Policy Research Working Paper 10226 Cartels in Infrastructure Procurement Evidence from Lebanon Mounir Mahmalat Wassim Maktabi Fragility, Conflict and Violence Global Theme November 2022 Policy Research Working Paper 10226 Abstract This paper studies cartels in public infrastructure procure- in Lebanon and analyzes the conditions under which pow- ment and analyzes the conditions under which they succeed erful political elites can broker deals to overprice and/or in generating rents. It first conceptualizes the interplay of over-spend contracts. To examine how cartels operate, the the central actors of a procurement project, notably the analysis identifies the political connections of contractors contractor, the procurement agency, as well as the super- and consultants and classifies them according to their vision and design consultants. By focusing on consultants, “quality” in terms of access to institutional functions of the framework includes important yet understudied actors the implementing agency. The paper argues that design in cartels that design tenders, evaluate bids, and supervise consultants serve as the lynchpin of the cartel by reducing the implementation of projects. The paper then explores transaction costs for searching, bargaining, and enforcing an original data set of infrastructure procurement contracts of corrupt deals. This paper is a product of the Fragility, Conflict and Violence Global Theme. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/prwp. The authors may be contacted at mmahmalat@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Cartels in Infrastructure Procurement – Evidence from Lebanon Mounir Mahmalat and Wassim Maktabi JEL: D72, D73, O17 Keywords: Procurement, cartels, middlemen, politically connected firms, Lebanon ACKNOWLEDGMENTS. This paper has been produced for The Policy Initiative, Beirut, Lebanon. Author affiliations: Mounir Mahmalat, the World Bank (Fragility Conflict and Violence Group) and The Policy Initiative; Wassim Maktabi, The Policy Initiative. The authors gratefully acknowledge fund-ing from the Konrad Adenauer Foundation, Lebanon Office. The authors are moreover grateful to Sami Atallah, Michael Bauer, Mona Fawaz, Norbert Fiess, Tom Lambert, Lamia Moubayed as well as work-shop participants at the Konrad Adenauer Foundation and the Institute des Finances Basil Fuleihan for helpful thoughts, comments, and reviews. The authors also express their gratitude to Jamal Haidar for making parts of the data available, and to the Council for Development and Reconstruction for provid-ing technical assistance to match additional datasets. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank. Corresponding author contact: mounir.mahma-lat@thepolicyinitiative.org. “Corrupt implementing firms always need corrupt consult- ants. And both are related to a corrupt official. Always!” CEO of a major Lebanese infrastructure development firm 1. Introduction Two broad observations motivate our study. First, public infrastructure procurement constitutes a major source of rents for elites, notably in countries with weak governance and control of corruption (Bosio et al., 2022; Dávid-Barrett and Fazekas, 2020). As spending on procurement accounts for 12.6% of gross domestic product (GDP) in high-income countries and 13.6% in upper-middle-income countries on average (in 2015) (Djankov, Islam and Saliola, 2016), public procurement offers ample incentives for elites to interfere, even in countries with strong institutions and control of corruption (Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2013; Hessami, 2014). As such a high share of spending makes procurement a crucial part of government operations and for pursuing most development outcomes (Fazekas and Blum, 2021), even small improvements in procurement practices can have large welfare effects. Second, an increasing body of research highlights the importance of networks, or cartels, to understand corruption in public procurement (Adam et al., 2022; Fazekas, Sberna and Vannucci, 2022), including for infrastructure (Hudon and Garzón, 2016). While corruption was previously conceived mostly as a principal-agent problem (Ugur and Dasgupta, 2011), recent studies increasingly conceptualize corrup- tion leveraging network theory (Marquette and Peiffer, 2018). Most of these studies, however, focus on the functionality of cartels, rather than their mechanisms (Fazekas, Sberna and Vannucci, 2022), even though analyzing the governance of such networks is crucial to understand their persistence and how to undermine them (Sberna, 2014). In this paper, we explore the mechanisms of cartels in Lebanon’s infrastructure procurement sector. We analyze a data set of all 394 infrastructure procurement contracts awarded between 2008 and 2018 by Lebanon’s Council for Development and Reconstruction (CDR), by far the country’s most important infrastructure development agency and central pillar of the power-sharing arrangement by providing a major source of rents for sectarian elites (Leenders, 2012; Mahmalat, Atallah and Maktabi, 2021).1 By identifying the political connections of both the contractor as well as the consultancy firms involved in the implementation of a procurement contract, we go beyond previous studies’ focus on contractors and analyze the interplay between the development agency (in this case CDR), the contractor, and consult- ants. Notably, we are not primarily interested in understanding whether elites extract rents via CDR. As we have shown in previous work, politically connected contractors receive contracts that are inflated by almost 33 percent vis-à-vis the average contract (Mahmalat, Atallah and Maktabi, 2021). Instead, we examine how cartels operate. More specifically, we leverage a series of expert interviews with pol- iticians, officials, contractors, and consultants to generate and test hypotheses to identify the conditions under which the cartel succeeds in generating rents. In doing so, we introduce two methodological novelties. First, we focus on procurement consultants, an immensely important player in the procurement process with a large degree of influence and discretion in different phases of a project cycle, earning them the label “masters of the game.”2 Consultants are involved in the design of a project, the evaluation of bids, the supervision of project implementation, as well as the assessment of claims and variation orders of ongoing projects. Despite their importance, however, the role of consultants has, to our knowledge, not received systematic treatment in the 1 As a formally independent institution, CDR enjoys special prerogatives to plan and execute large public infrastructure pro- jects of which it has handled the vast majority after Lebanon’s civil war (1975 -1990). In the 394 contracts for infrastructure projects from 2008 to 2018, CDR has awarded projects totaling $3.98 billion that involved $1.76 billion in foreign funding, thereby vastly outspending other procurement institutions. In the absence of natural resources, CDR became a central pillar for Lebanon’s power-sharing arrangement. 2 To use the words of the director of a large consultancy firm interviewed for this project. 2 literature on procurement cartels. We conceptualize the role of consultants and shed light on the mech- anisms of brokerage between different actors. Second, we differentiate the “quality” of a political connection. We initially follow previous studies in defining a firm to be politically connected (a politically connected firm, or “PCF”) if at least one of its board members or the CEO is a politician, a close relative, or a publicly known friend (Faccio, 2006; Rijkers, Baghdadi and Raballand, 2017; Diwan and Haidar, 2020). In a second step, however, we assign a connection to different circles of elites in order to better reflect the complexity of the phenomenon and distinguish the mechanisms by which connections matter. We follow the approach outlined in Mah- malat, Atallah and Maktabi (2021) and associate each connected firm to either of two groups of politi- cians. “PCF1” are those firms connected to the board members of CDR or to the small group of political elites that openly serve as their protégés and thereby reserved a “seat at the table” at the board of CDR.3 “PCF2” are firms connected to any other prime minister, president, minister, member of parliament, or party elite that held office during this period. We make two arguments. First, design consultants serve as the lynchpin of a cartel. For overpricing, contracts are inflated only when both the designer and contractor are connected to an elite with a “seat at the table” (i.e., they are PCF1). We estimate that these contracts are overpriced by roughly $3.5 million, or 35%, vis-à-vis the average contract, totaling $160 million for the period under investigation. For overspending, projects designed by PCF1 designers are more likely to be overspent and have larger cost overruns. Notably, it does not matter whether the supervisor of a project is politically connected. Second, the ability of elites to act as brokers depends on their influence over formal decision-making processes, rather than their political function. We find that only