (country) cell at time (in months) t measured
in months. Dod,t−i is a dummy variable which indicator whether anyone from the district o died in
destination d at time t − i. The coefficients τi s are normalized so that it is zero at time t − 1. αod
captures origin-destination fixed effects, γot captures time (monthly) fixed effects for each district, and
ξtd captures destination country specific time fixed effects. I cluster standard errors at the district
level allowing for arbitrary correlation in errors terms across months and destinations for a district.
    7 This estimation assumes that no workers return before the expiration of their contract, or over-stay their contract

illegally. Since it is impossible to get the data on such incidences, I make no adjustments for them. The effects of such
irregularities in the stock of migrants, and hence the death rates, are likely to be negligible.
    8 To keep this rate in perspective, the two-year mortality rate of Nepali men in Nepal with the same age distribution

as this sample is 4.6 per thousand. The two-year mortality rate of US men with the same age distribution is 2.8 per
thousand.


                                                           7
   Note that this estimation only uses data for o − d cells in month t if there has been at least one
death in the o − d cell in the 12 months surrounding time t. Further, if the o − d cell in month
t has multiple deaths in the 12 months surrounding month t, then each o − d − t observation will
appear multiple times. That is, this specification will over-weight the o − d cells with larger number
of migrants deaths.
   Alternatively, I estimate


                                 yodt,x = βDodt + αod + γot + ξdt + εodt                               (2)

which has identical sets of fixed effects and yodt,x captures the outcome y for origin district - destination
country cell for the next x months after month t. Dodt indicates whether there was a death event in
origin-destination cell in month t. Note that this specification uses all o − d cells for each of month
without over-weighting any particular cell.
   Essentially, β from this specification averages the τi from Equation (1) for i < 0 for x periods in
the populations. As there are no pre-trends in the outcome (which I show in the following section),
this specification identifies the same effect as equation (1). However, since these specifications use a
slightly different transformation of the dataset, the estimated results are slightly different. I use the
event study specification to describe the result in a figure, and use results from Equation (1) for further
calculations and heterogeneity analysis. In both of these specifications, the identifying assumption
is that the deaths are uncorrelated with other determinants of migration (or other outcomes) after
controlling for all the two-way fixed effects.
   Equation (2) allows a natural way to extend the specification to explore heterogeneity of the effects
of migrant death. To explore the heterogeneity by a characteristic X , I simply estimate

                   yodt,x = βDodt + δ (Dodt × Xodt ) + ζXodt + αod + γot + ξdt + εodt                  (3)

Here, δ denotes the marginal increase in the effect of death on outcome y with an increase in charac-
teristics X .
   In all these specifications, the identifying variation is the same and comes from three sources.
Within each origin-destination cell, the variation comes from different months having different number
of migrant deaths. Within each origin-month cell, the variation comes from different destination
countries having different number of deaths. Within each destination-month cell, the variation comes
from different districts having different numbers of deaths. All other sources of variations are subsumed
by the fixed effects.
   Though Equation (2) can be used to estimate the effects of death on migration flows to the same
destination, as well as other destinations, it is not straightforward to compute the net effect of deaths
on migration. To directly estimate the overall effect of deaths on migration (irrespective of destination
countries), I estimate
                                      yot,x = βDot + αo + γt + νot                                     (4)

where yot,x represents the migration flow measure from district o in the x months following month t,
Dot is the number of deaths of migrants from district o that occurred in month t, αo and γt represent
the district and month fixed effects and νot represents the error term. I allow for arbitrary correlation


                                                    8
in error terms between any two periods for a district. To explore heterogeneity, I estimate


                          yot,x = βDot + δ (Dot × Xot ) + ζXot + αo + γt + νot                         (5)

where Xot represents the variable of interest.


4     Results and discussion
In this section, I present the results of estimating the equations on various measures of migration, prices
and job composition. The first part of this section tests whether potential migrants are fully informed
about migrant death rate by examining the impact of death incidences on subsequent migration flows.
The second part of this section checks whether prices and job composition responds locally following
a migrant death. Note that these changes are local and will only capture changes in prices and
job composition within origin district-destination cells. The third part of this section tests whether
potential migrants understand that the migrant deaths are generated by an i.i.d process.
   Recent migrant deaths in the origin district- destination cell matter in how responsive potential
migrants are to a current migrant death. A change in responsiveness based on recent death rules out
some hypotheses. In particular, it rules out that potential migrants are Bayesian who believe that
migrant deaths are generated by an i.i.d process.


4.1    Does migrant death affect subsequent migration flows?
The event study specification shows that migrant death in an origin district - destination cell suppresses
migration flow in the same cell in the subsequent months (Figure 6, top left plot). I cannot reject
the null that migration flows in the cell do not exhibit a trend in the months preceding the death
event. As the plot shows, migration flow starts to drop after the migrant death. In particular, the
drop becomes large after 3 months and continues to stay low even 12 months after the death. The lag
could be a result of the delay it takes for the information about migrant death to spread, or because
the news may not be effective in changing the migration decision of those who have already made all
the preparations and investments to migrate.
    There is also evidence of some substitution to other destinations following migrant death in an
origin district - destination cell (Figure 6, top right plot). Here as well, I cannot reject the null that
migration flows to destinations other than that of migrant death do not exhibit a trend in months
preceding the death. As the plot shows, migration flows to other destinations start to rise after the
migrant death. The magnitude of these effects (expressed in logarithm of migration outflow per district
per destination per month) in this case are, however, lower than the effect on the same destination.
    Migrant death in a district has spillover effects to neighboring districts (Figure 6, bottom two
plots). The migration flows in neighboring districts (expressed in logarithm of flow per district per
destination per month) respond in similar way to a migrant death in an origin district - destination
cell. That is, in response to a migrant death in an origin district - destination cell, migrant flows from
neighboring districts to the same destination fall and migration flows from neighboring districts to
other destinations slightly increase.


                                                    9
    The estimates of these effects using Equation (2) show similar results. Consistent with the event
study plots, Table 3 shows that in response to every migrant death, the average monthly migration
outflow in the origin district- destination cell falls by 1.2 percent for the subsequent 6 to 12 months (top
panel, columns 1, 2, and 3). Similarly, the average monthly migration outflows to other destinations
increase by 0.2 to 0.3 percent for every migrant death in a cell for the subsequent 6 to 12 months
(columns 4, 5, and 6). This indicates that, as corroborated by event study plots, potential migrants
substitute to other destinations. The second and third panels of the table show smaller but significant
spillover to neighboring districts as well. The spillovers are limited to districts close to the district
of migrant death. Migrant deaths in an origin district - destination cell have no effects on migration
outflows from districts that are far (bottom panel, Table 3).
    However, the increase in migration flow to other destinations does not fully offset the negative effect
in the same origin district - destination cell. Table 4 shows that total migration from the district falls
by 0.9 to 1.2 percent in the subsequent 6 to 12 months for every migrant death in the district (top
panel, columns 1, 2, and 3). There are large spillovers of migrant death to the neighboring district,
but the spillover is limited to immediate neighbors only. Migrant death does not have significant
impact on the migration outflows from districts that are further away (bottom two panels).
    The estimated effects are quite large and of significant consequence to the nation. During the
period of analysis, the total monthly outflow of migrants from each district was 300. The total effect
of 0.9 percent reduction for 12 months means 32.4 fewer migrants migrate over a year after the death
of a single migrant from this district. If these individuals had migrated, they would have earned at
least $6,100 on the net from a migration episode that lasts 2.21 years.9 I assume that if they stayed
back, they would earn $2,900 in 2.21 years, which is the average income per employed male.10 With
these assumptions, a single death represents a loss of $0.1 million in forgone earnings over the 2.21 year
long migration episode. Accounting for spillover effects of the death to neighboring districts makes
this figure as large as $0.8 million. During the period of the study, an average of 550 migrant workers
died annually. This led to a total forgone income of $57 million ($460 million with spillover) which
translates to 0.3 percent (2.7 percent with spillover) of the average annual GDP for this period.11
Note that, however, these calculations do not adjust for cost of living without migration, or for other
monetary and other costs associated with migration.


