Policy Research Working Paper                          10430




   The People’s Voice and Access to Sanitation
                              John Nana Francois
                           Kwabena Gyimah-Brempong
                                 Johnson Kakeu
                                Cristelle Kouame




Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment Global Practice
May 2023
Policy Research Working Paper 10430


  Abstract
 This paper estimates the effect of voice and accountabil-                          estimator as both an alternative estimator for the analysis
 ity, which captures transparent electoral processes, free                          and an empirical strategy to formally assess the validity
 media, and freedom of expression, on access to sanita-                             of the instrument in a just-identified model—a previously
 tion services in developing countries. The core argument                           untestable just-identifying exclusion restriction. The paper
 is that voice and accountability increases the visibility of                       finds robust evidence that voice and accountability increase
 sanitation as a public good and raises awareness of its                            access to sanitation and help close the persistent rural-urban
 benefits; hence, increasing its supply and demand. The                             inequality in access to sanitation. The results suggest that
 analysis utilizes data from 73 developing countries and                            key tenets of democracy such a freedom of speech, free
 an instrumental variable approach to identify the causal                           media, and power of electoral incentives are not a luxury of
 effect of voice and accountability on access to, and use of,                       the rich—they are relevant to the world’s poor as they can
 sanitation. The paper also employs a novel instrument-free                         shape the demand and distribution of sanitation services.




 This paper is a product of the Macroeconomics, Trade and Investment Global Practice. It is part of a larger effort by the
 World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the
 world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/prwp. The authors may
 be contacted at jfrancois1@worldbank.org_and ckouame 1@worldbank.org.




         The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
         issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
         names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
         of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
         its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.


                                                       Produced by the Research Support Team
                                        The People’s Voice and Access to Sanitation*

            John Nana Francois†              Kwabena Gyimah-Brempong‡                                 Johnson Kakeu§
               World Bank                 University of South Florida and IZA               University of Prince Edward Island

                                                              Cristelle Kouame¶
                                                                 World Bank




       JEL Classification: C26, D72, H41, H42, O18, P16
       Keywords: Sanitation; Voice and accountability; Awareness and visibility; Rural and urban; Instrumental variable;
       Instrument-free estimator




   * We   are grateful to Michael Bleaney, Robert Johann Utz, Chiara Bronchi, Yaw Nyarko, Zalda Feliciano, Maty Konte, Leonce Ndikumana,
Mina Baliamoune-Lutz, Jesse Mora, Grace Phillips, Eric Hoffmann, Anne C. Barthel, Kodama Toyoko, Berta Macheve, and Guy Tchuente
for useful comments, feedback, and discussions on earlier versions of the paper that have significantly improved the paper. We would also
like thank conference participants and discussants at the 2021 American Economic Association (AEA), the 2022 97th Western Economic
Association International meeting in Portland, Oregon, and University of Prince Edward Island for useful discussions and feedback. We are
solely responsible for any remaining errors.
Disclaimer: The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors and should not be attributed
to the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.
    † Fiscal Policy and Sustainable Growth Unit, World Bank, 701 18th Street NW, Washington, DC20433, US.
    ‡ Department of Economics, University of South Florida, Tampa, FL 33620, Tel: (703) 798-2438 email: kgyimah@usf.edu and IZA-Institute

of Labor Economics, Bonn.
    § Email: jkakeu@upei.ca. Department of Economics, 550 University Avenue Charlottetown, Prince Edward Island Canada C1A 4P3
    ¶ Email: ckouame1@worldbank.org. World Bank, 701 18th Street NW, Washington, DC20433, US (J10-042)
1.      I NTRODUCTION

         “I stuck my neck out today when I said we have to break taboos because people didn’t even mention the word toilet in the UN
         [United Nations] five years ago ... We need to break taboos ... We don’t speak about [defecation], there’s a shame factor which
         is horrible. It is the most natural of human needs, which causes enormous problems which relate both to health and dignity.”—
         Jan Eliasson UN Deputy Secretary-General on his speech at the World Water Week in Stockholm on September 2, 2013 to the
         Guardian.

This paper studies the causal effect of voice and accountability (Voice, henceforth), which broadly captures transparent
electoral processes and free media and accountability, on the access to sanitation in developing countries.1 The paper
also investigates the effect of Voice on rural/urban gaps in access to sanitation. We do so by: (1) estimating the
effect of Voice on the percentage of people using basic sanitation for 73 developing countries; (2) examining whether
Voice increases access to sanitation in rural and urban areas; and (3) investigating whether Voice closes the persistent
rural-urban gap in access to sanitation in developing countries. Our core argument is that Voice increases sanitation’s
visibility as a public good, raises awareness of its benefits to households who demand its production, and pushes
governments to respond to pressure to increase the supply of sanitation.2 We instrument for Voice using the average
years of schooling in 1900. We find that Voice has a positive, statistically and economically significant effect on access
to sanitation services. This positive effect generally holds true in urban and rural areas. The results are also robust
to different model specifications and estimation methods. Furthermore, the results show that Voice can be used as an
effective vehicle to close the persistent rural-urban inequality in access to sanitation.
        Access to sanitation, measured as the percentage of people using at least basic sanitation services—improved
sanitation facilities that are not shared with other households—is fundamental to improved human health. This mea-
sure encompasses both people using basic sanitation services as well as those using safely managed sanitation ser-
vices.3 Recent updates of Sustainable Development Goal 6 (SDG 6) show that the developing world has seen sig-
nificant progress in the number of people with access to sanitation.4 However, globally, 3.6 billion people still live
without access to basic sanitation, and approximately 8 percent of the world’s population still practice open defecation
(United Nations, 2021). Furthermore, it is well-documented that the sanitation crisis is most acute in rural areas, home
to 91 percent of the people who defecate in the open and 72 percent of those without basic sanitation. Additionally, the
lack of access to sanitation poses a serious threat to vulnerable populations as it exposes them to serious environmen-
                     ua, Djebbari, and Pickering, 2020). In fact, poor sanitation is a leading risk factor for infectious
tal health risks (Alz´
diseases, including cholera, diarrhoea, dysentery, hepatitis A, typhoid, and polio. There is also strong evidence that
lack of access to sanitation exacerbates malnutrition, and in particular, childhood stunting (WHO , 2019).5 Access
to sanitation also improves education outcomes. For example, Adukia (2017) finds that latrine construction increases
female school enrollment in India, particularly those who may be vulnerable to illnesses caused by uncontained waste.
Similarly, Spears and Lamba (2016) find that early exposure to a sanitation campaign through India’s Total Sanitation
     1 Throughout  the paper, we often use voice and accountability to also capture free media and transparent elections.
     2 Thisargument is in line with Kaufmann et al. (2019), who find evidence that suggests that “voice”-related variables such as citizen voice
and transparency has a larger effect on the public sector service delivery performance and corruption. More practically, recent sanitation policy
iterations have targeted demand for sanitation through media campaigns, capacity building, and community activities (Pakhtigian et al., 2022).
The focus has shifted to education and communication, coupled with a continued emphasis on direct infrastructure provision and subsidization.
    3 We follow the World Health Organization’s (WHO) definition of sanitation as access to facilities for the safe disposal of human waste as

well as having the ability to maintain hygienic conditions. Improved sanitation facilities include flush/pour flush to piped sewer systems, septic
tanks or pit latrines; ventilated improved pit latrines, compositing toilets or pit latrines with slabs.
    4 See details on SDG 6 here: https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/water-and-sanitation/ at United Nations.
    5 https://www.who.int/news-room/fact-sheets/detail/sanitation




                                                                        1
Campaign improves childhood cognitive skills. The direct role of sanitation on educational outcomes suggests that
lack of access to sanitation is a threat to human capital formation, which is an important driver of long-term growth
and development. Despite its benefits, governments in developing countries have not provided sufficient investment,
administrative support, and continuous oversight for the substantial provision of basic sanitation services.
      Table 1 provides a first look at the progress made in access to electricity and water compared to sanitation
services in low-income countries. Over the 2010 to 2019 period, access to electricity and water services increased
by 14.07 and 7.97 percentage points, respectively. Meanwhile, access to sanitation services increased by only 0.68
percentage points in low-income countries. This marginal increase in access to sanitation may be partly driven by the
fact that there is less public awareness of, and perhaps, lower priority given to, the sanitation problem— i.e., sanitation
is a “low visibility good” in developing countries— compared to electricity or water services.

                           Table 1: The change in access to basic public goods in low-income countries, 2010-2019

                       Public good/service                                        2010          2019          Change (% Points)
                       Electricity (% of population)                              26.85         40.92                 14.07
                       Water services (% of population)                           49.85         57.80                  7.95
                       Sanitation services (% of population)                      44.56         45.24                  0.68
                      Source: Authors’ calculation of World Bank’s World Development Indicators. Access to electricity is the per-
                     centage of population with access to electricity. Water services (% of population) is the percentage of people
                     using at least basic water services. This indicator encompasses both people using basic water services as well as
                     those using safely managed water services. Basic drinking water services is defined as drinking water from an
                     improved source, provided collection time is not more than 30 minutes for a round trip. Improved water sources
                     include piped water, boreholes or tubewells, protected dug wells, protected springs, and packaged or delivered
                     water.


      Access to sanitation is both a demand and supply problem. Specifically, households demand to use sanitation
services, and governments have a key leadership and facilitating role (e.g., partnering with the private sector) in
providing sanitation services. Households may be able and willing to pay for improved sanitation services, but the
government’s supply of public infrastructure is required to facilitate the final provision of these services. Without
government provision of sanitation infrastructure, household demand for, and use of, sanitation may not be possible.
In several rural areas in low-income countries, households may not be able to afford sanitation services— i.e., demand
is nonexistent simply because income is too low. In such a case, the government can provide sanitation services (e.g.,
public toilets) as public goods to serve the poor at little to no cost.6 On the other hand, if the supply of sanitation
service is available, people will have the incentive to access and use these necessities. For several people in the
developing world, however, the immediate and long-term benefits of accessing and using quality sanitation services
and the facilitating role of government in providing these services are not well-communicated. Hence, the demand,
and consequently, the supply for basic sanitation services might be low partly because of low awareness from lack of
information. Moreover, even if there is awareness of the sanitation problem, the suppression of discussions and media
campaigns around it can keep the problem hidden and hence, make it less visible as a priority policy issue. These may
be attributed to weak institutions related to voice and accountability.
      Using average years of schooling in 1900 as an instrumental variable to identify the exogenous component of
voice and accountability, we estimate the latter’s impact on access to sanitation in 73 developing countries over the
period 2002-2020. Our empirical analysis uncover the following results: First, we find that higher levels of Voice
   6 In situations where building sanitation infrastructure can generate positive externalities on the demand side,the empirical study by Gautam
(2023) shows that a price subsidy is more effective than a targeted cash transfer in increasing the average sanitation adoption rate.