PCF1 connections matter for either rent generation channel. Other (PCF2) elites, including very powerful ones such as ministers, party figure- heads or militia leaders, play no systematic role in the workings of the cartel. These results suggest that high-level brokerage works through the institutional channel, rather than other conceivable mechanisms that could influence the allocation of rents, such as coercion (Berman et al., 2017; Rizkallah, 2017) or distribution by quotas (Dibeh, 2005; Salloukh, 2019; Mahmalat, 2020). Even in countries with weak bureaucracies such as Lebanon, elites, as brokers, need to control formal institutional functions via loyal personnel within which they enjoy a long-time horizon to reduce searching, bargaining, and enforce- ment costs. We make three contributions to the literature. First, we add to the literature on procurement cartels and organized crime (for a review, see Sberna, 2014). As the analysis of cartels is inherently difficult due to their clandestine nature, the few studies that provide insights into their mechanisms are mostly qual- itative. Hudon and Garzón (2016) leverage testimonies of elected officials and witnesses to investigate the workings of a procurement cartel in Quebec, Canada, and show how contractors paid kickbacks to politicians for preferential treatment by financing political parties. Jancsics and Jávor (2012) and Jancsics (2015) leverage a series of expert interviews with actors involved in a cartel in Hungary to describe how elites design and coordinate multilevel structures of corrupt networks within and among organizations. Quantitative insights come mostly from an important body of literature that identifies indicators to detect cartels (Adam et al., 2022), as well as from analyses of public procurement in Italy, for which the involvement of the Italian Mafia is found to impact the performance of public procurement in Italian municipalities (Ravenda et al., 2020). To our knowledge, our study is the first to provide quantitative insights into the mechanisms of cartels in infrastructure procurement. 3 The connections of CDR board members to political elites are public knowledge and, in most cases, obvious from close family relationships. The members are: Nabil El-Jisr (president), brother of Samir El-Jisr (former member of parliament of the Future Movement), appointed president by Prime Minister Rafic Hariri in 1995 and again by Prime Minister Fouad Sin- iora (both Future Movement) in 2006; Yasser Berri (first deputy), brother of Nabih Berri (Amal Movement), speaker of par- liament since 1992; Alain Kordahi (second deputy, deceased); Ghazi Haddad (secretary general), close to President Michel Aoun; Malek Ayyas (board member), close to Walid Jumblatt; Yahya El-Sangari (board member), brother-in-law of former prime minister Omar Karami; and Walid Safi (deputy to the government), close to Walid Jumblatt. 3 Second, our results add to the literature on brokers, or middlemen, another rarely examined phenome- non for which it is notoriously difficult to obtain insights (Stokes et al., 2013). Recent evidence suggests that middlemen are often, if not always, key actors in corrupt exchanges as they are able to reduce transaction costs and make corrupt exchanges feasible in the first place (Lambsdorff, 2007). Della Porta and Vannucci (2012), for example, provide a range of examples on the involvement of middlemen and suggest that they are active even in high levels of government. Bussell (2017) provides a theoretical framework to explain the conditions under which middlemen play a role. She argues that the demand for middlemen increases whenever an interaction is repeated frequently and among partners that are unfamiliar with each other. As most accounts lack differentiation between levels of brokerage, we add to this literature by illustrating how brokerage can happen at the highest levels of government and that the ability of elites to serve as middlemen depends on the extent to which these were able to penetrate administrations with loyal personnel. Lastly, we contribute to the literature that investigates the effects of firms’ political connections on economic outcomes. Previous studies show how political connections of board members boost a firm’s corporate value (Fisman, 2001; Faccio, 2006; Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2009) while the presence of PCFs is found to hinder job creation and competitiveness of affected sectors (Rijkers et al., 2014; World Bank, 2015). Evidence from Lebanon is available on the effects of political connections on job creation (Diwan and Haidar, 2020), rent-seeking from procurement contracts (Mahmalat, Atallah and Maktabi, 2021), and political outcomes (Chaaban, 2019; Mahmalat and Atallah, 2019). Recent contributions also provide evidence on the extent to which PCFs receive higher value public procurement contracts, both in developed and developing countries (Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2013; Hessami, 2014; Baránek and Titl, 2020; Dávid-Barrett and Fazekas, 2020). Schoenherr (2019), for example, finds that connections of firms to an incoming president in the Republic of Korea led to allocative distortions both in the allocation and renegotiation of contracts. We add to these findings by providing evidence that the “qual- ity” of connections matters in determining which firms can access rent generation mechanisms. While we abstain from claiming generalizability of our results, we believe that they provide important insights into how elites can extract and distribute rents from public institutions in countries with weak bureaucracies. While CDR is a formally independent institution, the use of external design and super- vision consultants is common practice among procurement agencies worldwide (Asian Development Bank, 2013). Cartels and allocative distortions in public procurement have been documented even for countries with comparably low levels of corruption, such as South Korea (Schoenherr, 2019), the United States (Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2013), Italy (Ravenda et al., 2020), or OECD countries more gener- ally (Hessami, 2014). Such findings suggest that these effects are also plausible in countries with a weaker governance framework (Bosio et al., 2020; Dávid-Barrett and Fazekas, 2020), particularly where elites face fewer constraints to penetrate public institutions with loyal personnel (Mahmalat and Zoughaib, 2021). We proceed as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the interplay between the major actors within the procurement cartel and develops hypotheses. Section 3 describes our data and methods. Section 4 analyzes the mechanisms by which consultants facilitate rent generation, after which section 5 addresses endogeneity concerns. Section 6 discusses the results. Section 7 concludes by outlining policy recom- mendations. 2. Cartels and infrastructure procurement Many crimes cannot be committed alone. Whenever a crime requires iterative and complex interactions, such as in public procurement, individual actors need partners or networks to fulfill interrelated tasks (Lambsdorff, 2007; Sberna, 2014; Lessing, 2021). These networks bring together a range of hetero- genous actors, who need to ensure deferred reciprocity (as transactions are often intertemporal), interact in indirect mutuality (partners are often linked through middlemen or brokers), and ensure disguise of payments (as corrupt deals are illegal) (Adam et al., 2022). 4 To address these issues, these networks face classical collective action problems (Lambsdorff, 2002; Della Porta and Vannucci, 2012). Corrupt exchanges are, by definition, not enforceable by law and lack an ex-ante definition of property rights. Actors lack opportunities for third-party enforcement and ex- post regulation, increasing insecurity and risks of cheating or defection especially when deals are com- plex and include intertemporal transactions (Sberna, 2014). Moreover, while partners need to disguise their transactions, they acquire potentially damaging information about each other. Corrupt exchanges, therefore, tend to rely on middlemen who provide the necessary information and brokerage to link dif- ferent partners (Lambsdorff, 2007, pp. 221–222; Bussell, 2017). Cartels address the demand for a governance structure that allows parties to trust in each other’s will- ingness to respect informal rules and mutual (intertemporal) commitments. In such more complex rela- tionships, “a combination of first-party internalized mechanisms of self-sanctioning, reciprocal second- party bonds of trust, and other forms of third-party guarantees is needed that allows exchanges of pre- carious property rights” (Della Porta and Vannucci, 2012, p. 30, emphasis in text). Notably, (threats of) physical coercion can be an important resource to provide guarantees and prohibit an individual’s exit from the cartel (ibid.). Following Lambsdorff (2002), the goal of cartels is to reduce transaction costs in three domains, namely searching for partners, bargaining, and enforcing of contracts. In verifying this framework in an application to public procurement contracts of Italian municipalities, Fazekas, Sberna