4.2     Effect of death on job composition and prices
If migrant death makes potential migrants believe that a particular job category is more risky than
others, then they may respond by changing the jobs for which they migrate. Additionally, intermedi-
aries may anticipate this and offer potential migrants less risky jobs in response to a migrant death.
However, this does not seem to be the case. The event study plots in Figure 7 confirm this (top and
bottom plots in third column). For both the plots, I cannot reject the null that all effects before the
   9 This estimate is half of the net earnings (net of migration fees) inexperienced potential migrants expect to make

from a migration episode lasting 2.21 years (Shrestha, 2017). I take half of the earnings to account for two major effects:
misinformation and cost of living abroad that is not factored into the net earnings. In Shrestha (2017), I show that
misinformation is at least 26 percent. In The World Bank (2011), returnees from these destinations mentioned that
they saved 75 percent of their earnings. Hence, half of the net earnings is a conservative estimate of migrant income.
  10 Author’s calculations from the Nepal Living Standards Survey-III, of 2010.
  11 GDP figures taken from The World Bank.




                                                           10
death and after the death are zero. As Table 5 shows, the estimated magnitudes of the effects are
very small (top panel). These are, indeed, precisely estimated zero effects.
    Another way in which intermediaries could respond to a migrant death is by offering potential
migrants higher wages (if they can) or lowering their recruitment fees. Note that any changes in
wages or contracts offered by the employer abroad will not be captured by the specification. Since the
employers leave it to the intermediaries to select the workers within the country, any wage response
they make to the laborers in response to the death of their workers will be subsumed by the destination-
month fixed effects. Hence, if this specification finds an effect, it will be capturing the response by the
intermediaries who may be able to vary the net benefit of migration locally in response to a migrant
deaths, or change the wages and recruitment fees to entice potential migrants.
    There is no evidence of wages and fees changing in response to the migrant death. Figure 7
confirms this (top and bottom plots in the first two columns). For all the plots, I cannot to reject the
null that all effects before the death and after the deaths are zero. As Table 5 shows, the estimated
magnitudes of the effects are precisely estimated zero effects.12
    This suggests that the migration response to migrant death is not mediated by compensating
changes in wages and cost of migration. Therefore, the migration impact of migrant death is a result
of a shift in the migrant supply at a constant price. The shift in migrant supply is caused by the
changed perceptions among potential migrants about the mortality rate abroad.


4.3       Does recent history of migrant deaths matter?
The effect of a migrant death in changing migration decision in Section 4.1 shows that potential
migrants are not fully aware of the mortality rate in the destination country. One class of explanations
is that potential migrants are committing some sort of fallacy by responding to migrant deaths, another
class of explanations is that potential migrants are uninformed about the underlying death rates and
are learning about about it from the realizations of migrant deaths in their districts. The latter
explanation presumes that potential migrants understand the underlying data generation process and
treat realized deaths as i.i.d signals from this process. If potential migrants believe that migrant deaths
are i.i.d signals generated by an underlying data generation process, then their updating behavior
would only depend upon the signal that they receive at every period and not on the distribution of
signals in the recent past. That is, the migration response to migrant death should not depend upon
the number of deaths that have happened in the district in the recent past.
    However, I find evidence that migration response to a current death depends upon realizations of
migrant deaths in the recent past. Table 6 shows that when there have been no deaths in the past six
months in the origin district - destination cell, the migration flow does not respond significantly to a
current migrant death in the cell (top panel, columns 1, 3, and 5). If anything, the point estimate of
the response is positive. But for every additional migrant death in the cell in the past six months, the
effect of a current death in the cell on the migration flows falls by 0.5 to 0.6 percentage points. Put
it differently, if there has been one or fewer deaths in the origin district - destination cell in the past
 12 The   small magnitude of the effect rules out some of the concerns on quality of data on wages and fees. If the
discrepancy in reported wages and actual wages can be modeled by measurement error, then the misreporting only
leads to increased imprecision of the estimates. The same applies for fees as well. The estimated coefficients have both
small magnitude as well as small standard errors.



                                                         11
six months, a current death in the cell does not affect migration flow. But, if there have been more
than one migrant deaths in the cell, death in the current month reduces migration flows in the cell
by about 3.2 to 3 percent for the subsequent 6 to 12 months (top panel, columns 2, 4, and 6). That
is, the entire effect of migrant death on migrant flows is driven by origin district - destination cells
which have experienced more than 1 migrant death in the past 6 months.
   Note that these effects are observed even after controlling for the response to changes in actual
death rates in the destinations. As Table 6 shows, change in actual underlying death rates in desti-
nation countries, however, does not affect how migration flow responds to current death (top panel,
third interaction term).
   The interaction of the effects with recent deaths persists for migration to other destinations, as
well as to migration from neighboring districts, but are estimated less precisely (Table 6, middle and
bottom panel). As the table shows, migration responses to deaths are larger when there have been
more deaths in the recent six months although not all coefficients are statistically different from zero.
Note that, in particular, the interaction coefficients for migration flows to other destinations are as
large as the overall effects in Table 3.
   Table 7 shows that the interactions with recent deaths are important for effects on migration from
the district as a whole. The table shows that in districts where 3 or fewer deaths occurred in the past
six months, a current death does not change migration outflows. But if there have been more than
3 migrants death in the districts, then the migration flow falls by an additional 2 to 2.2 percentage
points (top panel). The interaction effect is, however, limited to the same district as the migrant
death (middle and bottom panel).
   The evidence presented here suggests that potential migrants do not respond to migrant death as
if it was generated by an i.i.d process. Most importantly, the clustering of the deaths seems to matter
in the way they respond to migrant death. They respond to a migrant death more strongly when
there have been more recent deaths. This suggests that potential migrants are committing a fallacy
in the way they update their beliefs about the mortality rate abroad.
    One fallacy that generates an update rule that depends on the sequencing of signals is the law of
‘small’ numbers (as coined by Tversky and Kahneman, 1971). Here, individuals fallaciously update
their beliefs because they expect the probability rules to hold exactly even in ‘small’ samples. The
context of this study is aptly suited for individuals to commit this fallacy. Potential migrants do not
know the underlying mortality rate and have to infer it from the migrant death that they observe.
But since death rates are very small, the sample size needed to accurately estimate death rate from
incidences is large. Potential migrants may not have access to a large number of migrants to make this
inference, or have the patience to observe the sample at their disposal for a long duration. Therefore,
they are likely to make inference based on the sample at their disposal and the migrants deaths that
they observe, and hence commit the fallacy of believing in the law of ‘small’ numbers.
   In his mathematical formulation of this fallacy, Rabin (2002) shows that such individuals, even
when they are Bayesian in their updating rule, tend to over-infer from short sequences of signals.
Therefore, they tend to conclude that the true rate generating the sequence of signals is more extreme
than it actually is. In the current context, when they observe many migrant deaths in the recent
months, potential migrants are likely to believe that the underlying mortality rate is much larger than



                                                  12
it actually is. To check that potential migrants are indeed over-inferring from the sequences of migrant
death, in the next section, I compute the change in perceived mortality rate implied by the migration
effect and compare it with the change in the mortality rate of a Bayesian who does not commit this
fallacy.


5       Over-inference of mortality rate
In the first part of this section, I calculate the implied change in perceived mortality rate in response
to a migrant death using estimates of earnings elasticity and the value of statistical life (VSL) from
my companion paper (Shrestha, 2017). In the second part, I present a simple learning model of a
Bayesian who believes that migrant deaths every month are generated by an i.i.d binomial process
and computes his level of updating in response to migrant deaths. I compare these two estimates to
show that potential migrants update a lot more in response to a death than the model.