                                                                            2
increases access to and use of sanitation. Specifically, after accounting for key covariates, our point estimate indicates
that a 1 unit increase in Voice causes an 18 percentage points increase in access to and use of basic sanitation service.
Second, we find that a unit increase in Voice leads to 12 and 32 percentage point increase in sanitation access in urban
and rural areas, respectively. Third, the results reveal that increases in Voice decreases the rural/urban gap in access to
sanitation. These results are robust across different estimators, specifications, and samples.
     The causal impact of Voice on access to sanitation in developing countries suggests that Voice makes the sanita-
tion problem visible. Once the problem is made visible, solutions may be seriously considered; hence, help increase
the provision and access of sanitation services. Moreover, our findings imply that policies targeting the strengthening
of institutions along the dimension of voice and accountability in developing countries will not only improve the latter
but also induce an increase of access to sanitation. More precisely, policies that target the improvement of Voice can
generate positive second order effects with important development implications. Furthermore, the results strongly
suggest that Voice can be used as an effective vehicle to close the rural-urban gap in access to sanitation.
     Our study makes four key contributions to the literature: First, we establish causality between Voice and access
to, and use of, sanitation— previous studies have not established a casual impact of Voice on access to sanitation.
Relatedly, our work focuses exclusively on the effect of voice and accountability on access to, and use of, sanitation
in developing countries as opposed to simply using it as another control variable in previous studies. Second, we use
a simple conceptual framework to shed light on the mechanisms—i.e., the demand and supply channels— through
which voice and accountability might affect access to sanitation in developing countries. Third, our analysis identifies
a rural-urban gap in access to sanitation and investigates the degree to which voice and accountability can close this
gap. The result establishes that Voice can serve as an important vehicle in solving this critical and structural spatial
inequality in access to sanitation. This can in turn improve well-known rural-urban gap inequalities in education
and health. Fourth, the study applies a novel instrument-free estimator in kinky least squares (KLS) to formally test
the validity of our instrumental variable— a previously untestable just-identifying exclusion restriction. Importantly,
as a robustness exercise, we employ the KLS as an alternative estimator to establish a causal effect of voice and
accountability on access to and use of sanitation.
     The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 briefly summarizes the related literature on the subject,
Section 3 introduces a simple conceptual framework to shed light on how voice and accountability can impact access
to sanitation. Section 4 describes the data and discusses the methodology. Section 5 presents and discusses the
estimation results. Section 6 concludes.

2.   R ELATED LITERATURE
     Despite its importance, the development economics literature has paid scant attention to sanitation (Ravilla et al.,
2021). However, this is rapidly changing as the literature has begun to pay serious attention to the subject in light of
the prominence given to it in the SDGs. Recent studies of sanitation in the development economics literature have
focused on three main areas: the impact of sanitation on development outcomes; the supply of, access to, and use of
sanitation services; and the role of external aid in the provision of sanitation. Our paper focuses on the effects of voice
and accountability on access to and use of sanitation; hence, we do not focus on the literature that investigates the
effect of sanitation on development outcomes. We therefore limit our literature review to the supply and demand for
sanitation, and the role of foreign aid in the supply, access and use of sanitation.



                                                            3
      On the demand side, several studies have stressed the importance of income (Immurana et al., 2022); education
and information (Alexander et al., 2019), Adil et al. (2021); Legge et al. (2021); Pakhtigian et al. (2022), resource
constraints, as well as socio-cultural environment (Munamati et al., 2016) as important determinants of the access to,
and use of, sanitation infrastructure and services. The argument is that information and education shift household
preferences towards sanitation use while increasing income and relaxing resource constraints, generally, make san-
itation services affordable to households. These studies have been conducted mostly at the aggregate level and do
not establish causality. Other researchers stress the importance of accountability and advocacy as important factors in
access and use of sanitation services. Some studies also highlight the critical role of information and peer effects in
overcoming social and cultural barriers in the use of sanitation (Adil et al., 2021; Alexander et al., 2019; Legge et al.,
2021; Pakhtigian et al., 2022, among others)
      Researchers interested in the supply of infrastructure services have focused on the characteristics of sanitation
infrastructure and services, political institutions and the environment in which services are provided as well as po-
litical accountability and advocacy generated through voice and accountability. Ashraf et al. (2016) and Batley and
Mcloughlin (2015) argue that sanitation infrastructure and services are characterized by indivisibility as well as exter-
nalities; hence, have to be provided by the public sector else the quantity provided will be sub-optimal. In low income
countries, private provision may not even be feasible because of affordability. Other researchers have focused on the
type of political institutions that provide sanitation services more effectively. Deacon (2009) argue that democracies
provide better public services, including sanitation, to citizens relative to autocracies, probably because of increased
accountability. Similarly, Keefer and Khemani (2005); Khemani (2015) argue that political incentives emanating from
visibility and political pressure determines which public goods will be provided in a society.7 Looking at sanitation
issues through an institutional lens, data from 85 countries are analyzed by Anbarci et al. (2009) to show that cor-
ruption negatively affects both efforts to improve drinking water and sanitation. Breen and Gillanders (2022) using
data on 45,000 households’ across Africa provide strong evidence that local corruption in the utilities sector impedes
everyone’s access to clean water and sanitation.               Similarly, some researchers argue that the supply of sanitation is
influenced by the institutional environment (Francois et al., 2021; Hepworth et al., 2022; Hout et al., 2022).
      An aspect of the provision of public services generally, and sanitation in particular, is visibility and accountability.
The more visible a project is and the more policy makers are held accountable for its provision, the greater the quantity
of such services that will be provided; the reverse is also true—policy makers tend to provide less of services that are
not visible and for which they are not held accountable. Voice shines a spotlight on sanitation thus making it visible
as well as helping to keep policy makers accountable for its provision. Adil et al. (2021) finds that information and
increased accountability improves access to safe drinking water and sanitation in Punjab, Pakistan. Similarly, Hout
et al. (2022) finds that increased accountability increases both access and sustainability of sanitation in Kenya.
                                                                                                                       an
      A large amount of research focuses on testing the effects of foreign aid in providing access to sanitation (Abell´
and Alonso, 2022; Gopalan and Rajan, 2016; Ndikumana and Pickbourn, 2017; Pickbourn et al., 2022, among others)
and generally finds a significant and positive effect of aid on access to sanitation. These studies are generally conducted
at the aggregate level using a variety of estimation methods. These researchers argue that international aid affects the
demand for sanitation by changing the marginal utility of sanitation through health education and other information
   7 An  interesting case is provided by Narzetti and Marques (2021), who seem to suggest that in vulnerable areas in Brazil, sanitation issues
have a very low degree of visibility in the eyes of regulators than they do elsewhere. One way to see it is that governmental entities resign from
their roles there, as evidenced by the lack of inclusion and application of regulation and public policies in vulnerable areas.



                                                                        4
channels. On the supply side, foreign aid works to reduce the marginal cost to household as well as decrease the cost
of provision to governments tat otherwise may not be able to afford to provide the infrastructure.
                                   an and Alonso (2022), previous research focuses exclusively either on the demand
        With the exception of Abell´
side or the supply side without integrating supply and demand for access to and use of sanitation. We do so in
this paper. Second, although some papers have mentioned voice and accountability, they do not focus on it as the
central issue in their analyses. Finally, none of these studies establishes the direction of causation between voice and
accountability on the one hand and access and use of sanitation on the other. Our paper addresses these issues by
investigating the causal effects of Voice on sanitation access and does so within a supply and demand framework. In
addition, our study extends the analysis to study rural and urban areas alongside the role of voice and accountability
in closing the rural/urban gap in access to sanitation. Besides using instrumental variables estimation to overcome
possible endogeneity problems, we also use a novel instrument free estimator in kinky least squares developed by
Kiviet (2013, 2022) as a robustness check on our results. Our primary approach in this study is the use of cross-
section data and thus does not explicitly account for time dimension. The use of cross sectional data allows us to use
our estimation methodology and draw causality in the process.

3.     C ONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK :                   DEMAND AND SUPPLY CHANNEL OF VOICE                             & ACCOUNTABILITY
        Access to and use of sanitation services is a two-part problem— a demand side and a supply side issue. In this
section, we provide a brief description of the channels through which Voice can directly broaden access to sanitation
by stimulating the demand and supply.
        On the demand side, households are the main beneficiaries of sanitation services and hence, have the key respon-
sibility of gaining access to it. In low information environments, lack of awareness of the benefits of sanitation as well
as government’s inability or unwillingness to provide sanitation services can lower the demand for these services by
households. The lack of information issue is likely to be more pervasive in rural areas compared to urban areas. Notice
that when the freedom of the media is suppressed by government, certain socioeconomic issues may not be publicly
discussed and certain educative information may not reach the populace. In contrast, a free media can effectively serve
as a medium in communicating key information to citizens on the benefits of sanitation. Consequently, by providing
the appropriate health information and education about the benefits of sanitation through TV and radio advertisements
for example, Voice can stimulate the demand for sanitation, all things equal.
        Formally, we can consider that households maximize a utility function that is positive and concave in sanitation
services and a bundle of all other consumption goods and services (X ) subject to budget constraints. Additionally,
we assume that households gain utility from an exogenous level of Voice v in the country that is complementary to
sanitation services. Specifically, voice increases the marginal utility of sanitation and hence, the demand for sanitation.
Algebraically, the household utility is given as U = u(s, X , v),                   ∂ U /∂ s > 0 and         ∂ U /∂ s∂ v > 0. The last term
captures the complementarity (in the Edgeworth pareto sense) between voice and sanitation services in utility, so that
an improvement in voice and accountability raise the marginal utility of sanitation services and hence, its demand.
We can summarize the demand function for sanitation service as sd = g(v, Z ), where Z captures other factors that may
affect the demand for sanitation and             ∂ sd /∂ v > 0.8
     8 Other factors such as lack of basic income and credit constraints can reduce demand for the adoption of safely managed sanitation services.

Indeed, credit constraints often limits poor households in the adoption of privately optimal technology (e.g., flushable toilets or energy efficient
technologies) that can improve household lifestyle. See for instance, Berkouwer and Dean (2022) for the case of adoption of energy efficient



                                                                         5
      On the supply, there is a key role for governments in broadening access to sanitation. A primary responsibility
of governments is to provide investment in sanitation infrastructure in order to increase sanitation delivery services to
households.9 , 10 Given scarce public resources, there may be incentives for government facing elections not to provide
sanitation services, as they channel these resources to the more visible public goods such as roads, electricity, and
water services that can win them elections relative to low visibility services such as sanitation. However, effective
media can spark social action by highlighting the pervasive nature of lack of sanitation and the role of governments
in facilitating sanitation services, thus increasing its visibility. Another argument, often discounted in the literature,
is the inherent characteristic of sanitation. Sanitation is more of a merit good rather than a pure public good; hence,
governments can remain agnostic on its role in the provision of sanitation services and shift responsibility to the
private sector unless forced to do so through civic/political action.11 An effective media and environment that allows
for peaceful protests can help hold governments accountable by spelling out the government’s role in the provision of
sanitation services.
      As discussed above, politicians are likely to supply more high visibility public goods/services for which they
can take credit and be held publicly accountable by the electorate in order to boost their electoral chances. We assume
that the politician’s objective is to be (re) elected, which is an increasing function of the quantity and quality of public
services (including) sanitation, provided i.e., Pr(E ) = f (s, Ω),               ∂ Pr(E )/∂ s > 0, where Pr(E ) is the probability of the
politician getting (re)elected, Ω is all other variables that affect the politician’s re-election chances, all other variables
as defined above. Sanitation services may not always fall in the priority list of “high-visibility” expenditure programs,
such as electricity, famine relief, road construction, and water, geared to the groups of voters most beneficial to the
incumbent government (Mani and Mukand, 2007) in low income, low information countries. Free media acting as
information multipliers can, not only make sanitation services visible, but can also hold politicians accountable for
lack thereof. We assume that because politicians want to increase their electoral chances, the push for the increase in
sanitation services by the electorate through voice and accountability will induce government to supply more sanitation
services, i.e. ss = ψ (v),        ∂ ss /∂ v > 0,12   13   The role of the media and communicators as information multipliers is
therefore paramount to public advocacy and awareness-raising, which can increase the visibility of sanitation and
hence, access to sanitation.14
technologies in Kenya.
    9 Ashraf et al. (2016) illustrate the complementarity between infrastructure and institutions and shows how institutional weaknesses deter-

mine whether fines, subsidies, both or neither are optimal. With general strong institutions, the latter (i.e., fines and/or subsidies) is one of the
ways government can play a leading role in sanitation delivery services.
   10 A practical example of government’s role in leadership and administrative support and oversight in the provision of sanitation delivery

service is the Greater Accra Metropolitan Area Sanitation and Water Project (GAMA) project in Ghana. GAMA is being implemented by the
Ghana Water Company and the Ministry of Sanitation and Water Resources with funding support from the World Bank.
   11 Merit goods could be, and indeed are, provided through the market, but not necessarily in sufficient quantities to maximize social welfare.
   12 Conceptually, ∂ s/∂ v ̸= 0 since the politician will choose not to respond to the news or might conclude that the available sanitation service

is enough. We rule out these possibilities because we assume that the politician wants to maximize electoral probability and that the level of
sanitation service is very low in our setting.
   13 We also provide a simple stylized model to further explain how voice and accountability may impact access to and use of sanitation. We

embed the concept of visibility of a public good into a tractable political economy framework to model the delivery of sanitation services in a
country with the key tenets of voice and accountability—i.e., free media, transparent elections, and freedom of speech as inputs. See Appendix A
for details. See, https://www.un.org/waterforlifedecade/waterandsustainabledevelopment2015/stakeholders media.shtml for additional details
on the role of the media in raising awareness to the sanitation problem
   14 Another argument discussed in the corruption literature is that governments tend to invest less in small projects where they cannot gain a

lot of rent. In general corrupt governments would prefer to invest more in big infrastructure such as roads where they can get a big share of
the money. However, education or perhaps sanitation projects are not attractive enough for government officials to gain maximum rent (see
for example Mauro, 1998). Here, voice and accountability can serve as first line of imposing checks and balance to reduce corruption in how
funds are used by the government and make sanitation services an important public good that needs attention from politicians by unearthing the