and Vannucci (2022) contend that “extra-legal governance services provided [by cartels] may become an integral and functional component of corruption transactions in public procurement.” (p. 4) Middlemen, or brokers, assume a crucial role in minimizing these transaction costs (Lambsdorff, 2007; Della Porta and Vannucci, 2012; Stokes et al., 2013; Bussell, 2017). Brokers generally establish the contacts between two parties, search for appropriate counterparts, conduct negotiations, and often fa- cilitate the exchange of resources. The demand for brokers varies with the nature of the corrupt ex- change. Bussell (2017), for example, argues that the demand for middlemen is higher for transactions that are frequent but involve potential participants that are unfamiliar with each other. As crimes vary in complexity and value, different levels of brokerage require a different set of expertise of the broker (Stokes et al., 2013). As we hypothesize, to minimize transaction costs of high-value transactions such as infrastructure procurement, brokerage requires three conditions. First, brokers need to control important institutional functions via loyal personnel in order to limit competition among con- sultants and contractors and minimize costs arising from the searching and matching of partners. Sec- ond, they need long-term trusting relationships to partners to reduce bargaining costs and facilitate dealmaking. And third, they need to enjoy a long-time horizon in order to reduce enforcement costs and ensure that all actors honor a deal in deferred reciprocity. In what follows, we review the process of infrastructure procurement of CDR and identify how the different actors involved in the cartel enable these conditions. “The masters of the game” – Consultants in infrastructure procurement Infrastructure procurement requires the coordination of a complex set of tasks among a variety of actors. Due to the high degrees of specialization each project requires and the resource constraints public in- stitutions face, any agency—in this case, CDR—avails not only of contracting firms to implement pro- jects, but also of consultancy firms for design and supervision. Figure 1 provides a schematic depiction of how the four main players are interconnected. 5 Figure 1: Schematic overview of interrelationships among parties in infrastructure procurement After CDR conceives of a given project, it assigns a consultant to design it, specify its parameters and requirements, provide a cost estimate, as well as develop the terms of references based on which the contractors can bid. After CDR publishes the bidding documents and coordinates the tendering process, the designer often supports CDR in the technical evaluation of incoming bids. CDR, then, awards a contract to an infrastructure development firm (contractor) based on criteria that can vary according to the requirements outlined by the funding organization. In case the initial contract with the designer does not include project supervision, CDR opens a separate tender for consultancy firms to bid on the project supervision. These supervision consultants are “the eyes on the ground” for CDR, doing “basically everything other than management .”4 Even site visits by CDR personnel are announced in advance in coordination with the contractor and occur only spo- radically. Eventually, the supervisor assesses whether all contract requirements are met and the con- tractor has delivered all works as specified. Supervisory consultants (henceforth, supervisor) also play a major role in the management of cost over- runs. These overruns can occur from two sources, variation orders or claims. Variation orders are a modification of the original contract to change the scope or technicalities of a project and are usually prepared and thereby approved by a consultant. Claims, by contrast, result from unforeseen difficulties a contractor faces to implement the project. For such claims, the supervisor has to provide an assessment for CDR as to whether the claim is justified. In these interrelationships, the design and supervision consultants have a significant degree of influence over the success of a project. While the designer can influence the specifications of a project and thereby affect contract prices or the competition among bidding firms, supervisors determine how a contractor can overspend a contract or deliver quality work. Hypotheses We investigate how cartels facilitate rent generation to infer insights into the three central tasks of car- tels (searching, bargaining, and enforcing). To that end, we develop three sets of hypotheses that dis- aggregate different conditions under which the cartel can succeed in generating rents. These hypotheses are informed by previous work on indicators for the detection of cartels (Adam et al., 2022), as well as 4 Quote of a former CDR project engineer interviewed for this project. 6 a set of expert interviews we conducted with CDR officials, members of parliament, bureaucrats, pro- fessors, as well as CEOs and engineers of leading contractors and consulting firms. The interviews were conducted between December 2021 and May 2022, followed an open-ended, semi-structured interview guideline, and provided rich anecdotal evidence of alleged cases of collusion. Searching The first function of the cartel should be to reduce searching costs by minimizing the number of actors involved. We differentiate two broad ways in which the cartel can generate rents – through overpricing (H1) or overspending of a contract (H2) – and hypothesize that the cartel only succeeds in generating rents for contracts in which it was able to reduce searching costs. This places the role of design consult- ants into the focus by having discretion over the tendering process. We identify a number of sub-hy- potheses to specify the conditions under which overpricing or overspending can happen. H1: Politically connected design consultants facilitate the overpricing or overspending of infrastruc- ture contracts by limiting the number of eligible firms. Overpricing Our first two hypotheses serve as a baseline in which a reduction of searching costs is not needed to overprice (H1.1 and H1.2). First, when designer and supervisor are the same firm, the consultant would have opportunities to include excessive provisions in project design, knowing they will be “covered- up” in the supervision stage. In another potential configuration, politicians broker a deal between con- nected designers, supervisors and the CDR board, which would approve excessive provisions in tender documents. H1.1: When the designer and supervisor are the same firm, contractors can overprice a contract. H1.2: When both the designer and supervisor are PCFs, contractors can overprice a contract. For other hypotheses, a reduction in searching costs would be necessary. The designer would limit the competition among firms by “tailoring” tender documents, arbitrarily excluding firms that have submit- ted bids, and thereby enabling favored firms to overprice. A politician would broker between designers and contractors to know for which firm to tailor the design or bidding process. In a first configuration, contracts would be inflated when the designer is connected, independently of whether the contractor is connected as well. In a second configuration, politicians would also need a connection to a contractor to be able to broker a deal. H1.3: When a design consultant is a PCF, contractors can overprice a contract. H1.4: When a design consultant and the contractor are PCFs, contractors can overprice a contract. Overspending Secondly, rent generation can happen via overspending of contracts. Cost-overruns are a common phe- nomenon in infrastructure procurement (Flyvbjerg, Skamris Holm and Buhl, 2003) and are associated with the presence of cartels (Ravenda et al., 2020). Following the above discussion, we should observe that the only contracts that are overspent are those for which elites were able to reduce searching costs. In our first four hypotheses, a reduction of searching costs is not required. First, it would be sufficient when designer and supervisor are the same firm. Sloppy design or inflated provisions would be covered up during the implementation of the project by the supervising team of the same firm. Second, if the supervisor and contractor interact frequently with each other, the better a trusting relationship can emerge based on which contracts can be overspent. H2.1: When the designer and supervisor are the same firm, contracts are more likely to be overspent. 