5.1        Computing the implied change in perceived mortality rate caused by
           migrant death
                                                    ∂ log M
In Section 4.1, I present the estimates of β =         ∂D ,   the effect of a migrant death D, on migration
flows M . Each death reduces migrant flow from a district by 0.9 percent for 12 months. This represents
a total of 11 percent reduction in monthly migrant flow (albeit over a year) in response to a single
migrant death. I then calculate a one-time increase in migrant earnings necessary to induce the same
number of potential migrants to migrate so that the net effect on migration is zero. Since the earnings
                               ∂ log M
elasticity of migration, ε =   ∂ log W ,   the earnings increase necessary to offset the migration effect is
given by:
                                                         β
                                                 ∆W =      ·W
                                                         ε
      A simple thought experiment behind this calculation is as follows: First, shock a district with a
death of a migrant in a particular month. This will lead to a reduction in migration flows from the
district for the next 12 months. At the same time, shock the district with a one-time increase in
expected migrant earnings for all those who migrate in that month in such a way that it induces the
same number of migrants as had been dissuaded by the migrant death. The equation above provides
with precisely the amount of such earnings shock necessary to compensate the district for the fall in
migrant flow induced by the migrant death.
      Finally, I use the estimate of the VSL to translate the earnings response to change in perceived
                                                                         ∆d
mortality rate. I use the discretized definition of the VSL, V SL =       ∆W   , and the formula above to do
so.
                                               ∆W       1     1
                                       ∆d =         =      ·β· ·W                                       (6)
                                               V SL   V SL    ε
where d represents the perceived probability of death and W will be the average potential earnings
from migration.
      I use the earnings elasticity and the VSL estimates from Shrestha (2017) for this calculation. In
that study, I randomly assign information on earnings and mortality to potential migrants without



                                                       13
prior migration experience and observe how they affect their expectations on earnings and mortality
rate as well as their migration choices. I then use the information assignments as an instrument that
moves these expectations on a binary choice model of migration decision. The estimated earnings
elasticity of migration is 0.7 and the elasticity of migration with respect to expected mortality of 0.5.
I calculate the VSL as the trade-off the inexperienced potential migrants are willing to make between
expected earnings and expected mortality. The (preferred) estimate of the VSL from the study is
$0.28 million.
    With these estimates, I find a large increase in perceived mortality rate following a single migrant
death. The earnings elasticity of 0.7 implies that earnings need to go up by 15 percent to offset the
reduction in migrant flow following a migrant death.13 Using the $0.28 million estimate of the VSL,
I find that the change in perceived mortality rate following one migrant death in the district is 6.7
per thousand during a two-year migration episode.14 This level of updating of beliefs in response to
a single migrant death is quite large. In particular, the increase in perceived mortality rate is more
than 5 times the actual mortality rate of 1.3 per thousand.15


5.2     How much would a rational (i.i.d) Bayesian update?
In this part, I outline a simple model of learning from migrant death. In this model, individuals are
Bayesian who believe that deaths are generated by an underlying i.i.d process. Specifically, they believe
that the number of migrant death in their district every month is generated by a binomial distribution
B (N, p) where N is the stock of migrants abroad and p is the true but unknown mortality rate. For
purposes of simplicity, I assume that N is fixed and remains the same every period. Individuals’ priors
follow a beta distribution, B (a0 , b0 ) where a0 and b0 are the parameters of this distribution. Given
the binomial signal generating process, the priors a0 and b0 have the interpretation of their prior
exposure to migrant deaths, and migrant survivals respectively before the Bayesian learning begins.
As I assume a fixed stock of migrants, this simplifies to b0 = N − a0 with the prior expectation of
                     a0
mortality rate of    N.
    In each period, indicated by t, individuals observe the number of migrant deaths in their district, st ,
which is drawn from the binomial distribution. In period 1, after they observe s1 , their posterior belief
on the mortality rate follows a beta distribution given by B (a0 + s1 , N − a0 + N − s1 ). In general, in
period n, after observing s1 , s2 , · · · , sn , their posterior distribution follows a beta distribution given
  13 As a robustness exercise, in Online Appendix A, I estimate earnings elasticity of migration using the same data

as this study on migrant flow and wages. I use the relative exchange rate between other destination countries and
Malaysia as an instrument that changes relative wages between other destinations and Malaysia. As Table A.1 shows,
the point estimate of the elasticity in the top 6 destinations is 1.2, which is, in fact, slightly larger than the estimate
from Shrestha (2017). I use the estimate from the experiment as it has better identification due to the experimental
setup.
  14 Assuming that each component of equation (6) is normally distributed with the estimated mean and variances, and

also that these components are uncorrelated with each other, the standard error for this estimate is 3.72.
   The calculation using alternative estimates of VSL from Shrestha (2017) of $0.538m and elasticities of 0.7 from
Shrestha (2017) and 1.2 from Online Appendix A produce estimates of ∆d ranging from 2.1 to 6.7 per thousand, quite
similar to each other.
  15 Alternatively, one could directly use the experimental estimate of elasticity of migration to perceived mortality rate

from Shrestha (2017) to convert migration effects to induced change in perceived mortality rate. This method would
not need the estimates for VSL and earnings elasticity of migration. This method also yields estimates of ∆d between
3.7 and 5.9 per thousand, quite similar to the estimates discussed above. I present estimates using Equation (6) as it
allows using alternative estimates of earnings elasticity to check robustness (as in the Online Appendix).



                                                            14
by
                                                   n                           n
                                    B a0 +             st , (n + 1) N − a0 −         st
                                               t=1                             i=1
                                               n
                                       a0 +       st
with expected mortality rate of           (n+1)N .
                                              t=1
                                                         Note that when the number of periods, n, is large, the
expected mortality rate limits to the true mortality rate p.
     This model gives a simple prediction on the relationship between the signal at time t, st , and their
posterior belief after time t. A regression of their posterior beliefs and the signal in period t produces
an estimated coefficient of β  ˆt =    1
                                  (t+1)N . The same relationship holds for all periods t from 1 through
n. Therefore, a regression of their posterior beliefs and the signal in all periods produces an estimated
coefficient given by

                                           n               n
                                  ˆ= 1        ˆt = 1                1       Hn+1 − 1
                                  β           β                           =
                                     n    t=1
                                                   n      t=1
                                                                (t + 1) N     nN

where Hk represents the k -th Harmonic number. Note that the estimated coefficient falls with the
size of migrant stock N and the period of observation n (at large levels of n).16
     The amount of updating under this model is small relative to the estimates of actual updating
done by potential migrants. In the study, we observe the each district for 60 periods. A district had an
average of 13,300 migrants during the period of this study. Plugging these numbers into the formula
above yields a coefficient that translates to a two-year mortality rate of 0.111 per thousand migrants.
The actual estimated updating of 6.7 per thousand is 60 times this number. Even when we allow
individuals to update based on 6 months of data on migrant deaths, this model predicts a coefficient
of 0.479 per thousand migrants, only seven percent of the actual updating. The largest amount of
updating this model can generate is when individuals observe only one month of signal. Even this
method only generates a coefficient of 0.9, which is only 13 percent of the actual updating observed
in the data.
     This exercise emphasizes a few features of the way in which potential migrants update their beliefs
on mortality rate following a migrant death. First, potential migrants update too much. The amount
of updating that they do is 60 times higher than what a rational Bayesian who assumes that deaths
are generated by an i.i.d process does. Simple explanations along the lines of potential migrants only
using a few months of data to form their beliefs does not suffice on its own. The observed level of
updating is much higher than a rational Bayesian using only one month of migrant deaths to form
their posterior. Allowing potential migrants to be misinformed about the stock of migrants could
generate such large response. But with n = 60, rational Bayesian must assume that the stock of
migrants from their district is only 220 in order to generate the observed size of the effect. Even with
n = 6, that the rational Bayesian only observes past 6 months of deaths in their district, they must
assume that the stock of migrants from their district is only 950. Both these numbers seem too small
given the prevalence of migration in the country.
     Furthermore, the rational Bayesian model does not match another key aspect of the updating
process: that the sequencing of migrant deaths matters in their inference. This feature rules out other
 16 At   large values of x, Hx = γ + log (x) where γ is some constant (Euler-Mascheroni constant).