                                                                         6
      Combining the effects that Voice has on the demand for, and supply of sanitation, we see that equilibrium access
to and use of sanitation services in developing countries positively depends on voice and accountability and other
factors—s∗ = s(v, Z ),        ∂ s∗ /∂ v > 0, where s∗ is the observed amount of sanitation services provided in a country. In
this simple formulation, Voice can increase sanitation access through the demand side by households, the supply side
by government, and/or other factors.

4.    DATA AND E STIMATION M ETHODS
This section describes the various layers of the country-level analyses of the influence of Voice on access to sanitation,
discusses key variables employed, as well as the empirical strategies implemented to identify the causal effect of Voice
on access to sanitation. Our analysis focuses on measures of access to sanitation, exploiting variations in cross-country
data. We estimate the effect of voice on: (i) overall access to sanitation, (ii) access to sanitation in rural and urban
areas, and (iii) closing the rural/urban gap in access to sanitation. The first sub-section describes the data while the
second sub-section briefly describes our estimation methods and empirical strategy.

4.1    DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS In this section, we present descriptions and data sources for our main
variables. We utilize data from 73 developing countries to study the effect of voice and accountability on access to
sanitation. We measure our dependent variable, the access to sanitation (S) in four different ways: (1) the proportion
of the entire population using basic sanitation (St ), (2) proportion of rural population using basic sanitation (Sr ), (3)
proportion of urban population using basic sanitation services (Su ), and (4) the rural-urban gap in access to sanitation
(Sg ). The data for S and its various components is from World Development Indicators (2021). Our main explanatory
variable is the institutional variable, voice and accountability (Voice). This variable captures perceptions of the extent
to which a country’s citizens are able to participate in selecting their government, as well as freedom of expression,
freedom of association, and a free media. We employ the standard measure of freedom of expression, of association
and free media as our measure of Voice. The standard measure of this variable ranges from -2.5 to 2.5 with higher
values being associated with better outcomes and hence, higher levels of quality Voice. We use this index because it
provides the most up-to-date measure of broad institutions relevant to the time period we consider. The data onVoice
comes from the Worldwide Governance Indicators constructed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2011).
      We include potentially important control variables in our empirical estimation. In particular, we include GDP per
capita and population density. GDP per capita is included as a measure of income level as well as a proxy for overall
economic development in each country. Per capita GDP is measure is real terms (constant 2015 US$). We expect
a positive relationship between access to sanitation and the level of per capita income across countries. We include
population density in the analysis to control for possible scale or scope economies effects. The relationship between
population density and access to sanitation can be positive or negative. A positive relationship may arise because
higher population density could mean lower administrative costs as well as scale economies and thus translate lower
cost of access to improved sanitation facilities for a larger segment of the population (Gopalan and Rajan, 2016). On
the other hand, sanitation is a rival good at least in low and lower-middle income countries, hence, higher population
density could be associated with lower access to sanitation as a share of the population. Data on per capita GDP and
population density were obtained from the World Development Indicators (World Bank, 2021). Controlling for these
factors may help with minimizing specification errors.
severity of the sanitation problem.



                                                                7
                                                             Table 2: Summary Statistics

        Variable                                                                              obs      Mean         SD        Min.      Max.

        People using sanitation services, total (share of population)                          73       0.63       0.28       0.11       0.99
        People using sanitation services, urban (share of urban population)                    72       0.71       0.25       0.21       0.99
        People using sanitation services, rural (share of rural population)                    72       0.54       0.29       0.05       0.97
        Rural-Urban Gap                                                                        72       0.17       0.12      -0.03       0.49
        Voice and accountability index (lowest = -2.5 highest =2.5)                            73       -0.41      0.69      -1.79       1.04
        Mean year of schooling, 1900                                                           73       0.27       0.39       0.01       1.52
        Log GDP per capita                                                                     72       7.84       0.97       5.85       9.44
        Log population density                                                                 73       4.20       1.10       1.26       7.04

      Notes: SD is the standard deviation of the variables. The mean difference (i.e., rural - urban gap) of 0.17 is statistically different from zero
      with p-value of 0.0002.
      Source: Authors’ illustration from the World Development Indicators World Bank (2021)



     Table 2 presents the summary of the data. The data are for 73 developing countries over the 2002 to 2020 period.
We also report the country-by-country data for the four measures of the dependent variable used in our cross-sectional
analysis in Table 3. We observe from Table 2 that, on average, 63% of the population in our sample has basic sanitation
services. The standard deviation, at 28% is, however, relatively large, indicating high variability in the proportion of
the population using basic sanitation across countries. In particular, several Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries in
the sample, have less than 30% of their population using basic sanitation services. These countries include Sudan
          ote d’Ivoire (27.8%), Zambia (27.7%), Malawi (24.1%), Mozambique (23.7%), the Democratic Republic
(29.1%), Cˆ
of Congo (19.3%), Uganda (18.5%), Liberia (16.2%), Ghana (15.7%), Togo (14.2%), Sierra Leone (13.6%), Benin
(13.2%), and Niger (10.7%) (see, Table 3). In contrast, there are countries in our sample with more than 90% basic
sanitation services access and usage. Additionally, more than a third of countries in our sample have less than 50% of
their population accessing and using sanitation services over the period. Finally, Table 2 reports the summary statistics
for the standard control variables in our estimation—i.e., logarithm of GDP per capita and population density. The
mean value of log GDP per capita is 7.84 with a standard deviation of 0.97 while that of lop population density is
4.20 with a standard error of 1.12. These suggest large variances in per capita income and population density across
countries in our sample.
     We now switch our attention to rural and urban access to sanitation. As shown in Table 2 the means of the
percentage of people with access to sanitation in rural and urban areas are 54% and 71%, respectively, suggesting the
existence of a rural-urban gap in access to sanitation. A simple t-test confirms that the rural-urban gap is statistically
significant at conventional levels (mean difference = 0.17, p−value = 0.0002). The country-by-country summary in
Table 3 provides a granular look and reinforces rural-urban inequality. With the exception of Sri Lanka, Thailand, and
Jamaica, where the rural-urban gap is negative, the gap is positive in all other countries. Additionally, while the rural-
urban gap is highest in Yemen Rep. (49.2%) and Cambodia (42.2%); the gap is generally high in Latin American and
                                                       ote D’Ivoire, Mozambique, Peru, Panama, Niger, Liberia,
African countries— e.g., Argentina, Brazil, Cameroon, Cˆ
Guatemala, Zambia, and Tunisia, where it is above 20 percent. (See, Table 3).15
     It is worth highlighting that while the rural-urban gap is small in countries such as Congo, Dem. Rep., Lesotho,
and Kenya, these countries have low access to sanitation in both rural and urban areas. Hence, the low gap in access to
sanitation is not indicative of a lack of sanitation problem in in these countries; it is in fact the result of a chronically
low access to sanitation in both rural and urban areas. In contrast, countries like Malaysia, Jordan, Serbia, and Costa
  15 Romania   has one of the highest rural-urban gap in access to sanitation outside Latin America and Africa


                                                                             8
                                            Table 3: Percentage of people using basic sanitation services


                                   Access to sanitation (%)                                                       Access to sanitation (%)
 Country                  % Pop.     % Rural Pop.     % Urban Pop.     Gap         Country               % Pop.     % Rural Pop.    % Urban Pop.      Gap
 Malaysia                   98.7         97.3             99.4         2.10        Philippines            70.5          65.9             76.0        10.1
 Jordan                     97.8         96.7             97.9         1.30        South Africa           69.9          63.0             74.5        11.4
 Serbia                     96.7         94.9             98.1         3.20        Myanmar                69.2          64.9             79.9        14.9
 Costa Rica                 96.1         92.9             97.5         4.70        Nicaragua              67.4          54.6             77.1        22.5
 Thailand                   95.8         96.3             94.9         -1.4        Guatemala              65.4          51.7             80.0        28.3
 Albania                    95.5         92.9             98.1         5.10        Indonesia              63.9          52.1             76.1        24.0
 Egypt, Arab Rep.           94.6         92.4             97.5         5.10        Eswatini               57.2          57.0             58.1        1.00
 Mauritius                  93.8         93.0             95.0         1.90        Pakistan               51.4          39.6             73.4        33.8
 T¨urkiye                   93.7         83.9             98.0         14.1        Bolivia                50.3          29.0             61.0        31.9
 Argentina                  91.9         74.3             94.6         20.3        Yemen, Rep.            50.1          34.3             83.6        49.3
 Libya                      91.5          —                —            —          Senegal                48.1          34.7             65.4        30.7
 Fiji                       90.5         86.6             94.3         7.80        Gambia, The            46.5          41.0             49.7        8.70
 Syrian Arab Republic       90.5         88.1             92.6         4.50        Nepal                  46.2          44.5             55.1        10.6
 Cuba                       89.4         82.1             91.7         9.60        India                  45.4          36.8             64.8        28.0
 Tunisia                    87.9         73.0             95.5         22.5        Cambodia               41.2          32.5             74.7        42.2
 Russian Federation         87.1         66.3             94.5         28.2        Cameroon               41.0          23.3             57.2        33.9
 Sri Lanka                  86.8         87.1             85.6         -1.4        Bangladesh             40.5          37.5             48.0        10.5
 Algeria                    86.4         77.2             90.8         13.7        Zimbabwe               40.5          33.8             53.9        20.1
 Bulgaria                   85.9         83.7             86.8         3.10        Afghanistan            36.6          32.7             48.7        16.0
 Belize                     85.9         82.5             90.0         7.50        Lesotho                32.2          31.1             35.8        4.70
 Mexico                     85.8         72.0             89.9         17.9        Kenya                  31.9          30.7             35.5        4.80
 Iran, Islamic Rep.         85.6         73.2             90.9         17.7        Mali                   31.2          22.8             45.9        23.1
 Iraq                       85.5         77.9             88.9         11.0        Sudan                  29.3          18.3             51.2        32.9
 Colombia                   85.3         72.4             88.9         16.5        Haiti                  28.3          19.2             37.9        18.7
 Jamaica                    84.9         86.7             83.5         -3.2        Cˆote d’Ivoire         27.8          13.6             43.4        29.8
 Guyana                     83.5         81.5             88.8         7.30        Zambia                 27.7          17.4             43.6        26.3
 El Salvador                83.2         72.8             88.5         15.6        Malawi                 24.1          22.4             33.2        10.8
 Paraguay                   83.1         72.0             90.9         18.8        Mozambique             23.7          12.3             46.9        34.6
 Dominican Republic         82.9         73.9             86.0         12.1        Congo, Dem. Rep.       19.3          16.9             22.5        5.60
 Brazil                     82.6         51.0             88.5         37.5        Uganda                 18.5          16.0             28.4        12.4
 Ecuador                    81.6         72.9             86.9         13.9        Liberia                16.2          5.30             27.9        22.6
 Romania                    80.0         63.4             94.4         30.9        Ghana                  15.7          10.1             21.0        10.9
 Morocco                    78.8         62.2             90.6         28.4        Togo                   14.2          5.50             28.1        22.6
 China                      77.0         67.5             87.3         19.8        Sierra Leone           13.6          7.20             23.6        16.3
 Honduras                   74.8         67.3             81.9         14.6        Benin                  13.2          5.30             23.4        18.1
 Panama                     74.2         55.7             83.9         28.2        Niger                  10.7          5.40             37.9        32.5
 Peru                       72.1         46.4             80.1         33.7
 Notes: Access to sanitation is People using at least basic sanitation services (% of population). Gap is the difference between People using at least basic
sanitation services, urban (% of urban population) and People using at least basic sanitation services, rural (% of rural population).
 Source: Authors’ illustration from the World Development Indicators World Bank (2021).