7 H2.2: When the supervisor and contractor execute contracts frequently together, contracts are more likely to be overspent. Our third and fourth hypotheses posit that supervisors play the central role in allowing projects to be overspent. They would enable a contractor to file for excessive variation orders or claims and use their political connections to ensure that these are approved by the CDR board. The same would hold true in hypothesis 4, in that both supervisors and contractors would be required to have political connections. H2.3: When the supervisor is politically connected, contracts are more likely to be overspent. H2.4: When both the supervisor and contractor are PCFs, contracts are more likely to be overspent. Alternatively, cost overruns would only be possible when searching costs are reduced at the design stage. Politically connected designers would limit competition among contractors and know that elites facilitate the approval of designs that require adjustments during the implementation stage of a project. H2.5: When the designer is politically connected, contracts are more likely to be overspent. Bargaining In the above hypotheses, we have assumed that elites have similar bargaining costs regardless of which politician or elite a firm is connected to. Previous studies from other country contexts have found vari- ous attributes of a political connection to matter, such as party affiliation (Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2013; Baránek and Titl, 2020), or the political function (Schoenherr, 2019). Following previous work on elite-capture of public institutions in Lebanon (Leenders, 2012; Salloukh, 2019; Mahmalat and Zoughaib, 2021), however, we hypothesize that elites which were able to penetrate public institutions with loyal personnel have a larger degree of discretion over decisions in the board of CDR. In a third hypothesis, we test whether the “quality” of a political connection helps to reduce bargaining costs. Firms would place higher trust in the ability of elites to honor intertemporal transactions that are “embedded” in the institutional framework and exert discretion over decisions via loyal personnel. We expect that PCF1 elites have lower bargaining costs to broker deals and therefore make overspending and overpricing more likely. H3: Only PCF1 connections can succeed in overpricing or overspending contracts. Enforcing A central issue of corrupt exchanges is deferred reciprocity, making enforcement costly. Many deals require that mutual promises are honored with a time-lag, as not all resources are available at the same time (for example, promises for upcoming projects can only be kept once these projects are imple- mented). PCF1 elites, then, should face lower costs to enforce deals than other (PCF2) elites with direct discretion over decision making and are able to provide kickbacks in future contracts. H4: PCF1 connected consultants involved in the cartel are compensated with inflated contracts in intertemporal transactions. 3. Data and methods We leverage two sources of data. First, we analyze a data set of all 394 infrastructure procurement contracts awarded by CDR between January 11, 2008, and March 12, 2018. The data set contains the name of the contract and winning firm, the initially awarded contract value, the sources of funding, the project location(s), the sector, and other identifying information about each contract. We obtained the data from CDR with a formal request pursuing the access to information law. 8 Second, for each infrastructure contract, we reviewed the webpage of CDR to identify the actualized expenditure of each contract, as well as the names of design and supervision consultants. We also rec- orded the values of supervision consultancies and matched each consultancy to its corresponding infra- structure contract. The dependent variables Our key dependent variables are the contract values for infrastructure and consultancy projects. We chose contracts—rather than projects—since bargaining takes place over contracts.5 Of the 394 con- tracts in our data set, we record 384 contracts for which we can identify the contractor, 361 of which contained information on the supervision consultancy and 233 of which we can associate a design con- tract (Table 1). The missing contracts are distributed relatively evenly among sectors in terms of share of contracts, total value, and mean value of contracts. Exceptions are the irrigation and solid waste sectors in which our subsample includes larger values, which are, however, the smallest sectors with 11 and 12 observations. In total, we capture 99.5 percent and 80.6 percent of all contract values with our subsample of supervision and design contracts. Table 1: Composition of data set based on infrastructure contracts Transport Water works Solid waste Irrigation Education Other Total n 79 106 12 11 73 103 384 Total contract Total 1,162 1,189 507.4 413.6 321.4 392.5 3,986 value Mean con- 14.7 11.2 42.3 20.7 4.4 3.8 10.1 tract value n 74 103 11 8 73 92 361 % of all con- 93.7% 97.2% 91.7% 72.7% 100.0% 89.3% 94.0% tracts Super- Total contract 1,158 1,186 505.4 406.9 321.5 385.9 3,964 vision value % of total 99.7% 99.8% 99.6% 98.4% 100.0% 98.3% 99.5% contract value Mean con- 15.7 11.5 45.9 50.9 4.4 4.2 10.9 tract value n 41 72 8 8 37 67 233 % of all pro- 51.9% 67.9% 66.7% 72.7% 50.7% 65.0% 60.7% jects Design Total contract 718.8 1,054 499.4 406.9 222.7 309.4 3,211 value % of total 61.9% 88.7% 98.4% 98.4% 69.3% 78.8% 80.6% contract value 5 Contracts can encompass multiple projects, all of which are implemented by the same contractor and consultant and pertain to the same contract ID. See Mahmalat, Atallah and Maktabi (2021) for a detailed description. 9 Mean con- 17.5 14.6 62.4 50.9 6.0 4.6 13.8 tract value Notes: All values in million US dollars. The contract values captured by politically connected supervisors vary significantly among sectors (Ta- ble 2). Water works exhibit the most contracts (86), followed by the transport and education sectors. In these sectors, 19, 12, and 21 different contractors won at least one contract, of which nine, four, and four are coded as PCF1. In total, supervisors received contracts amounting to $213 million, much of which has been captured by PCF1 consultants. Consultancy contract values in the solid waste and irri- gation sectors, for example, have been captured almost entirely by PCF1 supervisors. Such high levels of concentration of contract values contrast with measurements of market competition. The Herfindahl- Hirschmann Index (HHI), a widely used indicator for industry competitiveness, indicates that the mar- kets for consultancies in the transport, and water works sectors would be competitive, despite that 76% and 73% of projects are captured by PCF1s.6 PCF2s only play a very minor role in contract allocation. The allocation of contracts for design consultants exhibits a similar degree of concentration for the solid waste and irrigation sectors. In these sectors, PCF1 designers designed 99% of all contract values. The water works sector, by contrast, has a lower degree of concentration of connected designers. Table 2: Market competition among sectors Supervision Transport Water works Solid waste Irrigation Education Other HHI 2,159 996 4,287 9,171 3,874 895 Number of contracts 64 86 8 8 60 71 Number of contractors 12 19 6 6 21 28 Number of PCF1 firms 4 9 5 5 4 9 Number of PCF2 firms 2 4 0 1 2 1 PCF1 share in value 76% 73% 99% 99% 88% 66% PCF2 share in value 5.0% 6.0% 0.0% 1.0% 1.0% 2.0% PCF share in value 81% 79% 99% 100% 89% 68% Design HHI 1,513 1,396 5,953 9,392 3,624 1,076 Number of contracts 41 73 8 8 37 69 Number of contractors 12 21 3 6 17 24 Number of PCF1 firms 5 8 2 4 4 8 Number of PCF2 firms 1 4 0 2 2 1 PCF1 share in value 69% 35% 98% 99% 65% 61% PCF2 share in value 8.6% 3.3% 0.0% 0.9% 8.4% 3.5% PCF share in value 78% 39% 98% 100% 74% 64% Notes: Number of contracts based on supervision contracts, rather than infrastructure contracts. Con- tract numbers can deviate from the above as the same consultancy contract can supervise several in- frastructure contracts. HHI for supervisors based on supervision contract values. HHI for designers based on infrastructure contract values. Independent variables: Political connections 6 The HHI index is calculated as the sum of squares of the percentage share of each competing firm competing in a sector, = ∑ 2 1 , and ranges between 10,000 for a perfect monopoly and approaches 0 for many firms with equal market shares. An HHI of up to 1,500 is generally considered a competitive market, while scores above 2,500 indicate a highly con- centrated market. 