                                                               15
explanations of the over-inference that involves potential migrants simply assigning larger decision
weights to small probabilities (as in Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). The law of ‘small’ numbers
explanation qualitatively matches both aspects of the observed learning process. As proposed by
Rabin (2002), I find that potential migrants do over-infer from migrant deaths, and they update
differently when there has been too many or too few deaths (a streak of similar signals) in the recent
past. This, however, is not to claim that other channels are not at all at play. For instance, it could
be possible that one or many of the channels discussed here are at play in conjunction with the belief
in the law of ‘small’ numbers. For example, they only observe migrant deaths of the past few months
to form their beliefs and also believe in the law of ‘small’ numbers. A combination such as this could
explain the large sensitivity to migrant deaths that we observe in the data.
    The expected mortality rate expressed by potential migrants in Shrestha (2017) is consistent with
these explanations. The inexperienced potential migrants expect the mortality rate to be 27.6 per
thousand for a two-year migration episode. From the estimates above, they only need 4.1 deaths in
their district to generate this level of expected mortality rate starting form a prior of zero mortality
rate. In 2013, an average district experienced 4.3 deaths in 5 months, suggesting that such high level of
mortality perception can be generated even if potential migrants are making decisions about mortality
risks only based on past five months of migrant mortality incidences in their districts. Hence, the
belief held by inexperienced potential migrants is consistent with an updating behavior where they
only look at a few months of migrant deaths and believe in the law of ‘small’ numbers to form their
beliefs.


6     Conclusion
This paper demonstrates two key features of how potential migrants form their beliefs on the mortality
rate abroad from migrant deaths. First, their response is large. A single migrant death in a origin
district - destination cell reduces migration flow by 1.2 percent for 12 subsequent months. After
accounting for the substitution to other destination countries, a single migrant death in the district
reduces migration flow from the district by 0.9 percent for 12 subsequent months. This translates to
an increase in their perceived mortality rate of 6.7 per thousand for a two-year migration episode. The
amount of updating alone is 5 times the actual mortality rate. In addition, the amount of updating
is several times larger than the updating of a rational Bayesian who believes that migrant deaths are
generated by an i.i.d binomial process. The second crucial feature is that the response depends upon
the recent history of migrant deaths in the district. If there have been no (or very few) deaths in the
recent past, migrant death in the current period has no effect on the subsequent migration. However,
if there have been more deaths in the recent past, migrant death in the current period has larger
effect on the subsequent migration. In fact, the large response to migrant deaths is almost completely
driven by cells in which there have been more deaths in the recent past.
    These two features are consistent with a model of belief updating where potential migrants commit
a fallacy of believing in the law of ‘small’ numbers. As Rabin (2002) shows, such individuals, when
they encounter a streak in signals, such as no deaths in the past 6 months or too many deaths in the
past 6 months, erroneously believe that the deaths are generated by a more extreme underlying rate


                                                   16
than the truth. As discussed above, the data matches both the over-inference result as well as the
dependence of updating behavior on the sequence of signals.
   This paper finds that the belief on mortality rate expressed by inexperienced potential migrants
in Shrestha (2017) is consistent with their experience and their updating behavior. A suggested
explanation for the high expected mortality is that the potential migrants observe migrant deaths in
their own district for a few months to form their priors, but at the same time they commit the fallacy
of the law of ‘small’ numbers which leads them to over-infer from the migrant deaths that they see.
   Finally, this paper presents a real world setting in which a learning fallacy can have large welfare
consequences for potential migrants. Incidences of deaths, which should convey zero information to a
fully informed potential migrant, seems to thwart migration substantially. Policies designed to make
individuals less ‘scared’ of migrant deaths abroad could potentially have large welfare effects.




                                                  17
References
Bertrand, M., E. Duflo, and S. Mullainathan (2004): “How much should we trust differences-
 in-differences estimates?,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), 249–275.

Bryan, G., S. Chowdhury, and A. M. Mobarak (2014): “Underinvestment in a profitable tech-
 nology: The case of seasonal migration in Bangladesh,” Econometrica, 82(5), 1671–1748.
Carroll, R. (2015): “Bodies at the border: ‘Many Mexicans have no option. This flow will not
 cease’,” The Guardian.

Gibson, O. (2014): “Qatar government admits almost 1,000 fatalities among migrants,” The
 Guardian.
International Organization for Migration (2015): “Missing Migrants Project,” .
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky (1974): “Subjective probability: A judgment of representative-
 ness,” in The Concept of Probability in Psychological Experiments, pp. 25–48. Springer.

        (1979): “Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk,” Econometrica, 17(2), 263–291.
McKenzie, D., S. Stillman, and J. Gibson (2010): “How important is selection? Experimental vs
 non-experimental measures of the income gains from migration,” Journal of the European Economic
 Association, 8(4), 913–945.

Rabin, M. (2002): “Inference by believers in the law of small numbers,” Quarterly Journal of Eco-
 nomics, 117(3), 775–816.
Shrestha, M. (2017): “Get rich or die tryin’: Perceived earnings, perceived mortality rate and
  the value of a statistical life of potential work-migrants from Nepal,” World Bank Policy Research
  Working Paper Series WPS7945, The World Bank.

The World Bank, . (2011): “Large-scale migration and remittance in Nepal: Issues, challenges and
 opportunities,” Discussion Paper 55390-NP, The World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic
 Management Sector Unit, South Asia Region.
         (2016): “World Development Indicators,” .

Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman (1971): “Belief in the law of small numbers,” Psychological
 Bulletin, 76(2), 105.
         (1973): “Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability,” Cognitive Psychol-
  ogy, 5(2), 207–232.




                                                 18
Figures and Tables
Figures


                                            Figure 1: Permits granted by DoFE for work abroad
                       400     300
            Total outflow in '000
                  200  100
                       0




                                     2005    2006      2007   2008    2009   2010     2011      2012   2013

                                            Malaysia            Qatar               S. Arabia           UAE
                                            Kuwait              Bahrain             Others

Source: Author’s calculation on the data provided by Department of Foreign Employment (DoFE).
Note: This figure shows the number of work-permits issued by DoFE for work abroad by year and destination country.




                                                                     19
                                                  Figure 2: Total permits issued by DoFE for top destination countries

                                                             Malaysia                       Qatar                      Saudi Arabia




                                                                                                             10
                                                  20




                                                                               10
                                                  15




                                                                                                             5
                                                  10




                                                                               5
                   Monthly permits issued, '000
                                                  5
                                                  0




                                                                               0




                                                                                                             0
                                                    2009m1   2011m1   2013m1     2009m1   2011m1    2013m1    2009m1    2011m1     2013m1

                                                               UAE                         Kuwait                        Bahrain




                                                                               1.5
                                                  6




                                                                                                             .4
                                                                                                             .3
                                                  4




                                                                               1




                                                                                                             .2
                                                                               .5
                                                  2




                                                                                                             .1
                                                  0




                                                                               0




                                                                                                             0
                                                    2009m1   2011m1   2013m1     2009m1   2011m1    2013m1    2009m1    2011m1     2013m1



Source: Author’s calculations from DoFE database
Note: This figure shows the number of work permits issued every month for the period of the study (2009-2013) to the top six
destination countries. This does not include migration flows to India.




                                                                Figure 3: Monthly deaths in top destinations

                                                             Malaysia                       Qatar                      Saudi Arabia
                                                                                                             25
                                                  30




                                                                               20




                                                                                                             20
                                                                               15
                                                  20




                                                                                                             15
                                                                               10
                                                  10




                                                                                                             10
                   Total deaths per month




                                                                               5




                                                                                                             5
                                                  0




                                                    2009m1   2011m1   2013m1     2009m1   2011m1    2013m1    2009m1    2011m1     2013m1

                                                               UAE                         Kuwait                        Bahrain
                                                                               8




                                                                                                             3
                                                  10




                                                                               6




                                                                                                             2
                                                                               4
                                                  5




                                                                                                             1
                                                                               2
                                                  0




                                                                               0




                                                                                                             0




                                                    2009m1   2011m1   2013m1     2009m1   2011m1    2013m1    2009m1    2011m1     2013m1



Source: Author’s calculations from FEPB database
Note: This figure shows the number of deaths of registered Nepali migrants every month for the period of the study (2009-2013).