Rica have low rural-urban gaps because access to sanitation in both areas is high.

4.2    I NSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE A difficulty in estimating the effect of Voice on access to and use of sanitation is
the possible endogeneity of Voice. While Voice may have a positive effect on access to sanitation, sanitation could
also improve human capital and economic and institutional development of which Voice is a part. It is also possible
that both Voice and access to sanitation are being driven by an unobserved common factor. In addition to these factors,
institutional variables, such as Voice are measured with substantial errors (Rodrik et al., 2004). All these factors could
introduce endogeneity when Voice is used in a regression analysis, making it difficult to infer causal effects.
       Given the possible endogeneity of our independent variable, OLS estimates are likely to be biased. To address
this endogeneity issue, we use primary school enrollment rate in 1900 as an instrument to achieving identification. The
core argument is that historical levels of education plays an important role in teaching civic education and highlighting
the role of governments while raising awareness of basic individual rights in civil society (Glaeser et al., 2007).
This means that countries with historically higher levels of education will likely have societies with active civic


                                                                              9
participation. Moreover, with citizens being aware of their rights, they are more likely to push governments, through
voting, mobilization and demonstrations, to act to address socioeconomic issues. Such civic participation induced
by education can be passed down to later generations. Consequently, historical levels of education can be a durable
good that impacts today’s Voice in those countries. Beyond this intuitive explanation, a long-standing theory in
political science argues that education is a key determinant of the emergence and sustainability of democracy, because
it promotes political participation at the individual level and fosters a collective sense of civic duty. Specifically,
findings from studies such as Lutz, Cuaresma, and Abbasi-Shavazi (2010) confirms a strong positive relationship
between past levels of education and democracy even after controlling for many other country characteristics. While
current levels of Voice may be correlated with primary school school enrollment in 1900, it is unlikely that primary
school enrolment in 1900 will be correlated with current levels of access and use of basic sanitation. This makes
primary school enrolment in 1900 a potentially good instrument for Voice. In summary, we can exploit a measure of
education from historical times as an instrument for today’s level of Voice across countries while assuming that it only
impacts current levels of access to sanitation through its correlation with Voice.
      In addition to using instrumental variable estimation, we apply a novel instrument-free identification strategy in
kinky least squares (KLS), a non-parametric estimator, developed by Kiviet (2020, 2022). The primary motivation
for this additional empirical step is as follows: Our model is a just-identified model hence, we cannot test whether
our proposed instrument does not violate the exclusion restriction. The KLS estimator, which is an instrument-
free estimator, allows us to formally test the exclusion restriction to validate our instrumental variable estimations.
Furthermore, the KLS serves as an alternative estimator to examine the effect of Voice on access to sanitation, which
we can compare with the estimates from the instrumental variable estimation. We also apply the KLS estimator to
panel data to exploit the relevance of time dimension in the causal effect in question. Consequently, the KLS is used
for model validation and robustness exercises. We discuss the details of the KLS estimator in Section 5.4.

4.3   E MPIRICAL STRATEGY The main regression equation we estimate is:

                                                                    ′
                                            Si = α + β1 Voicei + Xi β2 + εi ,                                        (1)

where the subscript i refers to countries, Si is access to sanitation in country i, Voice is voice and accountability, X
is a vector of the two control variables in our models, ε is a stochastic error term, and α and β are coefficients to
be estimated. We begin with a parsimonious specification of a bivariate regression of access to sanitation on voice
and accountability. We then proceed to our baseline estimation that includes the standard covarates that may affect
access to sanitation. We follow the convention in the sanitation literature in specifying the covariates. The analysis
implements empirical strategies to mitigate issues of endogeneity. To address these endogeneity issues, we employ
an instrumental variable estimator for the causal analysis. Our instrument for Voice in our cross-country analysis is
primary school enrollment in 1900.
We present ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates to show the correlation between Voice access to sanitation. We
present the bivariate estimation as well as our estimations where we include the standard control variables. The
estimates from the OLS estimates will help contextualize the severity of the endogeneity issue, which the 2SLS
estimator will address. After presenting the OLS estimates, we proceed to present and discuss the 2SLS estimates.
In addition to the OLS and the IV estimates, we also use an instrument-free non-parametric estimator, Kinky Least


                                                           10
Square (KLS) estimator to estimate the model as an added robustness check. In all the regressions, we control for
geographical differences by including regional dummies. Throughout the paper, the standard errors that we report are
robust against arbitrary heteroskedasticity.

5.    R ESULTS

5.1   O RDINARY LEAST SQUARE REGRESSIONS Table 4 presents results from the OLS regressions showing the
correlation between basic sanitation use and Voice in total, rural and urban populations. Before proceeding to discuss
the results, a few features of the table needs highlighting: Odd numbered columns report the results from the bivariate
specification whereas even number columns report results that include the control variables in the regression model.
      We now discuss the results for column 1 and 2. While the estimated coefficients are positive, they are small and
statistically insignificant (Column 1). Furthermore, once we control for the level of GDP per capita and log population
density, the coefficient of Voice becomes even smaller, close to zero and remains statistically insignificant. The
relationship between per capita income and basic sanitation use is positive and statistically significant at conventional
levels in all the regressions. On the other hand, we find no significant relationship between access to sanitation and
population density. These results generally hold for access to sanitation in urban and rural areas (Columns 3 – 6).


                    Table 4: Ordinary least squares (OLS) cross-country regressions (Dependent variable: Sanitation)

                                                             Total                      Urban                        Rural
                                                       (1)             (2)        (3)            (4)           (5)            (6)

              Voice and accountability              0.074          0.006        0.053          0.001        0.083          0.012
                                                  (0.047)        (0.024)      (0.041)        (0.022)      (0.053)        (0.033)
              log real GDP per capita                          0.197***                   0.152***                     0.191***
                                                                 (0.025)                    (0.023)                      (0.031)
              log population density                               0.012                      -0.007                       0.031
                                                                 (0.015)                     (0.015)                     (0.022)

              Regional dummies                        Yes              Yes       Yes             Yes          Yes            Yes
              R-squared                             0.677            0.858     0.716           0.857        0.578          0.751
              Observations                             73               72        72              71           72             71
              Notes: ∗∗∗ indicates significance at the 1% and 5% level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. South Asia is the region
             excluded in the regional dummies.



      The finding of no significant relationship between access to sanitation and Voice is not surprising for the follow-
ing reasons: The OLS regression is likely to be plagued with endogeneity problems. Consequently, the OLS estimates
can not be relied on for causal inference. We therefore employ instrumental variable estimation to address the possible
endogeneity problem and draw casual inference on the relationship between Voice and sanitation access and use.

5.2   I NSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES ESTIMATION Table 5 presents the results from the two-stage least squares (2SLS)
model. Odd (even) numbered columns present results for estimations where we exclude (include) the standard control
variables. Panel A of the table reports the 2SLS estimates of the effect of Voice on access to sanitation services.




                                                                         11
                                         Table 5: The effect of voice and accountability on access to sanitation

                                                               Full Population                  Urban Population                  Rural Population
                                                         (1)               (2)                (3)              (4)              (5)              (6)

    Panel A: Second-stage regression (Dependent variable is access to sanitation)
    Voice and accountability                         0.323***            0.177**          0.241***           0.127*          0.423***         0.322**
                                                      (0.079)            (0.076)           (0.073)           (0.067)          (0.090)         (0.126)
    AR confidence intervals                         [0.16, 0.50]       [0.06, 0.44]      [0.09, 0.39]     [0.01, 0.34]      [0.27, 0.65]     [0.15, 0.8]

    log real GDP per capita                                             0.150***                            0.117***                           0.103
                                                                         (0.040)                             (0.031)                          (0.065)
    log population density                                                -0.006                              -0.017                           0.004
                                                                         (0.016)                             (0.014)                          (0.024)


    Panel B: First-stage regression (Dependent variable is voice)
    Mean years of schooling, 1900                    0.826***           0.689***          0.823***          0.680***         0.823***        0.680***
                                                      (0.172)            (0.204)           (0.172)           (0.204)          (0.172)         (0.204)

    Regional dummies                                    Yes                Yes               Yes               Yes              Yes             Yes
    R-squared                                          0.412              0.750             0.520             0.780            0.105           0.410
    Observations                                         73                 72                72               71                72              71
    F-stat of excl. instruments                        23.01              11.36             22.84             11.17            22.84           11.17
    Effective F-stat of excl. instruments              14.44               8.99             14.23             8.677            14.23           8.677
    Kleibergen & Paap (2006) test ( p-value)           0.009              0.007             0.009             0.007            0.009           0.007

    Notes: ∗∗∗ and ∗∗ indicate significance at the 1% and 5% level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. AR confidence intervals correspond to
   the 95% Anderson-Rubin confidence intervals robust against weak instruments and heteroscedasticity. The p-values of the Kleibergen & Paap
   (2006) test correspond to a test in which the null hypothesis is that the equation is underidentified, and under the null, the statistic is distributed as
   chi-squared.