10 Our key independent variable of interest is the political connectivity of each firm. We follow Faccio (2006), and others, and code a firm as politically connected when it has at least one board member or CEO who is a politician, a close relative of one, or a publicly known friend. For that purpose, we lev- erage online business directories and Lebanon’s commercial registry to look up the name of each firm’s board members in addition to collecting data on their size, age, and paid-in capital. Our approach to identify political connections takes into account that political connections are a com- plex phenomenon in a country like Lebanon (Leenders, 2012; Diwan and Haidar, 2020). We go beyond previous studies, which establish objective criteria for the identification of connections, such as by name matching of a company’s shareholder or CEO names with those of political actors. As such approaches have tended to underestimate results,7 we instead review each firm in our data set manually via an approach outlined in detail in Mahmalat, Atallah and Maktabi (2021). For each firm, we go through a multi-layered search process that relies on media searches on the names of each board member of a firm with a corresponding name of a politician or their political party. This approach allows us to carefully assess a number of common issues in the identification of political connections, such as whether indi- viduals with matching names are related, connections are “deep” enough to matter, or relevant during the period of investigation. We augment and validate the findings with our key informant interviews and code a firm we have not found reliable information on as connected when multiple interviewees correspond in their assessment of a particular firm.8 Moreover, we review the commercial registries as well as the companies’ websites to identify firm characteristics, notably their age, size (in number of employees), and paid-in capital. As these directo- ries fail to report some of the characteristics for some firms (Table 3), we use multiple imputations to estimate the missing values for these observations. The goal of using multiple imputations is to max- imize the use of available information, minimize estimation bias, and obtain appropriate standard errors (Enders, 2010). We use multiple imputation, rather than other available techniques such as stochastic or deterministic imputation, to minimize the bias of standard errors in our regression analyses. We lev- erage the mi estimate command in Stata using a multivariate normal distribution with 10 imputations and take the contract value as an auxiliary variable.9 Table 3: Number of incomplete observations of supervision and design consultants Supervisors Complete Incomplete Total Percent missing Age 340 21 361 5.8% Size 332 29 361 8.0% Paid-in Capital 260 101 361 28.0% Designers Age 207 26 233 11.2% Size 203 30 233 12.9% Paid-in Capital 159 74 233 31.8% Descriptive statistics 7 The widely-cited work of Faccio (2006), for example, uses a data set of firms worldwide and finds no politically connected firms in Zimbabwe and Venezuela—two countries with an arguably weak record for the control of corruption. Even for the United States, where the author’s data set includes more than 7,000 firms, her approach only identifies 14 connected firms (p. 374), a number that other works have found to be much higher (Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2009). 8 Note that the differentiation between PCF1 and PCF2 is mutually exclusive. In the few cases in which we find connections to both circles of elites, we code the firm according to its superior connection (i.e., PCF1) as such firms would prefer invoking their direct connection to decision makers to influence the procurement process, rather than their connection to a third party. 9 Multiple imputation, however, requires that the mechanism that produces missing values is at least missing at random (MAR) in that the missing values are not completely random but that other observed variables can be used to predict the value of the missing ones. MAR moreover requires the ignorability assumption in that the probability of missing data does not depend on the value of the missing information itself. In our case, missing observations are distributed in a non-system- atic way among both small and big firms winning both small and big contracts, as well as those that have other information reported. 11 Of the 384 contracts we observe, 160 have been won by PCF1 contractors, capturing 64% of the total value of all contracts (Table 4). We observe a similar concentration of contract value for supervisors, who capture 83% of all supervision contract values. PCF1 designers get to design 65% of all contract values, while non-connected firms design almost the same number of contracts as PCF1 designers. Overall, PCF2s do not receive or design larger contract values than non-connected ones. Table 4: Contract characteristics Contractor Supervisor Designer PCF 1 PCF 2 Non-PCF PCF 1 PCF 2 Non-PCF PCF 1 PCF 2 Non-PCF Number of 160 71 153 171 27 100 113 22 101 contracts Value of con- 2,544 560.7 878.0 177.1 6.2 30.1 2,101 130.4 988.4 tracts* Share in total 64% 14% 22% 83% 3% 14% 65% 4% 31% contract value Average value of con- 15.9 7.9 5.7 1.04 0.23 0.30 18.6 5.9 9.8 tract* Note: * Value in million US dollars. For designers, the table shows the value of infrastructure contracts. While PCF1s receive or design larger contracts, they are on average larger firms (Table 5). The number of employees for all three types of firms is larger for PCF1s than for PCF2s or non-connected firms. For consultants, connected firms are on average also older than non-connected ones. Moreover, design- ers are the largest firms, corroborating many of our interviewees’ conjectures that Lebanese consultants enjoy an international reputation of delivering high-value work. Table 5: Firm characteristics Contractors Supervisors Designer PCF1 PCF2 Non-PCF PCF1 PCF2 Non-PCF PCF1 PCF2 Non-PCF Number 31 18 77 11 6 37 10 5 36 of firms Age (number 37.5 34.7 41.1 48.6 36.7 35.6 50.1 34.8 37.6 of years) Size (number 640 565 388 891 886 766 1,353 1,039 922 of em- ployees) Paid-in capital (in 0.63 1.62 5.53 1.98 10.26 0.07 1.37 12.31 0.06 mil. USD) 4. How do cartels operate? Overpricing We first investigate the hypotheses related to overpricing. We conduct cross-sectional regression anal- yses in which our dependent variable, logvalue, is the natural log value of infrastructure procurement contract i. Our key independent variable of interest is the vector X that introduces a set of dummy variables j to test for each of the hypotheses outlined above. Vector M includes various firm character- istics n, specifically the natural log of the designer’s age in years, size in number of employees, its paid- in capital in U.S. dollars, as well as whether the winning contractor is a PCF1. We include various fixed effects (FE) l in vector N. Sector FEs account for specificities of each sector, such as their varying degree of competitiveness, the possibility that PCFs sort into higher-value sectors, as well as any natural alignment of a PCF to the political priorities of a party in a specific sector. Governorate FEs capture whether geographical areas require more complex works and whether elites allocate higher-value 12 contacts to specific regions. Year FEs account for other time-invariant heterogeneity. All regressions are run by using the White-Huber sandwich estimator to calculate robust standard errors to account for model misspecifications. Formally, we estimate the following model in which denotes the error term: = 0 + 1 + 2 + 3 + The results are displayed in Table 6. Model 1 tests hypothesis 1.1 and introduces a dummy variable for whether the supervisor is the designer of the same project. The variable is significantly correlated to contract prices with a negative coefficient, suggesting that contracts for which all consultancy services come from the same firm are generally smaller. Models 2 and 3 test hypothesis 1.2 and introduce dummy variables for whether both the supervisor and designer are PCF1 (model 2) or PCF2 (model 3). Models 4 and 5 introduce dummy variables for whether the designer of a project is a PCF1 (model 4) or PCF2 firm (model 5). None of these specifications turn out to be significantly related to contract values. Models 6 and 7 test hypothesis 1.4 and include a dummy variable for whether both the designer and the contractor are either both PCF1 (model 6), and whether the designer is PCF2 while the contractor is PCF1 (model 7). The resulting coefficient for model 6 is highly significant, while the coefficient for PCF1 contractors loses statistical significance. This result signifies an important finding in that, unless designers are PCF1, even contractors close to the CDR board do not win larger contracts. A designer that is connected to other politicians, however, does not design larger contract values, even when their projects are won by PCF1 contractors. Table 6: Regression results Hypothesis H1.1 H1.2 H1.3 H1.4 Model 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Supervision contains -0.39* design (-1.91) Supervisor & designer PCF1 0.31 (1.51) Supervisor & designer PCF2 -0.36 (-0.86) Designer PCF1 0.30 (1.46) Designer PCF2 -0.41 (-0.96) Designer & contractor PCF1 1.18*** (5.18) Designer PCF2 & 0.08 contractor PCF1 (0.16) Contractor PCF1 0.44*** 0.55*** 0.57*** 0.57*** 0.57*** 0.22 0.55*** (2.74) (2.83) (2.83) (2.95) (2.85) (1.30) (3.43) 13 Age 0.23 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.04 0.29 0.45 (0.73) (-0.03) (-0.04) (-0.01) (-0.09) (0.83) (1.22) Size -0.04 0.02 0.04 0.01 0.04 -0.09 -0.07 (-0.39) (0.17) (0.33) (0.07) (0.37) (-0.93) (-0.63) Capital 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.05 (0.84) (0.59) (0.48) (0.63) (0.41) (0.83) (0.89) Sector FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Governorate FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES constant 12.46*** 12.61*** 12.75*** 12.63*** 12.85*** 12.13*** 11.15*** (8.64) (7.58) (6.79) (7.60) (6.76) (8.22) (7.11) Observations 342 236 236 236 236 384 384 Notes: Dependent variable is the log value of procurement contracts. PCF indicates dummy variables for all connected firms. PCF1 captures firms connected to the inner circle of elites that controls the CDR board. PCF2 includes firms of all political elites. Regression