                                                                                          20
                                                          Figure 4: Official cause of migrant deaths by destination




                   1
                   .8
                   .6
                   .4
                   .2
                   0




                                                     Malaysia       Qatar    Saudi Arabia      UAE      Kuwait     Bahrain

                                                             MA/Cardiac arrest       Natural         Traffic acc      Suicide
                                                             Workplace acc           Murder          Other


Source: Author’s calculations from FEPB database
Note: This figure shows the official cause of deaths of Nepali migrants for each of the major destination countries




                                                   Figure 5: Deaths rates over time for top destination countries
                                        10
                        Monthly death rates per 100,000
                             4          6
                                        2         8




                                               2010m1                 2011m1           2012m1          2013m1         2014m1
                                                                                        Month

                                                                                  Malaysia           Qatar
                                                                                  S. Arabia          U.A.E


Source: Author’s calculations from FEPB database and the 2011 Population and Housing Census Public Use Microdata Sample
Note: This figure shows the smoothened monthly death rates (per 100,000 migrants) of Nepali workers in the top destination
countries. Locally linear regression with epanechnikov kernel and bandwidth of 4.5 used for smoothing. Thick lines show the
point estimates whereas the light dashed lines around the thick lines show 95% confidence intervals.




                                                                                      21
                                                       Figure 6: Effect of a migrant death on migration flows: Event study plots




                                                                                                           Effect on Log(Mig elsewhere from neighbors) Effect on Log(Migration elsewhere)
             -.06 -.04 -.02 0 .02 .04




                                                                                                                                                        -.06 -.04 -.02 0 .02 .04
                 Effect on Log(Migration)




                                                       -12   -9   -6     -3    0    3    6   9   12                                                                                         -12   -9   -6     -3    0    3    6   9   12
                                                                       Months from death                                                                                                                    Months from death
             Effect on Log(Migration from neighbors)
                 -.06 -.04 -.02 0 .02 .04




                                                                                                                  -.06 -.04 -.02 0 .02 .04


                                                       -12   -9   -6     -3    0    3    6   9   12                                                                                         -12   -9   -6     -3    0    3    6   9   12
                                                                       Months from death                                                                                                                    Months from death


Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: This figure shows the relationship between migrant death and migrant flows in the months preceding and following a
death event. The figures plot point estimates (in red) of τi s from the event study specification, Equation (1), for 12 months
before and after any death event.
The measure of migration flows are indicated on the y-axis of each plot. The plot on the top left shows the effect on the
logarithm of migration flow from the same district to the same destination as the death event. The plot on the top right shows
the effect on the logarithm of migration flow from the same district to other destinations as the death event. The plot on the
bottom left shows the effect on the logarithm of migration flow from neighboring district to the same destination as the death
event. The plot on the bottom right shows the effect on the logarithm of migration flow from neighboring district to other
destinations as the death event.
The vertical line at 0 indicates the month of a migrant death.
In each plot, the blue lines denote the 95% confidence intervals. Robust standard errors are clustered at the district level.




                                                                                                      22
         Figure 7: Effect of a migrant death on wages, fees, and job composition: Event study plots



                              .01




                                                                                            .02




                                                                                                                                                                   .01
                                                                                                                                        Effect on non-construction
                                                                                              .01




                                                                                                                                                           .005
                            .005
             Effect on Log(Wage)




                                                                             Effect on Log(Fees)
                                                                                          0




                                                                                                                                                     0
                        0




                                                                           -.02 -.01




                                                                                                                                           -.005
             -.005




                                                                                                                                                              -.01
                              -.01




                                                                                            -.03
                                                 -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12                                      -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12                                               -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12
                                                       Months from death                                            Months from death                                                     Months from death




                                                                                                                                        Effect on non-construction work elsewhere
                                .001 .002 .003




                                                                                              .005 .01 .015




                                                                                                                                                                          .002
               Effect on Log(wages elsewhere)




                                                                              Effect on Log(fees elsewhere)




                                                                                                                                                            0     .001
             -.002 -.001 0




                                                                           -.01 -.005 0




                                                                                                                                          -.002 -.001
                                                 -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12                                      -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12                                               -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12
                                                       Months from death                                            Months from death                                                     Months from death


Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: This figure shows the relationship between migrant death and migrant wages, fees and job composition in the months
preceding and following a death event. The figures plot point estimates (in red) of τi s from the event study specification,
Equation (1), for 12 months before and after any death event.
The y-axis of each plot denotes the dependent variable. The plots on the top row shows the effect on outcomes in the same
destination as the death event. The plots on the bottom row shows the effect on outcomes in other destination as the death
event. The outcome for the plots on the first column is the logarithm of monthly contractual wages. The outcome for the
plots on the second column is the logarithm of fees paid by migrants to intermediaries. The outcome for the plots on the third
column is the share of workers that migrate for jobs that are definitely not in construction industries.
The vertical line at 0 indicates the month of a migrant death.
In each plot, the blue lines denote the 95% confidence intervals. Robust standard errors are clustered at the district level.


Tables


                                                     Table 1: International migration from Nepal and remittance income
                                                                   Migrant/Population share                                     Remittance Income
                                                           Year     All    India                                 Non-India          % of GDP
                                                           1961    3.49
                                                           1981    2.68    2.48                                      0.19
                                                           1991    3.56    3.17                                      0.37                1.5
                                                           2001    3.41    2.61                                      0.78                2.4
                                                           2011    7.43    2.80                                      4.63               22.4
Source: Migrant/Population share from the Census reports for respective years, Remittance as a share of GDP from the World
Development Indicator database (The World Bank)
Note: This table shows the migrant to population share for each of the census years since 1961. It also shows the share broken
down by destination. The last column shows the personal remittance income as a share of national GDP for the years available.




                                                                                                                      23
                                           Table 2: Summary statistics
                          Total     Number of        Wage          Fee      Exchange rate                 Share of non
                        Outflow        Deaths      (in US $ ) (in US $ )      NPR / US $                   construction
                       mean/(sd) mean/(sd) mean/(sd) mean/(sd)                mean/(sd)                    mean/(sd)
                           (1)          (2)           (3)          (4)            (5)                         (6)
                          Overall means (means per district per destination per month)
    Mean                 49.639        0.102        230.551      582.606                                      0.346
    SD                  (90.956)      (0.353)      (64.362)     (225.627)                                    (0.302)
                         By year (means per district per destination country per month)
    2009                 25.093        0.057        203.853      674.616        77.428                        0.302
                        (52.254)      (0.251)      (64.081)     (185.960)       (2.190)                      (0.302)
    2010                 46.247        0.093        212.331      674.081        73.157                        0.358
                       (114.468)      (0.338)      (62.884)     (199.288)       (1.255)                      (0.329)
    2011                 42.534        0.105        226.260      607.697        74.578                        0.355
                        (65.368)      (0.359)      (74.353)     (228.804)       (4.143)                      (0.298)
    2012                 58.658        0.116        234.269      522.638        84.975                        0.358
                        (86.307)      (0.369)      (53.692)     (212.414)       (3.121)                      (0.291)
    2013                 75.664        0.142        269.948      457.904        93.602                        0.351
                       (111.321)      (0.423)      (42.158)     (211.431)       (6.046)                      (0.287)
                             By Destination Country (means per district per month)
    Malaysia            124.452        0.218        192.791      766.250                                      0.057
                       (152.036)      (0.508)      (38.771)      (94.362)                                    (0.089)
    Qatar                56.187        0.141        226.671      365.417                                      0.228
                        (79.923)      (0.402)      (40.218)     (222.834)                                    (0.165)
    Saudi Arabia         72.869        0.178        206.008      530.926                                      0.251
                        (88.556)      (0.458)      (33.528)     (155.410)                                    (0.159)
    UAE                  34.804        0.050        254.636      584.206                                      0.584
                        (41.604)      (0.227)      (54.438)     (174.725)                                    (0.211)
    Kuwait                7.037        0.018        264.430      666.013                                      0.571
                        (10.687)      (0.136)      (70.982)     (213.247)                                    (0.308)
    Bahrain               2.485        0.010        261.827      611.061                                      0.532
                         (4.113)      (0.101)     (108.430)     (244.385)                                    (0.386)
Source: Author’s calculations on migrant registration database of DoFE and migrant death database of FEPB.
Note: This table shows the means and standard deviations of the outcome variables. The column variables indicate the outcome
variables. An observation in the dataset used to compute the summary statistics is a district-destination-month cell. Outcomes
are first aggregated up to the cell level from the data provided by DoFE and FEPB.
Wages and fees are converted to USD using the monthly exchange rate between USD and Nepali Rupee.
The top panel shows the average of the outcome in a district-destination-month cell. The middle panel shows the average
outcome in a district-destination-month cell in each year. The average is taken over all districts, destinations, and months in
the year indicated in the corresponding row. The bottom panel shows the average outcome in a district-destination-month cell
for each destination country. The average is taken over all districts and months.