      We begin by discussing the results in column 1 of Table 5, where we only include Voice and regional dummies
in the model. The dummies of the regions included are Europe and Central Asia, Middle East and North Africa,
East Asia and Pacific, Sub-Sahara Africa, Latin America and the Caribbean. The omitted group is South Asia. From
column 1, we see that Voice has a large and positive effect on access to sanitation with a coefficient of 0.323, which is
fairly precisely estimated, with standard error of 0.079. This results implies that a one unit increase in Voice increases
access to sanitation by 32.3 percentage points. Furthermore, Panel B of the Table shows that our instrumental variable
explains a large proportion of the variation in Voice and is statistically significant showing that there is a strong first-
stage association with Voice. This suggests that our instrument passes the instrumental relevance test. The associated
F-statistic and Effective F-statistic of excluded instrument are approximately 23 and 14, respectively. This is larger
than the rule-of-thumb value of 10 (see Andrews et al., 2018). Furthermore, the AR confidence interval shows that the
interval excludes a zero effect.
      Column 2 in Table 5 reports the results from the specification that includes the control variables. The controls
are the log income per capita and the log population density. Introducing these controls almost halves the coefficient
of voice to 0.177 implying that a unit increase in Voice increases access to sanitation by 17.7 percentage points. The
coefficient is also statistically significant at the 5% level and it is fairly precisely estimated, with standard errors of
0.076. Additionally, the first-stage regression in Panel B for column 2 shows that the coefficient of the instrumen-
tal variable is large and statistically significant. However, the associated F-statistic and the Effective F-statistic of
excluded instrument are 11.36 and 8.99, respectively. These values are close to the Staiger and Stock (1997) rule-of-
thumb value of 10 although the F-statistic is marginally greater than 10. Given the closeness of the Effective F statistic
to the threshold value, we rely on the AR confidence interval for inference. The AR confidence interval clearly shows


                                                                                   12
that the effect of Voice on basic sanitation service access and use exclude a zero effect.
      Columns 3–6 in Table 5, present the results for urban and rural areas. The coefficient estimates on Voice is fairly
large and statistically significant at least at the 10% level in all columns. A unit increase in voice and accountability
causes an increase in access to sanitation by approximately 13 and 32 percentage points in urban and rural areas,
respectively. The estimates suggest that the relationship between Voice and sanitation access is stronger in rural areas
than in urban areas. Similar to the results for the full population, Panel B of the Table shows that the coefficient of
the instrumental variable is large and statistically significant. The effective F-statistic for the even numbered columns
(i.e., Columns 4 and 6) are smaller than the rule-of-thumb of 10. Hence, we again rely on the AR confidence interval
for inference. The interval does not include a zero. We can therefore conclude that Voice has an unambiguous positive
impact on broadening access to sanitation in the developing countries we consider. This implies that improvements in
the populace’s ability to actively participate in selecting governments, freedom of speech through protests, and strong
and free press can help broaden access to sanitation in developing countries via the mechanisms previously discussed.

5.3   T HE RURAL - URBAN GAP As discussed earlier, there exists a significant rural-urban gap in access to sanitation
in developing countries (Table 6). The results in Table 5 provides a preamble for the question of whether Voice can
serve as an effective vehicle to help close this gap in access to sanitation. Specifically, Table 5 showed that while Voice
has positive effect on access to sanitation in both rural and urban areas, the effect is generally larger in rural areas than
in urban areas. In this section, we investigate whether Voice can help close this gap by regressing the gap, measured
as the difference between the share of rural population with sanitation access and the share of urban population with
sanitation access, on Voice.
                                              Table 6: The effect of voice on the rural-urban gap

                                                                                         (1)                    (2)

                      Panel A: OLS estimates
                      Voice and accountability                                          -0.029                 -0.011
                                                                                       (0.024)                (0.023)


                      Panel B: Two stage least squares estimates
                      Voice and accountability                                       -0.1833∗∗∗              -0.195∗∗
                                                                                       (0.057)                (0.082)

                      AR confidence intervals                                     [-0.344,-0.094]        [-0.503,-0.082]

                      Regional dummies                                                   Yes                    Yes
                      Other controls                                                     No                     Yes
                      Number of countries                                                72                      72
                      First-stage Effective F-statistic                                 14.28                  11.17
                      First-stage F-statistic                                           22.84                   8.68
                      Kleibergen & Paap (2006) test (p value)                           0.009                  0.007
                     Notes: *** p <0.01, ** p <0.05, * p <0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. AR confidence in-
                    tervals correspond to the 95% Anderson-Rubin confidence intervals robust against weak instruments and
                    heteroscedasticity. The p-values of the Kleibergen & Paap (2006) test correspond to a test in which the
                    null hypothesis is that the equation is underidentified, and under the null, the statistic is distributed as chi-
                    squared. The dependent variable is rural-urban gap in access to sanitation


      Table 6 presents the results. We include the estimations from the OLS estimator for completeness. Two findings
stand out. First, the estimates reveal that that there is a strong, negative, and statistically significant effect of Voice
on the rural-urban gap. Increased Voice is likely to increase sanitation access and use in rural areas faster than it will


                                                                          13
be for urban areas, which generally may be nearing the upper limit of access (100%) hence, the gap is likely to close
with increased Voice.16 This suggests that improvement in institutions along the lines of which the populace have the
ability to participate in selecting government and express freedom through associations and free media can narrow the
rural-urban gap.

5.4      ROBUSTNESS , VALIDITY, AND SENSITIVITY In this section we present robustness checks along the lines
of sensitivity analysis and validity of our instrumental variable. We also present estimation results from the KLS
estimator for both cross-section data and panel data. The latter allows as to control for time fixed effects.

5.4.1       S ENSITIVITY ANALYSIS In this section, we conduct sensitivity analysis to ensure that the positive effect of
Voice on access to sanitation is not driven by a set of outlier countries or a specific region. To this end, we re-estimate
the model with data which exclude countries from one regional grouping at a time from the full sample.


                                        Table 7: Sensitivity analysis on the effect of voice on access to sanitation

                                                                             Region Excluded in the Estimation
                                                  South Asia              EAP                MENA              EAP               SSA              LAC

       Panel A: Second-stage regression (Dependent variable is access to sanitation)
       Voice and accountability                    0.172**              0.214**              0.184**          0.158**          0.184*             0.137
                                                   (0.075)              (0.094)              (0.080)          (0.065)          (0.104)           (0.097)
       AR confidence intervals                   [0.06, 0.43]         [0.08, 0.58]         [0.06, 0.46]    [ 0.05, 0.37]     [0.03, 0.59]     [-0.02, 0.52]

       Regional dummies                               Yes                 Yes                  Yes              Yes              Yes              Yes
       Other controls                                 Yes                 Yes                  Yes              Yes              Yes              Yes
       Observations                                    66                  66                   63              64                49               52
       F-stat of excl. instruments                   11.42               8.53                 10.90            12.34            6.00             7.81
       Effective F-stat of excl. instruments          8.70                7.91                 7.92            10.43             5.39             5.16
       Kleibergen & Paap test (p value)              0.007               0.012                0.008            0.005            0.026            0.075
       Notes: ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , and ∗ indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. AR confidence intervals correspond
      to the 95% Anderson-Rubin confidence intervals robust against weak instruments and heteroscedasticity. The p-values of the Kleibergen & Paap
      (2006) test correspond to a test in which the null hypothesis is that the equation is underidentified, and under the null, the statistic is distributed as
      chi-squared. ECA is Europe & Central Asia, MENA is Middle East & North Africa, East Asia & Pacific is EAP, sub-Saharan Africa is SSA, and
      Latin American and Caribbean is LAC.



        Table 7 reports the estimates from the sensitivity exercise. All regressions include regional dummies and the
standard control variables as in log GDP per capita and the log population density. The results show that there is
sufficient evidence of a positive and statistically significant effect of Voice on access to sanitation when a region is
excluded from the sample. Specifically, excluding countries in South Asia, Europe and Central Asia (ECA), Middle
East and North Africa (MENA), East Asia and Pacific (EAP) or Sub-Sahara Africa (SSA) from the sample does not
impact the positive effect or the statistical significance of the effect. However, when Latin America and Caribbean
(LAC) countries are excluded from the sample, the coefficient remains positive but statistically insignificant. More
importantly, the AR confidence include zero, suggesting that we can not rule out a zero effect for some regions in the
sample. However, we note that the fact that five out of the six sensitivity exercise provide strong evidence in support
of the conclusion that Voice increases the percentage of people using basic sanitation services is reassuring.
  16 After all, sanitation use in urban areas is getting close to the upper limit in most regions, hence can only grow slowly while low levels of

access in rural areas imply that it can grow faster than in urban areas.




                                                                                  14
5.4.2    A N INSTRUMENT- FREE ESTIMATOR So far we have used instrumental variable estimation to establish a
causal effect of Voice and accountability on access to sanitation. In this section, we apply a novel instrument-free
non-parametric estimator, the kinky least squares (KLS) estimator, recently developed by Kiviet (2013, 2020, 2022).
Before discussing the results, we provide a brief background on the estimator. The estimator is designed as a comple-
ment, and in scenarios where obtaining valid and relevant instrument is difficult, a viable alternative to the standard
IV estimator.
      The primary benefit of the KLS is that it is an instrument-free estimator under more relaxed assumptions. In
the context of valid inference under conventional asymptotic theory, instrumental variables must be relevant and ex-
ogenous. The former condition requires that the instruments are sufficiently strongly correlated with the endogenous
regressor(s) while the second condition requires that the instrument is directly related to the dependent variable (ex-
clusion restriction) (Kripfganz and Kiviet, 2021). The KLS utilizes an identification strategy that does not rely on
such exclusion restrictions but instead imposes assumptions on the degree of regressor endogeneity, which is left un-
restricted in an IV estimation Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021). More precisely, the KLS makes use of a non-orthgonality
condition for the endogenous regressor in the model, which is a function of the correlation coefficient between the
endogenous regressor and the error term and the standard deviation of the endogenous variable and the error term in
the regression (see, Kiviet, 2022; Kripfganz and Kiviet, 2021, for additional details). Consequently, for identification
of the regression coefficient of the endogenous variable, the KLS restricts the plausible correlation of the regressor
with the error term within plausible bounds. In this case, no excluded instruments are needed, and instead, the bias of
the OLS estimator is analytically corrected for all values on a grid of endogeneity correlations (Kripfganz and Kiviet,
2021).
      The KLS estimator is given by:


                                               β1,KLS = β1,OLS − Bias Correction(ρ ),

where ρ is the unknown correlation coefficient, β1,KLS is the KLS estimator, and β1,OLS is the standard OLS estimator,
which is inconsistent when ρ is non-zero. The bias correction term, which is analytically derived and described in
Kiviet (2020, 2022); Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021) is a function of ρ , the estimated variance of the OLS residual, the
variance of the explanatory variable, covariance between the explanatory variable and the covariates.17 The KLS
estimator βKLS coincides with the standard OLS estimator βOLS if ρ is equal zero. To estimate βKLS , the researcher has
to postulate values for ρ , which includes the direction of bias of the OLS estimator. For a reasonably narrow range
of postulated endogeneity correlations, the KLS confidence intervals are — as a general rule— narrower than those
from 2SLS estimations, in particular if the instruments are relatively weak (Kripfganz and Kiviet, 2021). The KLS
inference in this case can be more informative while avoiding the challenges associated with finding strong and valid
external instruments. As described in Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021), the KLS approach enables testing of any potential
exclusion restrictions, which is not plausible under a just-identified model like our model in section 5.
      In our IV-estimation, it is evident that once we include the control variables in the specification, the standard F-
statistic for the excluded instrument gets close to the rule-of-thumb value of 10. Furthermore, the effective F-statistics
is consistently less than 10, although close, in several of the regressions. Although the robust AR confidence intervals
  17 See Kripfganz et al. (2021) and Kiviet (2020, 2022) for detailed discussion on the analytical derivation of the bias correction term. For

exposition purposes we present the full mathematical representation of the KLS estimator in the appendix.


                                                                     15
suggests that there may not be any issues related to weak instruments, the large differences between the OLS and
IV estimates raises concerns other concerns of the relevance of the instruments.(Kiviet, 2020, 2022; Kripfganz and
Kiviet, 2021).18 As a first step, we employ the KLS estimator as an additional estimator to help reinforce our results.
Because the KLS estimator does not rely on instruments, we are able to use it along with the 2SLS estimation to test
for any potential exclusion restriction violation in our just-identified model. In particular, it allows the user to assess
the validity of previously untestable just-identifying exclusion restrictions. The KLS estimator therefore serves as
both a complement to the IV-estimation as well as a validation tool.