model uses robust standard errors; The table shows beta coefficients and t-statistics in parentheses; Signif- icance levels: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. We can assign an approximate economic value to the effect size of model 6. We follow an approach by Goldman, Rocholl and So (2013) and calculate the marginal increase in contract values after including all control variables. We first take the estimated coefficient for a model in which we calculate the mar- ginal effect of model 6 without including any controls (~1.7, not reported in table 6). We then use model 6 to calculate the marginal impact of observing a pair of PCF1 designer and contractor. We calculate the reduction of the effect size by dividing the coefficients of model 6 by those of the model without controls and find that the increase in contract value goes down to ~60% of its univariate estimated value. This leaves an increase of $3.5 million, or almost 35%, for a contract of a PCF1 designer-contractor pair relative to the average contract.10 Observing 45 such PCF1 designer-contractor pairs, this amounts to roughly $160 million in overpricing of contracts throughout the period of investigation. Overspending We go on to investigate our hypotheses related to the overspending of contracts. Table 7 provides the results of a set of logistic regressions to estimate the likelihood that a project is being overspent given a vector of dummy variables for each hypothesis. Formally, we estimate the following model Pr⁡( = 1) = ⁡(0 + 1 + 2 + 3 +4 + 6 + 6 ) where overspent is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 when a contract i is overspent, X is a vector of dummy variables to test our hypotheses j, logvalue the natural log of the contract value, SVdu- ration the duration of the supervision period in years, SVforeign a dummy variable for whether the supervisor is a foreign firm, and funding_origin denotes a vector for the origin of the donor k, that is, whether the funding was provided from domestic, Arab or Western sources. By differentiating the origin 10The calculation is as follows. Table 6 shows the mean values of contracts by political connection. We subtract the mean contract value of PCF1 firms ($16.36 million) from the mean value of all contracts ($10.4 million). We multiply the result- 1.18 ing difference of the univariate results ($16.36 - $10.4 = $5.96 million) with the fraction of the marginal effects ( 1.7 = 0.59 or 59.45 percent) to obtain the value of $3.5 million. 14 of funds, we take into account potential differences in the requirements different funders assign to the supervision and monitoring of projects. Models 1 and 2 show that contracts are not more likely to be overspent when the same consultant does both the design and supervision (H2.1), while frequent interactions between contractor and supervisor are also not related to overspending (H2.2). Models 3 to 6 highlight that contracts are also not more likely to be overspent in relation to the political connections of supervisors (H2.3) or contractors (H2.4). Model 7 shows that contracts designed by PCF1 designers are more than 2.5 times as likely to be over- spent (H2.5). This result draws once again attention to the potential role of designers in a cartel by indicating that they get away with lower quality work that requires or allows for more extensive adjust- ments in the implementation stage. PCF2 designers, by contrast, even have a lower likelihood to overrun costs (model 7). Lastly and contrary to the previous results on overpricing, connected designer-contrac- tor pairs are not more likely to overspend contracts (model 8). These results hold despite accounting for the complexity of a project, as proxied by the supervision period and the overall value of the contract. All our specifications show that larger and more complex contracts are generally more likely to be overspent, highlighting the difficulties in administering more complex projects. Table 7: Regression results on the likelihood of overspending Hypothesis H2.1 H2.2 H2.3 H2.4 H2.5 Model 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Supervision contains 0.06 design (0.15) Repeated interactions 0.18 contractor & supervisor (0.64) Supervisor PCF1 0.41 (1.32) Supervisor & 0.21 contractor PCF1 (0.61) Supervisor PCF2 & -2.03*** contractor PCF1 (-3.35) Designer PCF1 1.02** (2.51) Designer PCF2 -1.54** (-2.38) Designer & contractor 0.24 PCF1 (0.52) Supervision period 0.11*** 0.11*** 0.11*** 0.11*** 0.12*** 0.09** 0.10** 0.11*** (3.39) (3.42) (3.26) (3.32) (3.50) (2.21) (2.48) (3.39) Log contract value 0.59*** 0.58*** 0.58*** 0.58*** 0.63*** 0.48*** 0.53*** 0.57*** (4.39) (4.50) (4.43) (4.44) (4.52) (3.16) (3.29) (4.33) Foreign supervisor 0.54 0.57 0.78 0.60 0.71 1.43** 1.19* 0.57 (1.17) (1.25) (1.55) (1.27) (1.42) (2.26) (1.86) (1.23) 15 Arab donor 0.49 0.51 0.52 0.49 0.51 0.50 0.34 0.47 (1.26) (1.33) (1.35) (1.28) (1.33) (1.00) (0.69) (1.22) Western donor 0.06 0.09 0.10 0.11 -0.03 0.11 -0.21 0.08 (0.14) (0.21) (0.24) (0.24) (-0.07) (0.19) (-0.38) (0.19) Sector FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Governorate FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES - - - Constant -10.99*** -11.14*** -10.88*** -11.72*** 10.17** -10.68*** 10.95*** 10.11*** * (-5.12) (-5.40) (-5.36) (-5.24) (-5.17) (-4.40) (-4.08) (-5.07) Observations 329 329 329 329 329 219 219 329 R2 0.25 0.25 0.26 0.25 0.27 0.31 0.31 0.25 Notes: Dependent variable is a dummy variable for whether a contract is overspent. PCF indicates dummy variables for all connected firms. PCF1 captures firms connected to the inner circle of elites that controls the CDR board. PCF2 includes firms of all political elites. Regression model uses robust standard errors; The table shows beta coefficients and t-statistics in pa- rentheses; Significance levels: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. We test the economic significance of these results and specify an additional model to understand whether those contracts are overspent by larger margins. We calculate the log value of a project's cost overruns, that is, the discrepancy between the amount of the initially awarded contract and the actualized expenditures. Using this discrepancy as a dependent variable, Table 8 shows that contracts supervised by connected con- sultants or executed by connected contractors are not overspent by a larger margin. Model 2 indicates that frequent interactions between a contractor and supervisor is weakly associated with higher cost overruns. Model 7 shows that projects designed by PCF1 designers, while already more likely to be overspent, are associated with significantly larger cost overruns. Projects designed by PCF2 designers, by contrast, are associated with lower actualized costs vis-à-vis the initial contract value. Table 8: Regression results on cost overruns Hypothesis H2.1 H2.2 H2.3 H2.4 H2.5 Discrepancy 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Supervision contains -0.08 design (-0.07) Repeated interactions 1.64* contractor & supervisor (1.96) Supervisor PCF1 1.78* (1.89) Supervisor & 0.89 Contractor PCF1 (0.83) Supervisor PCF2 & -5.23** contractor PCF1 (-2.52) Designer PCF1 2.83** (2.27) Designer PCF2 -3.90** (-2.15) 16 Designer & contractor 0.14 PCF1 (0.09) Supervision period 0.32*** 0.32*** 0.29*** 0.30*** 0.31*** 0.34*** 0.37*** 0.31*** (3.97) (4.08) (3.66) (3.72) (3.94) (3.27) (3.57) (3.88) Foreign supervisor 1.59 1.73 2.53* 1.79 2.15 4.32** 3.59* 1.59 (1.17) (1.31) (1.78) (1.30) (1.56) (2.22) (1.89) (1.17) Log contract value 1.27*** 1.24*** 1.22*** 1.23*** 1.30*** 0.78* 0.87** 1.26*** (3.58) (3.59) (3.55) (3.48) (3.80) (1.82) (1.99) (3.52) Arab donor 1.58 1.81 1.76 1.60 1.60 1.67 1.23 1.57 (1.36) (1.59) (1.49) (1.38) (1.40) (1.04) (0.79) (1.36) Western donor 0.52 0.70 0.73 0.68 0.25 0.23 -0.37 0.52 (0.35) (0.48) (0.49) (0.46) (0.17) (0.13) (-0.20) (0.35) Sector FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Governorate FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES - - Constant -18.97*** -19.82*** -19.93*** -14.55** -13.64** -18.91*** 20.10*** 18.69*** (-3.50) (-3.97) (-3.91) (-3.59) (-3.89) (-2.33) (-2.11) (-3.50) Observations 329 329 329 329 329 221 221 329 R2 0.28 0.29 0.29 0.28 0.30 0.34 0.33 0.28 Notes: Dependent variable is the log value of the discrepancy between initially awarded contract amount and actualized expenditures. PCF indicates dummy variables for all connected firms. PCF1 captures firms connected to the inner circle of elites that controls the CDR board. PCF2 includes firms of all political elites. Regression model uses robust standard errors; The table shows beta coefficients and t-statistics in parentheses; Significance levels: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. 