                                                              24
                Table 3: Effect of migrant deaths on district-destination level migration flows
                                To same destination                         To other destinations
                        6 months      9 months    12 months         6 months      9 months    12 months
                       after death after death after death         after death after death after death
                            (1)           (2)          (3)              (4)           (5)         (6)
                                                log(migration from district )
  Deaths in    month     -0.012**     -0.012***    -0.012***           0.002       0.003*      0.003**
                          (0.005)       (0.004)      (0.004)         (0.001)       (0.001)     (0.001)
  Obs                      27000         27000        27000           27000         27000       27000
  Adj R2                   0.979         0.984        0.987            0.998         0.998      0.998
                                          log(migration from neighboring districts)
  Deaths in    month    -0.007***     -0.008***     -0.007**           0.002        0.002       0.002
                          (0.003)       (0.003)      (0.003)         (0.001)       (0.001)     (0.001)
  Obs                      27000         27000        27000           27000         27000       27000
  Adj R2                   0.989         0.991        0.993            0.998         0.998      0.998
                                   log(migration from 2nd degree neighboring districts)
  Deaths in    month     -0.004**      -0.005**     -0.004**           0.001       0.001*       0.001
                          (0.002)       (0.002)      (0.002)         (0.001)       (0.001)     (0.001)
  Obs                      27000         27000        27000           27000         27000       27000
  Adj R2                   0.993         0.995        0.996            0.999         0.999      0.999
                                       log(migration from far neighboring districts)
  Deaths in    month       0.001         0.001        0.001           -0.000        -0.001      -0.001
                          (0.001)       (0.001)      (0.001)         (0.000)       (0.000)     (0.000)
  Obs                      27000         27000        27000           27000         27000       27000
  Adj R2                   0.999         0.999        0.999            0.999         0.999      0.999
Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: This table shows the effect of a death of a migrant in a district-destination cell on logarithm of migrant flows, estimated
using Equation (2).
The first 3 columns show the effect on the logarithm of subsequent migration flows to the same destination as the deceased
migrant. Columns (1), (2), and (3) show the estimates for subsequent flow in the 6, 9, and 12 months respectively.
The last 3 columns show the effect on the logarithm of subseqent migration flows to destinations other the country of migrant
death. Columns (4), (5), and (6) show the estimates for subsequent flow in the 6, 9, and 12 months respectively.
The top panel shows the effect on migration flows from the same district as the migrant death. The second panel shows the
effect on migration flows from neighboring districts. Neighboring districts share a border with the district of migrant death.
The third panel shows the effect of a migrant death on migration flows from second degree neighboring districts. Second degree
neighbors are separated from the district of migrant death by one district. The fourth panel presents the effects on migration
flows from districts that are from the district of migrant death. These districts are separated from the district of migrant death
by at least 3 districts in between.
Each column in each panel is a separate regression. For all specifications, standard errors are reported in parenthesis and are
clustered at the district level. ∗∗∗ : p < 0.01; ∗∗ : p < 0.05; ∗ : p < 0.1




                                                               25
                       Table 4: Effect of migrant deaths on district level migration outflow
                                                           Flow in the next
                                                  6 months 9 months 12 months
                                                      (1)         (2)           (3)
                                     log(total migration from district)
                           All deaths in month -0.012**       -0.010**      -0.009**
                                                   (0.005)     (0.005)       (0.005)
                           Obs                       4499        4500          4500
                           Adj R2                    0.967      0.973         0.976
                               log(total migration from neighboring district)
                           All deaths in month -0.015*** -0.013*** -0.013***
                                                   (0.004)     (0.004)       (0.004)
                           Obs                       4500        4500          4500
                           Adj R2                    0.962      0.965         0.968
                              log(total migration from 2nd degree neighbors)
                           All deaths in month      -0.002      -0.001        -0.000
                                                   (0.003)     (0.003)       (0.003)
                           Obs                       4500        4500          4500
                           Adj R2                    0.957      0.962         0.967
                                  log(total migration from far neighbors)
                           All deaths in month      -0.000      -0.001        -0.001
                                                   (0.001)     (0.001)       (0.001)
                           Obs                       4500        4500          4500
                           Adj R2                    0.991      0.992         0.992
Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: The table shows the effect of a death of a migrant from a district on the logarithm of migration flows, estimated using
Equation (4)
Columns (1), (2), and (3) show the effect on flows in the subsequent 6, 9, and 12 months respectively.
The top panel shows the effect of a migrant death on flows from the same district. The second panel shows the effect on flows
from neighboring districts. Neighboring districts share a border with the district of migrant death. The third panel shows the
effect on flows from second degree neighboring districts. Second degree neighbors are separated from the district of migrant
death by one district. The fourth panel shows the effect on flows from districts that are far from the district of migrant death.
These districts are separated from the district of migrant death by at least 3 districts in between.
Each column in each panel is a separate regression. For all specifications, standard errors are reported in parenthesis and are
clustered at the district level. ∗∗∗ : p < 0.01; ∗∗ : p < 0.05; ∗ : p < 0.1




                                                              26
                          Table 5: Effect of migrant deaths on job-composition and prices
                                   To same destination                        To other destinations
                           6 months     9 months      12 months       6 months      9 months    12 months
                          after death after death after death        after death after death after death
                               (1)          (2)           (3)             (4)           (5)         (6)
                                          Share of jobs definitely non-noconstruction
  Deaths in month            -0.001       -0.001        -0.001           0.000         0.000      0.000
                            (0.001)      (0.001)       (0.001)         (0.000)       (0.000)     (0.000)
  Obs                        25620        25987         26188           25620         25987       26188
  Adj R2                      0.711       0.776         0.816            0.920         0.934      0.944
                                                      log(contractual wages)
  Deaths in month            -0.000       -0.000        -0.000          -0.000        -0.001      -0.001
                            (0.001)      (0.001)       (0.001)         (0.001)       (0.001)     (0.001)
  Obs                        25616        25987         26188           25526         25915       26126
  Adj R2                      0.852       0.885         0.908            0.954         0.963      0.966
                                               log(fees paid for recruiting services)
  Deaths in month             0.002       0.002         0.002           -0.000        -0.000      -0.000
                            (0.002)      (0.001)       (0.001)         (0.001)       (0.001)     (0.001)
  Obs                        25579        25962         26176           25524         25911       26122
  Adj R2                      0.806       0.839         0.865            0.907         0.925      0.937
Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: This table shows the effect of a death of a migrant in a district-destination cell on job composition, logarithm of contracted
wages, and logarithm of fees paid to intermediaries, estimated using Equation (2).
The first 3 columns show the effect on the outcomes for the same destination as the destination of the deceased migrant.
Columns (1), (2), and (3) show the effect for the subsequent 6, 9, and 12 months respectively.
The last 3 columns show the effect on the outcomes for migrants going to destinations other the country of migrant death.
Columns (4), (5), and (6) show the effect for subsequent the 6, 9, and 12 months respectively.
The top panel shows the effect on the share of migrants who go for a job that is definitely not in construction sector. The
second panel shows the effect on the logarithm of average contractual wage of migrants. The bottom panle shows the effect on
the logarithm of average fees paid by the migrants for recruitment services.
Each column in a panel represents a separate regression. In all cases, standard errors are reported in parenthesis and are
clustered at the district level. ∗∗∗ : p < 0.01; ∗∗ : p < 0.05; ∗ : p < 0.1