5.4.3     K LS RESULTS Because the correlation coefficient, ρ , is unknown, the KLS requires the postulation of ad-
missible correlation of the regressors with the error term within plausible bounds. To do so, we combine information
from the OLS and IV estimates in previous sections for guidance. The coefficients of Voice from the OLS and IV
estimations in Tables 4 and 5 respectively suggest that the OLS estimator is downward biased in our case. To this
end, we specify a negative sign for the correlation as well as a reasonable interval of -0.6 to -0.2 for the unknown
correlation coefficient, ρ . Given that the KLS requires a postulated interval, as a more illuminating approach, the
KLS plots the estimated coefficient with their corresponding 95% confidence intervals over the chosen range of endo-
geneity correlations (i.e., -0.6 to -0.2). This shows immediately for which values of the correlation coefficient we can
reject (or not reject) the null hypothesis that a coefficient of interest equals a certain value. Furthermore, we are able
to check whether the coefficient is statistically significantly different from zero. We also report formal exclusion test
for our instrumental variable from postestimation tests from the KLS estimator.19
      Figure 1 presents the results. The top row of the figure, Panels A and B, reports the estimates of the effect of
voice on access to sanitation from the KLS estimator and the IV-regression. The light gray shaded area is the 95%
confidence for the 2SLS estimator and the solid black line is the point estimate from the 2SLS estimator of Voice, β1,IV .
The dark gray shaded area in Panels A and B is the 95% confidence interval for the KLS estimate and the dashed lines
are the KLS point estimates (β1,KLS ) of Voice corresponding to the postulated correlation coefficients given between
-0.6 and -0.2. Panel A is the specification with no control variables and Panel B is the model with control variables.
Both specifications include the regional dummies. The bottom figures, Panel C and D report the respective exclusion
tests for the instrument used in the IV regressions in Panel A and B.
      It is clear from panels A and B of figure 1 that for plausible range of the postulated values of the correlation
coefficient, Voice has an unambiguous and statistically significant effect on access to sanitation. Two notable points
need further highlighting: First, the effect of Voice from the KLS is decreasing in the postulated values of the corre-
lation coefficient. Recall that the OLS estimates of the coefficient of voice and accountability are biased downwards.
Hence, because the KLS estimator coincides with the OLS estimator at ρ = 0, it is intuitive to see that as the postu-
lated endogeneity gets closer to zero, the KLS estimates of the effect of Voice will get closer to the OLS estimate.20
Second, at approximately -0.56 and -0.52 for the postulated correlation coefficient in panel A and B, respectively, the
estimates from the KLS coincides with the estimate from the 2SLS (i.e., β1,KLS = β1,IV ). Additionally, for most of
the postulated values, the KLS confidence lies within the confidence interval associated with the IV-estimation. This
  18 We thank Aart Kraay and S. Kripfganz for raising this issue.   We intend on further investigating this issue and expanding the KLS postulated
correlation interval to include positive correlation. The analysis is ongoing.
   19 We use the Stata command kinkreg developed by Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021) to implement the KLS estimations and postestimations.
   20 Indeed, Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021) show that the KLS estimator β
                                                                           1,KLS is by construction, point-symmetric around ρ = 0 and that β1,KLS
is a monotonically decreasing function in ρ . See also Kiviet (2020) and Kiviet (2022) for additional details.



                                                                       16
                                  Figure 1: KLS estimation and validation of the effect of voice and accountability




 Notes: Panels A and B compare the KLS and 2SLS coefficient estimates and reports their corresponding 95% confidence intervals. The light gray shaded area
is 95% confidence for the 2SLS estimator and the solid black line is the point estimate from the 2SLS estimator. The dark gray shaded area in Panels A and B
is the 95% confidence for the KLS estimate and the dashed lines are the coefficient point estimates of voice and accountability corresponding to the postulated
correlation coefficients given between -0.6 and -0.2. Panel C and D report the p-value for F-statistic for null hypothesis that the instrument (predicted loan
disbursements) is validly excluded from the model. The instrument for the IV estimation in Panels A and B is the mean years of schooling in 1900.



reinforce the reliability of our results from the instrumental variable regressions in Table 5.
          Finally, we provide a test of exclusion of our instrumental variable, average years of schooling in 1900. As
discussed in Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021), effectively the KLS exclusion restriction test is asymptotically equivalent to
a test of coefficient equality between the KLS and 2SLS estimates, assuming that our prior belief about the endogeneity
correlation is correct. The p-values from Panel C and D, shows that for both model specifications we fail to reject
the null hypothesis of the exclusion test implying that the instrument used is indeed a valid instrument. Interestingly,
it can be observed from the figure that the point at which the p-value for the exclusion test for the instrument peaks
corresponds to the point where the KLS and IV-estimate intersect. In general, the results show that KLS and the 2SLS
estimators are both consistent. In summary, the KLS estimator reinforces our baseline results.

5.4.4       PANEL A NALYSIS WITH KLS In this section, we turn to using panel analysis, which allows us to consider
both the cross-section and time dimension of the data. This further permits us to address important endogeneity
issues. While the use of panel data offers richer insights into our key question, we do not have a relevant and valid
time varying instrument hence, we can not utilize IV-type estimation. However, in the absence of a ”good” instrument,
we can employ the instrument-free KLS panel estimator for causal analysis.                              21

  21 Itis worth mentioning that, instrument-free inference is not a panacea to the problems of instrument based methods (Kripfganz and
Kiviet, 2021). It replaces one set of possibly strong though speculative assumptions with another set of relatively less restrictive conjectural



                                                                             17
                                                   We have some prior information from the IV-KLS analysis from above that informs us about the sign of the
endogeneity. The KLS estimates in Figure 1 suggests that the plausible range of the correlation coefficient lies ap-
proximately between -0.6 to -0.1; this also lies within the confidence interval of the IV estimates. For our panel
estimation we specify a negative sign for the endogeneity coefficient, ρ , and restrict is to lie between zero and -0.2.22
                                                   We now estimate the panel data equivalent version of Equation 1 given as

                                                                                                                                                                                ′
                                                                                                  Sit = αi + δ t + β1 Voiceit + Xit β2 + εit ,                                                                                                 (2)


where the subscript i refers to countries and t refers to time in year, αi and δ are country fixed-effects and time effects
respectively, and all other variables as defined above.

                                                                 Figure 2: KLS Panel-data estimates of the effect of voice & accountability on access to sanitation

                                                           Panel A: Total access to sanitation
                                                                                                                                                                                          Panel B: Urban access to sanitation
                                             .25
  Estimated Voice & Accountability Coefficient




                                                                                                                            Estimated Voice & Accountability Coefficient
                                                                                                                                                                     .3
                                    .2




                                                                                                                                                     .2
                   .1    .15




                                                                                                                                        .1
   0      .05




                                                                                                                            0




                                                   −.2         −.15              −.1               −.05           0                                                           −.2              −.15              −.1               −.05        0
                                                            Postulated endogeneity of Voice & Accountability                                                                                Postulated endogeneity of Voice & Accountability

                                                                   KLS >=95% CI                KLS estimate                                                                                        KLS >=95% CI                KLS estimate




                                                           Panel B: Rural access to sanitation                                                                                      Panel D: Rural-Urban gap in access to sanitation
                                                                                                                                                                         .3
  Estimated Voice & Accountability Coefficient




                                                                                                                              Estimated Voice & Accountability Coefficient
                                           .3




                                                                                                                                                              .2
                           .2




                                                                                                                                                  .1
              .1




                                                                                                                            −.1        0
  0




                                                   −.2         −.15              −.1               −.05           0                                                           −.2              −.15              −.1               −.05        0
                                                            Postulated endogeneity of Voice & Accountability                                                                                Postulated endogeneity of Voice & Accountability

                                                                   KLS >=95% CI                KLS estimate                                                                                        KLS >=95% CI                KLS estimate




 Notes: The light gray shaded area in Panel A is the 95% confidence for the KLS estimate and the solid blue line is the coefficient point estimates of voice and
accountability corresponding to the postulated correlation coefficient, ρ set between -0.2 and 0. We control for country-specific effects and time-specific effect.
The estimation comprise 73 countries over the period 2002-2020 with a total number of observation of 1,378.


                                                   Figure 2 depicts the results for the KLS panel estimates. For the admissible range of correlation coefficients
(ρ < 0), we find strong evidence that Voice has a positive and statistically significant impact on access to sanitation
(Panel A, B, and C). Additionally, Panel D in the figure shows that Voice helps to close the rural-urban gap in access
to sanitation. These panel-data results complements the findings from the cross-sectional analysis.

assumptions. As pointed out by the authors, in several applications, it might be easier to specify a credible range for the correlation of an
endogenous regressor with the error term than to convincingly present strong and valid instruments. However, on one hand, if the postulated
endogeneity range is too narrow, it may not include the true correlation value, potentially leading to serious bias. In contrast, if it is too wide,
the resulting confidence intervals could be less informative than those from a 2SLS estimation with strong and valid instruments.
   22 We conduct preliminary estimation with ρ specified between (-0.6, 0). We found that the corresponding confidence intervals for ρ values

less than -0.25 are extremely wide. We therefore rule out these values for the purpose of inference.



                                                                                                                      18
6.   C ONCLUSION AND POLICY DISCUSSION
     Globally, 2.4 billion people live without access to basic sanitation. Developing countries also face serious gover-
nance challenges due to weak political institutions and processes. In this paper, we estimate the causal effect of voice
and accountability, characterized broadly as transparent electoral processes, free media, and freedom of expression,
on access to sanitation. Our core argument is that voice and accountability increase sanitation’s visibility as a public
good and raise awareness of its benefits, thereby increasing the supply and demand for sanitation services and access
to sanitation. In a cross-section of 73 developing countries, we find a positive and economically significant effect of
voice and accountability on access to sanitation. Importantly, voice and accountability can be used as an effective
vehicle to close the persistent rural-urban inequality in access to sanitation. Our findings reinforce the argument that
the institutionalization of monitoring and evaluation systems for sanitation delivery that sufficiently relies on citizens’
voices and perceptions is not a luxury of the rich. Instead, it is relevant to the world’s poor as its tenets, like the power
of electoral incentives and free media, can shape the demand and distribution of sanitation services.
     Our results are consistent with the results of previous research that finds that increased resources and education
increases access to and use of sanitation services. However, our results are also different from the results of previous
research. This is one of the few studies that establishes a causal relationship between voice and accountability and
access to and use of sanitation services. While most research on sanitation provision focuses on the effects of external
aid to increase the demand for and supply of sanitation, this study focuses on free media, freedom of expression, and
accountability as the drivers of increased provision and use of sanitation. In this regard, increased access to and use
of sanitation can be seen as the results of domestic institution building, hence more durable than the oft reliance on
external aid.
     This paper analyzed access to and use of sanitation as the results of a combination of supply and demand forces.
In the empirical analyses, we did not distinguish between demand side effects and supply side effects; distinctions
that may be important in policy formulation and implementation. In the robustness exercise, we extend our analysis
to panel data to capture the relevance of the time dimension in the relationship in question. Our baseline empirical
analyses (i.e., the instrumental variable estimation) was based on cross-country data; hence, we were not able to
analyze how the relationship between voice and accountability and sanitation use across countries changed over time.
Such changes could be potentially important and significantly affect our results. Our results should therefore be
interpreted with these caveats.