5. Addressing endogeneity: Complex projects or cartels? We can think of two narratives to explain the correlation between the political connections of design consultants and our outcome variables. In the first one, consultants “implement” deals struck between elites and connected contractors. Elites would pre-allocate contracts among connected firms and lever- age their connections to designers in order to ensure that the “right” firm is winning a given tender with a margin above what a competitive market would yield. As the designer is involved in both the formu- lation of tender documents as well as evaluation of bids, designers have a range of tools at their disposal to reduce searching costs, such as by tailoring documents to specific firms, excluding allegedly non- compliant bids of competing firms, or enabling the filing of claims or variation orders due to unspecific or poor project design. Consultants would be compensated for their involvement, notably for the risks to be discovered while implementing the deal, via kickback payments, either in the form of direct cash payments or inflated supervision contracts. In the second narrative, PCF1 designers are qualified to take on more technically demanding projects. These projects would be larger than the average because of their higher technical provisions and are more likely to be overspent because of the difficulty to foresee all eventualities. In this narrative, con- sultants would ascend to better connections as they are firms with specific technical capacities that implement more demanding projects. We cannot formally address this classic endogeneity problem in our setup as this would require addi- tional data on past firm performances and extensive fieldwork with a wider set of firms. However, based on a review of CDR’s governance and additional tests, we argue that narrative two is implausible in 17 that two conditions are not met for it to hold true. First, firms should be able to compete for superior connections. And second, to the extent that connected consultants are themselves part of the rent gen- eration scheme, they should receive larger contracts irrespective of their involvement in the cartel. As per condition one, competition among firms for superior connections remained closed during the period of investigation. According to its establishment decree, the CDR board should be composed of seven to 12 members with a mandate of five years. During the period of investigation, however, the CDR board consisted of only five members which remained almost unchanged since 2004.11 Yet, quorum and voting rules for decisions on awards still apply as if the board was fully staffed. For board decisions to be binding, all five board members must attend the meeting and must agree. In line with theoretical work (Huck, Normann and Oechssler, 2004), a small number of actors with a necessity for unanimous decisions is an important precondition for elites to ensure deferred reciprocity in repeated interactions. That way, the access of firms to larger contracts is blocked by way of competing for con- nections. As neither the board nor their protégés have changed during the period investigated, firms’ performance cannot explain their ascendance to superior connections. Second, PCF1 supervisory consultants receive inflated contracts only when they serve as designers. To show this, we conduct an additional set of regressions in which we take the value of supervision con- tracts as a dependent variable.12 Models 1 to 5 of Table 9 show that only PCF1 consultants receive larger contract values than the average, even after including our set of controls for company and project characteristics. Model 6 re-estimates model 5 without multiple imputations, showing that the results are not sensitive to the imputation of missing values. In models 7 and 8, we include coefficients to test whether contract values depend on a supervisor’s service as a designer in the cartel. In model 7, we include a dummy variable for whether a supervisor has designed any project otherwise, which turns out to be positive and significant. Model 8, by contrast, includes a dummy for whether PCF1 supervisors design a project within the same contract, which is not associated with larger contract values. These results suggest that PCF1 consultants receive inflated contracts themselves as a function of their involvement in the cartel. PCF1 supervisors appear to receive larger contracts in deferred reciprocity, that is, only when they have been serving as a designer and have been part of the rent generation scheme otherwise. Even when PCF1 supervisors design the same project, they do not receive larger contracts, further hinting at a complex system of awards that is intertemporal in nature. The economic value of this increase corresponds to approximately 0.21 million U.S. dollars on the average contract, or 29 percent,13 an increase of approximately the same order of magnitude identified above. 11 In 2009, the government issued a decree with which it extended the mandate of the current board “until the appointment of a new board” (Rizk, 2019). The only changes of the board were a new president, appointed in 2006, while one board mem- ber passed away in 2011. 12 Some supervision contracts cover multiple infrastructure contracts. For these contracts, we calculate the sum of the infra- structure contract values to be included in the models as log contract value. 13 The calculation follows the same logic as outlined above, based on the effect sizes of models 1 and 7. 18 Table 9: Regression results on the value of supervision contracts 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 PCF 1 0.67*** 0.25*** 0.22** 0.23* (3.58) (2.75) (2.15) (1.94) PCF 2 -0.20 -0.13 -0.05 (-0.63) (-0.78) (-0.31) PCF 0.21** (2.22) PCF1 SV serving as 0.24** designer otherwise (2.32) PCF1 SV designing 0.01 same project (0.13) Supervision period 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.11*** 0.11*** 0.09*** (6.63) (6.61) (6.50) (6.67) (6.09) (6.95) (6.03) Supervision contains 0.47*** 0.45*** 0.44*** 0.48*** 0.45*** 0.48*** 0.43*** design (3.78) (3.74) (3.56) (3.67) (2.88) (3.70) (2.90) Log contract value 0.63*** 0.63*** 0.63*** 0.63*** 0.62*** 0.62*** 0.64*** (13.50) (13.47) (13.46) (13.59) (12.17) (13.55) (11.94) Age 0.73*** 0.62*** 0.66*** 0.64*** 0.48* 0.66*** 0.60*** (4.18) (3.36) (3.12) (3.14) (1.73) (3.50) (2.87) Size -0.09** -0.07 -0.05 -0.08 -0.05 -0.08* -0.08* (-2.05) (-1.56) (-1.08) (-1.47) (-0.89) (-1.76) (-1.74) Capital 0.05*** 0.04** 0.04** 0.04 0.05** 0.04** 0.04** (3.27) (2.26) (2.00) (1.64) (2.33) (2.13) (2.28) Foreign supervisor 0.53** 0.55** 0.44* 0.50** 0.14 0.52** 0.48** (2.10) (2.28) (1.74) (2.09) (0.30) (2.19) (2.05) Sector FE NO YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Governorate FE NO YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Year FE NO NO NO NO YES YES YES YES Constant 11.80*** -1.51* -1.04 -1.17 -1.14 -0.27 -1.19 -1.09 (85.72) (-1.79) (-1.20) (-1.19) (-1.22) (-0.23) (-1.35) (-1.10) Observations 297 275 275 275 275 205 275 190 Notes: Dependent variable is the log contract value of supervision contracts. PCF indicates dummy variables for all connected firms. PCF1 captures firms connected to the inner circle of elites that controls the CDR board. PCF2 includes firms of all political elites. Regression model uses robust standard errors; The table shows beta coefficients and t-statistics in parentheses; Significance levels: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. 6. Discussion Our results chime with narrative one and help identify the conditions under which elites can broker deals. Two channels emerge in which the conditions for rent generation are met (Figure 2). First, for overpricing, both the designer and the contractor need to be PCF1. Second, for overspending, only the designer needs to be PCF1. Disaggregating the functions of a cartel helps explain this seemingly con- tradictory result. Design consultants are the lynchpin of the cartel by performing the critical task of limiting competition and thereby minimizing searching costs. Limiting the number of designers eligible to bid appears to be the precondition for elites to ease the searching and matching of actors. With prerogatives over bidding documents and discretion over who can be excluded from bidding, connected designers ensure that bidding documents are tailored to meet a deal and that the “right” firm wins a contract. As a result, even PCF1 contractors who are powerful actors in Lebanon’s political economy and close aides to the most powerful elites of the country (Leenders, 2012) do not receive larger contracts unless the designer is also a PCF1. 