                                                                27
                        Table 6: Heterogeneous effect of deaths on migration flows
  Flow in the next                          6 months                9 months                                 12 months
                                         (1)          (2)        (3)         (4)                           (5)       (6)
                                 log(migration to same destination)
  Deaths in month                      0.006         0.010     -0.001      0.002                          -0.003       0.000
                                      (0.014)      (0.014)    (0.014)     (0.014)                        (0.014)      (0.015)
   x Deaths in past 6 months        -0.006***               -0.006***                                   -0.005**
                                      (0.002)                 (0.002)                                    (0.002)
   x > 1 deaths in past 6 months                 -0.022***               -0.019***                                   -0.016**
                                                   (0.007)                (0.007)                                     (0.006)
   x death rate in Destination         -0.001       -0.002      0.001      -0.000                         0.001        -0.000
                                      (0.002)      (0.003)    (0.002)     (0.003)                        (0.002)      (0.003)
  Deaths in past 6 months           -0.012***                -0.010**                                   -0.009**
                                      (0.004)                 (0.004)                                    (0.004)
  > 1 deaths in past 6 months                      -0.020*                 -0.016                                      -0.014
                                                   (0.011)                (0.010)                                     (0.010)
                                log(migration to other destinations)
  Deaths in month                      -0.006      -0.007*     -0.004      -0.005                         -0.003       -0.004
                                      (0.004)      (0.004)    (0.004)     (0.004)                        (0.004)      (0.004)
   x Deaths in past 6 months            0.000                   0.000                                     -0.000
                                      (0.001)                 (0.001)                                    (0.001)
   x > 1 deaths in past 6 months                     0.003                 0.003                                       0.003
                                                   (0.003)                (0.003)                                     (0.003)
   x death rate in Destination         0.002*      0.001*      0.001        0.001                        0.001         0.001
                                      (0.001)      (0.001)    (0.001)     (0.001)                       (0.001)       (0.001)
  Deaths in past 6 months             0.004**                 0.004**                                   0.003**
                                      (0.002)                 (0.002)                                   (0.002)
  > 1 deaths in past 6 months                     0.010**                 0.009**                                     0.007*
                                                   (0.004)                (0.004)                                     (0.004)
                        log(migration from neighbors to same destination)
  Deaths in month                      -0.004       -0.002     -0.008      -0.007                         -0.006       -0.005
                                      (0.010)      (0.010)    (0.010)     (0.010)                        (0.009)      (0.009)
   x Deaths in past 6 months           -0.001                  -0.001                                     -0.001
                                      (0.002)                 (0.001)                                    (0.001)
   x > 1 deaths in past 6 months                 -0.014***               -0.013***                                   -0.012**
                                                   (0.005)                (0.005)                                     (0.005)
   x death rate in Destination          0.000        0.001     0.001        0.001                         0.000        0.001
                                      (0.002)      (0.002)    (0.002)     (0.002)                        (0.002)      (0.002)
  Deaths in past 6 months            -0.007**                 -0.005*                                    -0.005*
                                      (0.003)                 (0.003)                                    (0.003)
  > 1 deaths in past 6 months                     -0.015**                -0.012*                                     -0.012*
                                                   (0.007)                (0.007)                                     (0.007)
Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: The table shows how the migration effect of a death of a migrant in a district-destination cells changes with the number
of deaths in the district-destination cell in the past six months. The estimates reported are β and δ coefficients from Equation
(5). All specifications control for the effect of the interaction between current death and actual underlying death rates in the
destination countries.
The first two columns present the estimates for migrant outflow in the subsequent 6 months, columns (3) and (4) present the
estimates for migrant outflow in the subsequent 9 months, and columns (5) and (6) present the estimates for migrant outflow
in the subsequent 12 months.
Odd numbered columns show the interaction with the number of deaths in the district-destination cell in the past 6 months.
Even numbered columns show the interact with whether there has been more than one death in district-destination cell in the
past 6 months.
The top panel shows the effect on migration outflow from in the same district-destination cells as the migrant death. The
second panel shows the effect on migration outflow to destinations other than that of the migrant death. The third panel shows
the effect on migration outflow from neighboring districts to the same destination as the migrant death.
For all panels, standard errors are reported in parenthesis and are clustered at the district level. ∗∗∗ : p < 0.01; ∗∗ : p < 0.05;
∗ : p < 0.1

                                                                28
                      Table 7: Effect of deaths in any destination on total migration outflow
                                                                  Flow in the next
                                                         6 months 9 months 12 months
                                                             (1)         (2)          (3)
                                     log(total migration from district)
                      All deaths in month                   0.009       0.010       0.008
                                                          (0.008)     (0.007)      (0.007)
                        x > 3 deaths in past 6 months -0.022**       -0.022**     -0.020**
                                                          (0.010)     (0.010)      (0.009)
                      > 3 deaths in past 6 months           0.016       0.015       0.006
                                                          (0.020)     (0.021)      (0.020)
                      Obs                                   4049        4050         4050
                      Adj R2                                0.972       0.976       0.978
                               log(total migration from neighboring district)
                      All deaths in month                  -0.014      -0.012       -0.012
                                                          (0.011)     (0.011)      (0.011)
                        x > 3 deaths in past 6 months       0.007      0.005         0.006
                                                          (0.012)     (0.013)      (0.013)
                      > 3 deaths in past 6 months          -0.028      -0.024       -0.025
                                                          (0.021)     (0.021)      (0.020)
                      Obs                                   4050        4050         4050
                      Adj R2                                0.964       0.967       0.968
                              log(total migration from 2nd degree neighbors)
                      All deaths in month                   0.003       0.005       0.004
                                                          (0.006)     (0.006)      (0.005)
                        x > 3 deaths in past 6 months       0.000      -0.001       -0.001
                                                          (0.007)     (0.007)      (0.006)
                      > 3 deaths in past 6 months           0.013       0.018       0.018
                                                          (0.015)     (0.014)      (0.013)
                      Obs                                   4050        4050         4050
                      Adj R2                                0.958       0.964       0.967
Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the FEPB database and the DoFE database
Note: The table shows how the migration effect of a death of a migrant in district changes with whether there has been many
(> 3) migrant deaths in the district in the past six months. The estimates reported are β and δ coefficients from Equation (5).
Columns (1), (2), and (3) present the estimates for the migrant outflow in the subsequent 6, 9, and 12 months.
The top panel shows the effect on migration outflow from in the same district as the migrant death. The second panel shows
the effect on migration outflow from neighboring districts. The third panel shows the effect on migration outflow from 2nd
degree neighboring districts.
For all panels, standard errors are reported in parenthesis and are clustered at the district level. ∗∗∗ : p < 0.01; ∗∗ : p < 0.05;
∗ : p < 0.1




                                                                29
For Online Publication

A      Exploiting exchange rate shocks to estimate wage elasticity of
       migration
In this section, I use the exchange rate shocks to wages to estimate the wage elasticity of migration. The
first part outlines the methodology and the second part presents the estimates. The data used in this section
is the reported wages and migration flows from the DoFE database described in Section 2.2. The monthly
exchange rate data comes from the historic database of the online forex trading platform OANDA.17


A.I     Empirical specification
The earnings elasticity of migration that I want to estimate is given by β in the following specification