                                                             19
R EFERENCES
       ´ , J. AND J. A. A LONSO (2022): “Promoting global access to water and sanitation: A supply and demand
A BELL AN
  perspective,” Water Resources and Economics, 38, 100194.
A DIL , S., M. NADEEM , AND I. M ALIK (2021): “Exploring the important determinants of access to safe drinking
  water and improved sanitation in Punjab, Pakistan,” Water Policy, 23, 970–984.
A DUKIA , A. (2017): “Sanitation and Education,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 9, 23–59.
A LEXANDER , C. C., S. S HRESTHA , M. D. T OUNKARA , S. C OOPER , L. H UNT, T. H. H OJ , K. D EARDEN ,
  D. K EZAKUBI , V. ATUGONZA , J. W EST, ET AL . (2019): “Media access is associated with knowledge of op-
  timal water, sanitation and hygiene practices in Tanzania,” International journal of environmental research and
  public health, 16, 1963.
     ´ , M. L., H. D JEBBARI , AND A. J. P ICKERING (2020): “A community-based program promotes sanitation,”
A LZ UA
  Economic Development and Cultural Change, 68, 357–390.
A NBARCI , N., M. E SCALERAS , AND C. R EGISTER (2009): “The Ill Effects of Public Sector Corruption in the Water
  and Sanitation Sector,” Land Economics, 85, 363–377.
A NDREWS , I., S. JAMES , S. L IYANG , ET AL . (2018): “Weak Instruments in IV Regression: Theory and Practice,”
  Annual Review of Economics.
A SHRAF, N., E. L. G LAESER , AND G. A. P ONZETTO (2016): “Infrastructure, incentives, and institutions,” American
  Economic Review, 106, 77–82.
BATLEY, R. AND C. M CLOUGHLIN (2015): “The Politics of Public Services: A Service Characteristics Approach,”
  World Development, 74, 275–285.
B ERKOUWER , S. B. AND J. T. D EAN (2022): “Credit, attention, and externalities in the adoption of energy efficient
  technologies by low-income households,” American Economic Review, 112, 3291–3330.
B REEN , M. AND R. G ILLANDERS (2022): “Money down the drain: Corruption and water service quality in Africa,”
  Governance.
D EACON , R. T. (2009): “Public good provision under dictatorship and democracy,” Public choice, 139, 241–262.
F RANCOIS , J. N., J. K AKEU , AND C. KOUAME (2021): “Do Better Institutions Broaden Access To Sanitation In
  Sub-Sahara Africa?” Contemporary Economic Policy, 39, 435–452.
G AUTAM , S. (2023): “Quantifying welfare effects in the presence of externalities: An ex-ante evaluation of sanitation
  interventions,” Journal of Development Economics, 103083.
G LAESER , E. L., G. A. P ONZETTO , AND A. S HLEIFER (2007): “Why does democracy need education?” Journal of
  Economic Growth, 12, 77–99.
G OPALAN , S. AND R. S. R AJAN (2016): “Has foreign aid been effective in the water supply and sanitation sector?
  Evidence from panel data,” World Development, 85, 84–104.
G YIMAH -B REMPONG , K. AND S. M. DE C AMACHO (2006): “Corruption, growth, and income distribution: Are
  there regional differences?” Economics of Governance, 7, 245–269.
H EPWORTH , N., T. B REWER , B. B ROWN , M. ATELA , J. K ATOMERO , J. KONES , AND M. G ASHAW (2022):
  “Accountability and advocacy interventions in the water sector: a global evidence review,” H2Open Journal.
H OUT, W., N. WAGNER , AND B. A. D EMENA (2022): “Does accountability enhance service delivery? Assessment
  of a local scorecard initiative in Uganda,” World Development, 158, 106011.




                                                          20
I MMURANA , M., A.-A. I DDRISU , Z. M OHAMMED , AND T. J. M ATHEW KK (2022): “Access to basic drinking
  water and sanitation in Africa: Does financial inclusion matter?” Cogent Social Sciences, 8, 2057057.
K AUFMANN , D., A. K RAAY, AND M. M ASTRUZZI (2011): “The worldwide governance indicators: methodology
  and analytical issues,” Hague Journal on the Rule of Law, 3, 220–246.
K AUFMANN , D., G. M EHREZ , AND T. G URGUR (2019): “Voice or public sector management? An empirical in-
  vestigation of determinants of public sector performance based on a survey of public officials,” Journal of Applied
  Economics, 22, 321–348.
K EEFER , P. AND S. K HEMANI (2005): “Democracy, public expenditures, and the poor: understanding political
  incentives for providing public services,” The World Bank Research Observer, 20, 1–27.
K HEMANI , S. (2015): “Buying votes versus supplying public services: Political incentives to under-invest in pro-poor
  policies,” Journal of Development Economics, 117, 84–93.
K IVIET, J. F. (2013): “Identification and inference in a simultaneous equation under alternative information sets and
  sampling schemes,” The Econometrics Journal, 16, S24–S59.
——— (2020): “Testing the impossible: identifying exclusion restrictions,” Journal of Econometrics, 218, 294–316.
——— (2022): “Instrument-free inference under confined regressor endogeneity and mild regularity,” Econometrics
  and Statistics.
K RIPFGANZ , S. AND J. F. K IVIET (2021): “kinkyreg: Instrument-free inference for linear regression models with
  endogenous regressors,” The Stata Journal, 21, 772–813.
K RIPFGANZ , S., J. F. K IVIET, ET AL . (2021): “kinkyreg: Instrument-free inference for linear regression models with
  endogenous regressors,” Stata Journal, Forthcoming.
L EGGE , H., K. E. H ALLIDAY, S. K EPHA , C. M CHARO , S. S. W ITEK -M C M ANUS , H. E L -B USAIDY, R. M UENDO ,
  T. S AFARI , C. S. M WANDAWIRO , S. H. M ATENDECHERO , ET AL . (2021): “Patterns and Drivers of Household
  Sanitation Access and Sustainability in Kwale County, Kenya,” Environmental Science & Technology, 55, 6052–
  6064.
L UTZ , W., J. C. C UARESMA , AND M. J. A BBASI -S HAVAZI (2010): “Demography, education, and democracy:
  Global trends and the case of Iran,” Population and Development Review, 36, 253–281.
M ANI , A. AND S. M UKAND (2007): “Democracy, visibility and public good provision,” Journal of Development
  Economics, 83, 506–529.
M AURO , P. (1998): “Corruption and the composition of government expenditure,” Journal of Public economics, 69,
  263–279.
M UNAMATI , M., I. N HAPI , AND S. M ISI (2016): “Exploring the determinants of sanitation success in Sub-Saharan
  Africa,” Water Research, 103, 435–443.
NARZETTI , D. AND R. M ARQUES (2021): “Access to Water and Sanitation Services in Brazilian Vulnerable Areas:
  The Role of Regulation and Recent Institutional Reform,” Water, 13, 787.
N DIKUMANA , L. AND L. P ICKBOURN (2017): “The impact of foreign aid allocation on access to social services in
  sub-Saharan Africa: the case of water and sanitation,” World Development, 90, 104–114.
PAKHTIGIAN , E. L., K. L. D ICKINSON , J. O RGILL -M EYER , AND S. K. PATTANAYAK (2022): “Sustaining latrine
  use: Peers, policies, and sanitation behaviors,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 200, 223–242.
P ICKBOURN , L., R. C ARAHER , AND L. N DIKUMANA (2022): “Does project-level foreign aid increase access to
  improved water sources? Evidence from household panel data in Uganda,” World Development, 158, 105994.



                                                         21
R AVILLA , T., S. K ARUMANCHI , AND T. DAS (2021): “Health Management and Information: Key Principles and
  Enablers in Eye Health Program,” in South-East Asia Eye Health, Springer, 23–50.
RODRIK , D., A. S UBRAMANIAN , AND F. T REBBI (2004): “Institutions rule: the primacy of institutions over geog-
  raphy and integration in economic development,” Journal of economic growth, 9, 131–165.
S PEARS , D. AND S. L AMBA (2016): “Effects of Early-Life Exposure to Sanitation on Childhood Cognitive Skills:
  Evidence from India’s Total Sanitation Campaign,” The Journal of Human Resources, 51, 298–327.
S TAIGER , D. AND J. S TOCK (1997): “Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments,” Econometrica, 65,
  557–586.
U NITED NATIONS (2021): “Transformational benefits’ of ending outdoor defecation: Why toilets matter,” UN News
  Global Perspective Human stories, available at: https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/sanitation#1.




                                                       22
A.    A N ILLUSTRATIVE MODEL :                 VOICE AND SANITATION DELIVERY SERVICES

      We present a stylized model with an analytical solution that captures the relationship amongst visibility of public
good, voice and accountability, and access to sanitation.
      Our framework borrows from the works by Batley and Mcloughlin (2015); Keefer and Khemani (2005); Mani
and Mukand (2007) in applying the concept of visibility of a public good to address the issue of public provision of
sanitation services in a country where there is an elective political process for the choice of a high official who make
decisions on behalf of the people. The modeling approach strengthens our understanding of the political incentives and
economic mechanisms associated with the quality of institutions and stakeholder interests in the delivery of sanitation
services. Low visibility refers to the idea that the more obscured from the public view are the processes and outputs of
sanitation services to citizen, the more it can reduce political incentives for provision of sanitation services. In fact, the
visibility issue ties in directly with weak institution, particularly, in developing countries. Specifically, governments
in developing countries lack the institutions and political will to make sanitation a priority—i.e., sanitation tends to be
an “institutional orphan” as government official often avoid responsibility for the sector that many feel uncomfortable
discussing.23
      The incentives of politicians to provide sanitation services vary across countries. There is ongoing concern that
governments in sub-Saharan Africa are not devoting enough attention and resources to the delivery of basic sanitation
services, particularly when compared to spending on other infrastructure services. The potential political returns from
producing low visible sanitation outputs may be viewed as lower than those from tackling higher profile challenges
that are not obscured from public view. For instance, investing in physical buildings and infrastructure are inherently
more “noisy signals” of political effort than investing in less visible services like basic sanitation services (Batley
and Mcloughlin, 2015; Keefer and Khemani, 2005). Invisibility of basic sanitation provision and maintenance can
lead politicians to under-invest in sanitation services the long-run. Furthermore, low visibility public goods such as
sanitation are likely to get less voter and political attention than famine relief or defense during war (Mani and Mukand,
2007). Low visibility can be viewed as a persistent political constraints to effective delivery of sanitation services, as
they underscore weak political commitment. In what follows we present a striped down tractable economic model to
identify stakeholder interests and institutional determinants of political economy of sanitation delivery.

T HE INCUMBENT GOVERNMENT ’ S DELIVERY OF SANITATION SERVICES This model is an adaptation of the frame-
work by Mani and Mukand (2007) to the issue of sanitation service delivery with political incentives. We consider a
country where an incumbent government is responsible for the provision of sanitation services.
      There are often unobservable non-policy factors that may affect how citizens evaluate the process leading to
the delivery of sanitation services in a country. An example of these unobservable factors include lack of adequate
information on what the role of government is in providing sanitation services, which creates an uncertainty on the
role of government from the citizens perspective. The citizen voter therefore may understand sanitation delivery
outcomes as a combined result not only of active policy components (i.e., efforts and competency of elective officials)
but also other random non-policy societal factors represented by a normal distribution. The higher the magnitude of
uncertainty surrounding the role played by non-policy factors, the lower will be the visibility of government actions in
providing sanitation services which in turn will affect the electoral decisions of citizens. For instance, if the magnitude
  23 See   http://www.ledevoir.com/documents/pdf/rapporteau.pdf for details.



                                                                      23
of uncertainty surrounding non-policy factors is very high, that would lower the citizens’ perceived role attributed to
the incumbent government in providing sanitation services. In contrast, in a world where there is no uncertainty
surrounding non-policy societal factors, citizens would be able fully access the role and the magnitude of policy
factors involved in the delivery process of sanitation services. More formally, the incumbent government’s delivery of
sanitation services is perceived by a citizen-voter as follows

                                                                 St = τ + gt + ε ,                                                               (A.1)

which includes the government’s effectiveness τ , the incumbent government’s resource allocation, gt , and random
societal factors whose likelihood is measured by a normal distribution ε ∼ N (0, σε (D)).24 The magnitude of the im-
pact of the random societal factors on the process of sanitation delivery is given by the standard deviation function
σε (D) where D is a parameter that broadly captures the quality of the monitoring system by the people, free media
that actively informs the citizens about the role of government, the quality of electoral rules, and transparent elec-
                                                                                                         ′ (D) < 0,
tions. This variable is proxied by voice and accountability in our empirical estimation. We assume that σε
implying that an increase in D reduces uncertainty surrounding the role of government in sanitation delivery services.
Intuitively, a stronger media that can raise awareness about sanitation services, better monitoring system by the people
and/or greater transparency in the election rule reduces the perceived uncertainty played by other societal factors. For
simplicity, we assume that ε also captures demand factors that government takes as given in its decisions on sanitation
delivery services.
       It is assumed that the true ability of the incumbent government τ is not known to anyone, including the gov-
ernment itself. However, there is a common prior that the government’s competence or effectiveness is drawn from a
normal distribution τ ∼ N (τ    2 ) with mean τ
                           ¯ , στ                             2 . There is a cost C (g ) associated with providing san-
                                              ¯ and variance στ                       t
itation services delivery, where the cost function is assumed to be twice continuously differentiable. We assume that
the precise allocation gt is not observable to the citizens, which can be viewed from the perspective of a developing
country where voter illiteracy, corruption and a lack of transparency are rife.25 Indeed, even if published, information
on public good expenditures are notoriously unreliable in developing countries.

C ITIZENS ’ APPRECIATION OF THE INCUMBENT GOVERNMENT ’ S EFFORTS AND COMPETENCE The economy con-
tains citizens of unit mass who derive utility from consuming sanitation services. The citizen-voter preferences for
sanitation services are identical, such that
                                                                    Ut = u(St )                                                                  (A.2)
where u is an increasing and concave function. The citizen-voters do not know the incumbent government’s ability ex
ante, but they can update their assessment of its ability by examining its performance in providing sanitation service
outputs. Ceteris paribus, a higher realized sanitation service outputs results in the citizen-voter having a more favorable
perception of the government’s ability and hence, improves the latter’s chances of remaining in power. This suggests
that resources g are a substitute for the ability τ . It implies that an increased allocation of resources by a government
   24 In the model g can be viewed as the stock of accumulated expenditures up to time t so that S represents the net stock of sanitation services
                      t                                                                                 t
up to time t , after taking into account the depreciation of sanitation infrastructure. For tractability, the model is simplified to two periods. In the
first period, the incumbent has to make a decision that will influence the voter decision in the next period. The first period current government
spending can be viewed as a proxy of the accumulated stock of previous expenditures.
   25 In the context of literacy rate, adult total (% of people ages 15 and above), SSA ranks lowest among the world developing regions. See

https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SE.ADT.LITR.ZS?end=2010&locations=ZG-1W-Z4-8S-Z7-ZJ&start=2010&view=bar for details. See
also Gyimah-Brempong and de Camacho (2006) for the case of corruption.



                                                                          24
can favorably affect the citizen-voter’s inference of its ability. This suggests that a government interested in enhancing
its reputation may have a low incentive in investing high level resources in favor of sanitation delivery services if they
are perceived as having a very low impact on the people’s inference.

Q UALITY OF VOICE AND ACCOUNTABILITY Typically, the more democratic a country is, the more sensitive the
government is to the citizens’ perception of its competence. The parameter D is the likelihood that transparent elec-
tions accounting for voice and accountability are held at the end of the first period. D can also broadly comprise free
media and freedom of speech. However, for the purposes of highlighting the direct role of voice and accountability in
stimulating government’s ability to increase the supply of sanitation services, we limit the definition of D to free and
fair elections. Hence, D represents the degree to which the incumbent’s ability to retain power in the second period
depends on the citizen’s votes as related to their perception of its competence. A greater likelihood of transparent and
fair elections (higher D) implies that the government will have to put in effort to maximize its reputation for compe-
tence among citizens. The parameter D can also be viewed as a measure of the quality of political institutions, which
governs the process of collective decision-making in society.

R E - LECTION PROBABILITY ψ OF THE INCUMBENT GOVERNMENT Define ψ (S ) as the probability that incumbent
government retains power and enjoy “ego” rents R when the realized provision of sanitation services is S . With
no elections, (probability (1-D)), it remains in power for sure, independent of its reputation and enjoys the same
“ego’ rents from doing so for a second period. There is a “charisma” factor that citizens care about in their electoral
decisions, which may be related to the ethnicity of the candidates. We represent the charisma of the challenger, relative
to the incumbent, by a variable c drawn from a uniform law as follows c ∼ U [−c0 , c0 ]. It is realized immediately prior
to the elections after the incumbent has made the first period resource allocation decision. If the voter’s estimate of
                                        ¯ + c, she votes to retain the incumbent. If not, the incumbent must leave office
the incumbent’s ability is greater than τ
at the end of period one.
     The government’s efforts on sanitation services are driven by the fact that it wants to stay on in power. The voter’s
re-election decision depends on two factors: the competence and the charisma of the incumbent, relative to those of the
challenger. We denote by g∗ citizen’s expectation of how much effort has been allocated by the incumbent government
for delivering sanitation services. The citizen-voter compares his updated estimate of the perceived competence,
E (τ |S , g∗ ) with its ex ante estimate of a randomly drawn challenger’s competence, c. In addition, the voter takes into
account the realization of the challenger’s charisma c, which proxies for the all nonability related stochastic factors
that may influence elections. The incumbent is re-elected if the following citizen-voters’ condition is satisfied

                                                  E (τ |S , g∗ ) − τ
                                                                   ¯≥c


     For instance, if c is positive, the incumbent should have a sufficiently higher than average reputation to offset
its “charisma” deficit. The incumbent government makes resource allocation decisions with a view to maximizing his
probability of re-election ψ . In electoral equilibrium, we have




                                                           25
                                 ψ (S )                        =                        Probability E (τ |S , g∗ ) − τ
                                                                                                                     ¯≥c                          (A.3)
                                                Rational expectations condition

                                                                                         1     E (τ |,S ,g )−τ
                                                                                                             ¯          ∗

                                                               =                                               dx                                 (A.4)
                                                                                        2c0 −c0
                                                                                         1
                                                               =                            [E (τ |S , g∗ ) − τ ¯ + c0 ]]                         (A.5)
                                                                                        2c0

As shown in Mani and Mukand (2007), the Bayes’s rule can be used to compute the citizen-voter’s perceived compe-
tence of the incumbent government as follows:

                                                                                 1
                                                                                στ2     + σ 21
                                                                                             (D)
                                                                                                 (S − g∗ )
                                                                        ∗
                                                        E (τ |S , g ) =                    1
                                                                                            ε
                                                                                                                                                  (A.6)
                                                                                          στ2   + σ 21
                                                                                                     (D)  ε


The government’s discount factor is β and the objective is to solve the maximization problem
                                                                                                                                            
             
                                                                                                                                            
                                                                                                                                             
                                                                                                                                            
                                                                            1                 1                                             
       max               R              −           C(g)                +       R(1 − D) + RD     [E (E (τ |S , g∗ )) − τ
                                                                                                                        ¯ + c0 ]]                 (A.7)
        g                                                                  1+β               2c0                                 
             Value of holding office
                                                                                                                                 
                                           Sanitation delivery costs                                                             
                                                                                                                                  
                                                                                         Expected value of winning a second term in office


                             ¯ + e, the expression E (E (τ |S , g∗ )) can be computed (see, Mani and Mukand (2007)) as
Using the fact that E (S ) = τ
follows
                                                                                   1
                                                                                  στ2   + σ 21
                                                                                             (D)
                                                                                                  ¯ + g − g∗ )
                                                                                                 (τ
                                                                        ∗
                                                    E (E (τ |S , g )) =                      1
                                                                                                ε
                                                                                                                                                  (A.8)
                                                                                            στ2      + σ 21
                                                                                                          (D) ε

Plugging (A.8) in equation (A.9) leads to

                                    1                 1
                                                                                                     1
                                                                                                    στ2   + σ 21
                                                                                                               (D)
                                                                                                                    ¯ + g − g∗ )
                                                                                                                   (τ
                    max R − C(g) +     R(1 − D) + RD                                                              ε
                                                                                                                   1
                                                                                                                                   −τ
                                                                                                                                    ¯ + c0        (A.9)
                     g             1+β               2c0                                                          στ2   + σ 21
                                                                                                                             (D)
                                                                                                                            ε



E QUILIBRIUM DELIVERY OF SANITATION SERVICES The objective function is concave with respect to efforts allo-
cated to sanitation survives. Computing the first order condition shows that the optimal effort satisfies the following
the relation
                                                                                RD           στ2
                                                                   −1
                                                         g = C′                           2 (D) + σ 2
                                                                                                                                                 (A.10)
                                                                            2c0 (1 + β ) σε        τ

It is straightforward to show that

                                                                             ∂g
                                                                                        > 0                                                      (A.11)
                                                                             ∂D

       Equation (A.11) highlights that a higher probability of having transparent and fair elections, free media, and
stronger accountability of government lead the incumbent government to increase the delivery of sanitation services,
St .




                                                                                   26
B.   M ATHEMATICAL REPRESENTATION OF THE KLS                      ESTIMATOR

     Since the KLS is a relatively new estimator, which we are applying to our empirical model, and for convenience,
we provide the details of the KLS estimator derived and desribed in Kiviet (2020, 2022); Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021)
as applied to our model. Our model is given as,

                                                                    ′
                                                Si = β1 Voicei + Xi β2 + εi                                          (B.1)

     The kinkreg command in STATA, which implements the KLS automatically transforms all variables into devia-
tions from the means; hence, the intercept, α is partialled out of from the model. The KLS estimator is instrument-free
and Kiviet (2020, 2022) suggests an approach that makes use of a non-orthogonality condition for the endogenous re-
gressor, which in our model is Voice: E [Voicei εi ] = ρσ1 σε , where as discussed earlier ρ is the correlation coefficient
between Voice and ε , and σ1 and σε are the standard deviations for Voice and ε , respectively. As shown in Kiviet
(2020, 2022) the standard deviations can be estimated from the observed data. However, ρ is unknown and has to be
carefully postulated by the researcher in order to uncover the KLS estimator. Usually, a desirable interval is postulated
for ρ instead of a single value. This way, there is a higher likelihood that ρ falls with the given interval.
     With the assumption that the interval for ρ has been correctly postulated, the KLS estimator as derived in Kiviet
(2020, 2022); Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021) is given by

                                 ˆ1,KLS
                                 β             ˆ1,OLS
                                               β           ρσˆ1σ ˆ ε (ρ )                 1
                                           =           − 2     ′                                                     (B.2)
                                 ˆ 2,KLS       ˆ 2,OLS  ˆ1 − σ
                                                             ˆ 12 Σ ˆ −1 σ           ˆ −1 σ
                                                                                    −Σ
                                 β             β        σ             2 ˆ 12           2 ˆ 12

                                                             Bias Correction(ρ )or adjustment term


     where the bias correction term is also a function of the coviarance estimates σ and variance, Σ both of which
can be readily estimated from the data. There are a few features of the KLS estimator that need highlighting: First,
the KLS estimator is point-symmetric around ρ = 0, and β  ˆ1,KLS is monotonically decreasing function in ρ . βˆ1,KLS
                                                                  ˆ 2,KLS is monotonically increasing or decreasing,
coincides with the OLS estimator if ρ is zero. On the other hand, β
depending on the covariance terms. βˆ1,KLS coincides with the OLS estimator if ρ is zero or if X′ are exogenous and
                                                                                                      i
uncorrelated with the endogenous regressor, Voicei (i.e., σ12 = 0). For additional and in-depth derivation of the KLS
estimator, the interested reader should see Kiviet (2020, 2022); Kripfganz and Kiviet (2021) for details.




                                                            27