                                       log (ydt ) = αd + γt + β log (Wdt ) + εdt

where ydt represents the migrant flow from Nepal to destination country d in month t, Wdt is the contractual
wage in Nepali Rupee for month t in destination country d. αd and γt represent destination and time fixed
effects. Estimating β from this specification will be biased as the unobserved determinants of migration flows
is correlated with the wages offered to the migrants. Further, the relationship is an equilibrium relationship
and suffers from reverse causality. That is, a change in wages leads to a change in migration flows, but at
the same time a change in migration flows also leads to a change in equilibrium wages offered. Hence, an
instrument for wages is needed to identify the elasticity.
    One possibility is to use the exchange rate Edt between Nepal and the destination country as an instru-
ment. However, factors affecting exchange rate between Nepal and the destination country could directly
affect migration flows in addition to its effect though migrant wages. Therefore, I estimate a slightly modified
version of the equation:
                                          ydt                         Wdt
                                  log            =αd + γt + β log          + εdt
                                         yM t                        WM t
                                                                                                           (7)
                                         Wdt                         Edt
                                 log             =ξd + ψt + δ log         + ηdt
                                         WM t                        EM t
where yM t , WM t , and EM t represents migration, contractual wages and exchange rates in Malaysia. By
normalizing everything by Malaysian flows, wages and shocks, identification comes from the shocks to ex-
change rates between Malaysia and other destination countries. The exclusion restriction requires that the
destination choice of potential migrants does not depend upon the relative exchange rates with Malaysia
except through changes in relative wages. This is a more palatable assumption.
    The relative exchange rates and relative migrant flow appear to be strongly correlated. As shown in
Figure A.1, between 2009 and mid-2011, relative exchange rate between the Persian Gulf countries and
Malaysia fell drastically. Consequently, the relative flow of migrants from Nepal to Persian Gulf countries
also fell. This figure essentially shows the reduced form relationship for estimating Equation (7).
    Few issues arise in this estimation. For instance, shocks to exchange rates of a country are likely to be
correlated over time and not correcting for this will lead to standard errors that are too small. Bertrand,
Duflo, and Mullainathan (2004) show that with few groups, even clustering standard errors at the group
 17 http://www.oanda.com/currency/average.




                                                          30
level produces standard errors that are too small. In this context, increasing group size by including other
destination countries presents two main problems. First, migration to other destination countries is not
as easy as migrating to the common destination countries. For example, European employers may not be
as keen to sponsor the work visa of low-skilled Nepali workers as does Malaysia. Therefore, migration to
Europe will responds less to increase in low-skill wages in Europe. The average elasticity estimated by
including other countries will be lower than the elasticity for the most common destinations used in this
analysis. Second, since migration to other destination is not as frequent, I do not observe wage information
for the destinations in months in which there is no migration. The technique used to impute missing wage
information affects the estimated elasticities. To impute wages for months in which there is no migration, I
assume that the nominal wage in the destination country remains the same as the previous month and the
variation is induced only by fluctuations in the exchange rates. This process describes the wage data quite
well (with R-squared of 0.88) for countries where missing wage information is not a problem.
   In addition to specifications with standard errors clustered at the country level, I also present specifica-
tions that cluster the standard error at country × period level. The period are defined such that exchange
rates are unlikely to be serially correlated across periods. The first period between January 2009 and July
2011 is marked by steadily declining relative exchange rate, the second period between August 2011 and
May 2013 is marked by fluctuating but relatively stable exchange rate, and the third period between June
2013 and December 2013 as the period of increasing relative exchange rate.


A.II     Results
For the top 6 destinations, the relative exchange rates show strong first stages and reduced forms. As Table
A.1 shows, an increase in relative exchange rate of 1 percent increases relative migration to Malaysia by
6 percent (top panel, column 1). This comes at no surprise given the strong correlation between relative
migration flows and relative exchange rates as seen in Figure A.1. Similarly, an increase in relative exchange
rate of 1 percent increases relative wages by 5 percent (middle panel, column 1). The 2SLS estimate of the
wage elasticity of migration is 1.2. All of these estimates are statistically different from zero at conventional
levels at both clustering specifications.
   The point estimate of the elasticity is similar for the the top 10 destinations, but is estimated imprecisely
(Table A.1, column 2). As discussed earlier, due to institutional restriction in other countries, migration flows
do not respond as strongly to changes in relative exchange rates. The wage effect of exchange rate shocks
are also small and imprecisely estimated. Consequently, the estimated wage elasticity of migration is also
imprecisely estimated. However, the point estimate of 1.4 is similar to the estimate for top 6 destinations.
   Including more destination countries in the estimation simply exaggerates the problems discussed above
(Table A.1, columns 3 and 4). Due to institutional barriers, migration flow does not respond to exchange rate
shocks. Since, missing wages are imputed from the changes in exchange rates, the first stage estimates are
biased towards 1. As a result, the estimated wage elasticity of migration are much smaller and imprecisely
estimated.




                                                      31
A.III      Figures and Tables for Online Appendix
Figures


                                      Figure A.1: Relative exchange rates and relative migration

                                              Qatar                                                        Saudi




                                                                            2

                                                                                      0




                                                                                                                                          2
             0




                                                                            1




                                                                                                                                          1
                                                                                      -.1
                                                                            0
             -.1




                                                                                                                                          0
                                                                            -1




                                                                                                                                          -1
                                                                                      -.2
                                                                            -2
             -.2




                                                                                                                                          -2
                           2009m1 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2014m1                    2009m1 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2014m1

                                              UAE                                                         Bahrain


                                                                                      2.3




                                                                                                                                          -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1
                                                                            1
             0
             -.2 -.15 -.1 -.05




                                                                            0

                                                                                      2.2
                                                                            -1

                                                                                      2.1
                                                                            -2
                                                                            -3

                                                                                      2




                           2009m1 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2014m1                    2009m1 2010m1 2011m1 2012m1 2013m1 2014m1


                                       Log(ex-rate relative to Malaysia): Left                    Log(flow relative to Malaysia): Right



Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the DoFE database on migrant flow and historic exchange
rate data from OANDA
Note: Green (dark) line represents logarithm of exchange rate of the country relative to Malaysia in left-axis. The red (light
gray) line represents the logarithm of the ratio of migrant flow to the destination country relative to the flow to Malaysia
(right-axis). The plot titles show the destination country.




                                                                                 32
Tables


                         Table A.1: Effect of relative wage rate on relative migration
                                         Top 6           Top 10       Top 15          Top 20
                                     destinations Destinations Destinations Destinations
                                          (1)              (2)          (3)             (4)
                                                Reduced form
               Log(Ex-rate relative      6.211            0.554        0.451           0.258
               to Malaysia)            (1.583)**         (0.332)      (0.300)         (0.183)
                                      [1.915]***         [0.514]      [0.360]         [0.180]
                                                  First stage
               Log(Ex-rate relative      5.016            0.360        1.488           1.041
               to Malaysia)           (0.315)***         (0.866)      (1.214)         (1.067)
                                      [0.505]***         [5.318]      [3.652]         [1.026]
                                               2-SLS estimates
               Log(wage relative to      1.207            1.400        0.311           0.241
               Malaysia)               (0.366)**         (2.744)      (0.269)         (0.180)
                                       [0.481]**        [21.783]      [0.907]         [0.254]
               Observations               300              600          840            1140
Source: Author’s calculations from the dataset constructed from the the DoFE database and the exchange rate data from
OANDA
Note: This table shows the reduced form, first stages and the 2SLS estimates of the effect of logarithm of wages on logarithm
of migrant flow using logarithm of exchange rate shocks as instruments, estimated using Equation (7). All variables: wages,
migrant flow, and exchange rate are expressed relative to their values in Malaysia.
The column headings represents the sample of countries used for estimation. Except for the first column, wages are missing
when there is no migration flow to that destination. Wages are imputed assuming that the nominal wage in destination currency
remains the same as previous month. The only source of variation is through changes in the exchange rates.
Standard errors reported in parenthesis are clustered at the country level, whereas those reported in brackets are clustered at
the country × period level. There are three periods: the first period defined as months between January 2009 and July 2011,
the second period as months between August 2011 and May 2013, and the third period as months between June 2013 and
December 2013. ∗∗∗ : p < 0.01; ∗∗ : p < 0.05; ∗ : p < 0.1




                                                              33