19 While searching costs need to be minimized for both channels, differences arise for bargaining costs. As overpricing requires deferred reciprocity, bargaining costs are higher for overpricing than for over- spending of contracts. In the former channel, a deal has to be honored with a time-lapse of months or even years, which requires a trusted relationship among actors and therefore close connections. In the latter channel, by contrast, a deal to overspend can be honored on the spot. As all actors can be com- pensated immediately via kickback payments resulting from an approved claim or variation order, no extensive trust relationship needs to exist in order to bargain even complex deals. For the same reasons, enforcement costs are also more costly in the overpricing than for the overspend- ing channel. The long-time horizon of elites and the CDR board appears to be the necessary precondi- tion for making actors trust that other actors will eventually (be forced to) honor the deal. These costs are only low for PCF1 elites with a “seat at the table,” as PCF2 elites would have to impose much larger efforts to be able to credibly enforce a deal. Figure 2: Summary of conditions for rent generation Searching Costs Bargaining Costs Enforcement Costs Channel/ … incurred for matching part- … incurred for ensuring the …for ensuring that deal is hon- Description ner of a corrupt deal buy-in of all actors ored by all sides Overpricing Low when contracts allocated High as actors need to be com- to connected (i.e., trusted) de- pensated in deferred reciproc- High due to deferred reciproc- Contractor and signers who limit competition ity which is only possible when ity necessitating long-time ho- designer need among bidders by… contractor is also connected rizons of actors to be PCF1 ▪ Tailoring tender documents (i.e., trusted) ▪ Disqualifying non-connected bidders Overspending ▪ Facilitating “flow” of infor- mation among connected bid- Low as one-time interaction en- ders Low as one-time interaction en- Designer only ables withholding of rewards in ▪ Delivering lower quality de- ables immediate compensation needs to be case of non-compliance PCF1 signs In that way, our results advance the theoretical contribution of Bussell (2017) on the conditions under which middlemen can broker corrupt deals. She argues that “a middleman’s value is determined by the combination of access to high-quality information and relationships, acquired through repeat exposure to similar corrupt transactions, and the ability to use these resources to facilitate exchange between otherwise unlinked individuals” (p. 469). According to Bussell, it is the frequent repetition of transac- tions that create “opportunities for cultivating relationships”, requiring an “up-front investment to de- velop the trust of […] agents” (p. 468). Our results qualify this argument for high-level brokerage. Even in countries with weak bureaucracies such as Lebanon, elites, as brokers, can access high-quality information and build trusted relationships only when they have control of formal institutional functions via loyal personnel within which they enjoy a long-time horizon. 7. Conclusion Instead of reciting the results, we conclude by outlining policy implications and areas for further re- search. While we abstain from claiming generalizability, we believe our results can guide the 20 identification of “red flags” in similar contexts (Ferwerda, Deleanu and Unger, 2017) and improve cartel screening by qualifying where to search (Adam et al., 2022). The example of CDR shows that, in an otherwise well-functioning institution, corrupt deals might rarely be visible in the technical work of evaluating tenders and bids, or even to monitor the implementation of projects. Rather, they seem to be placed in the less technical pre-implementation stages in which a procurement agency retains a degree of discretion that has a higher likelihood to remain unchecked by accountability mechanisms. This dis- cretion can include measures such as short-listing of eligible (often connected) design consultants, or the determination of which bids of contractors are eligible in the first place. Future work can qualify such relationships. First, as our results highlight the complexity of the phe- nomenon of political connections, comparative studies can provide more insights on the enabling con- ditions for how they can be meaningful for rent generation. Second, we cannot ultimately exclude the possibility that connected contractors deliver higher quality work for their larger contracts. Although our results for designers being more likely to design projects that are overspent, our interviews, as well as extant literature (Baránek and Titl, 2020) strongly suggest otherwise, future work can leverage addi- tional data on the quality of project implementation to investigate this relationship. Third, future work can also elaborate on the issue of sub-contracting, which can be another opportunity for elites to dis- tribute rents. One effective way to undermine the ability of cartels to coordinate appears to be to shorten the time horizons of elites. Implementing legal requirements of rotating a sufficiently large board of an imple- menting agency such as CDR makes trust relationships more difficult to maintain and defections from cartels more likely (see also Lambsdorff, 2007). As these connections have a significant economic value, even small improvements in undermining cartel coordination can have large welfare effects. In the case of Lebanon, this is of high contemporary relevance as significant amounts of donor aid are pledged to facilitate the improvement of public infrastructure (Atallah, Dagher and Mahmalat, 2019) to recover from a severe economic crisis. References Adam, I. et al. (2022) Public procurement cartels: A systematic testing of old and new screens. GTI- WP/2022:01. Budapest. Asian Development Bank (2013) Outsourcing Public Procurement in the Public Sector. Available at: https://www.adb.org/publications/outsourcing-procurement-public-sector. Atallah, S., Dagher, G. and Mahmalat, M. (2019) ‘CEDRE Capital Investment Plan: Scrutinizing the Allocation of Projects and Funds Across Regions’, Lebanese Center for Policy Studies, 46. Baránek, B. and Titl, V. (2020) The Cost of Favoritism in Public Procurement. DPS20.07. Leuven. Available at: https://www.idnes.cz/zpravy/domaci/firma-kterou-vlastnil-ministr-rebicek-ziskala- zakazky. Berman, N. et al. (2017) ‘This mine is mine! How minerals fuel conflicts in Africa’, American Economic Review, 107(6), pp. 1564–1610. Bosio, E., Djankov, S., Glaeser, E. and Shleifer, A. (2022) ‘Public Procurement in Law and Practice’, American Economic Review, 112(4), pp.1091-1117. Bussell, J. (2017) ‘When do middlemen matter? Evidence from variation in corruption in India’, Governance, 31(3), pp. 465–480. 21 Chaaban, J. (2019) ‘I’ve got the power: Mapping connections between Lebanon’s banking sector and the ruling class’, in Diwan, I., Malik, A., and Atiyas, I. (eds) Crony Capitalism in the Middle East – Business and Politics from Liberalization to the Arab Spring. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Dávid-Barrett, E. and Fazekas, M. (2020) ‘Grand corruption and government change: an analysis of partisan favoritism in public procurement’, European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 26, pp. 411–430. Dibeh, G. (2005) The political economy of postwar reconstruction in Lebanon, Working Paper. 2005/44. Available at: http://works.bepress.com/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1000&context=ghassan_dibeh. Diwan, I. and Haidar, J. I. (2020) ‘Do Political Connections Reduce Job Creation? Evidence from Lebanon’, The Journal of Development Studies, 31, pp. 1–24. Djankov, S., Islam, A. and Saliola, F. (2016) How Large Is Public Procurement in Developing Countries?, Peterson Institute for International Economics. Available at: https://www.piie.com/blogs/realtime-economic-issues-watch/how-large-public-procurement- developing-countries (Accessed: 8 March 2021). Enders, C. K. (2010) Applied Missing Data Analysis. New York: The Guilford Press. Faccio, M. (2006) ‘Politically Connected Firms’, American Economic Review, 96(1), pp. 369–386. Fazekas, M. and Blum, J. R. (2021) ‘Improving Public Procurement Outcomes. Review of Tools and the State of the Evidence Base’, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, (9690), pp. 1–39. Fazekas, M., Sberna, S. and Vannucci, A. (2022) ‘The extra-legal governance of corruption: Tracing the organization of corruption in public procurement’, Governance, pp. 1–23. Ferwerda, J., Deleanu, I. and Unger, B. (2017) ‘Corruption in Public Procurement: Finding the Right Indicators’, European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research. European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 23, pp. 245–267. Fisman, R. (2001) ‘Estimating the Value of Political Connections’, American Economic Review, 91(4), pp. 1095–1102. Flyvbjerg, B., Skamris Holm, M. K. and Buhl, S. L. (2003) ‘How common and how large are cost overruns in transport infrastructure projects?’, Transport Reviews, 23(1), pp. 71–88. Goldman, E., Rocholl, J. and So, J. (2009) ‘Do politically connected boards affect firm value?’, The Review of Financial Studies, 22(6), pp. 2331–2360. Goldman, E., Rocholl, J. and So, J. (2013) ‘Politically Connected Boards of Directors and The Allocation of Procurement Contracts’, Review of Finance, 17, pp. 1617–1648. Hessami, Z. (2014) ‘Political corruption, public procurement, and budget composition: Theory and evidence from OECD countries’, European Journal of Political Economy, 34, pp. 372–389. Huck, S., Normann, H.-T. and Oechssler, J. (2004) ‘Two are few and four are many: number effects in experimental oligopolies’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 53(4), pp. 435–446. Hudon, P. and Garzón, C. (2016) ‘Corruption in public procurement: entrepreneurial coalition building’, Crime, Law and Social Change. Crime, Law and Social Change, 66, pp. 291–311. Jancsics, D. (2015) ‘“A friend gave me a phone number” - Brokerage in low-level corruption low- 22 level corruption’, International Journal of Law, Crime and Justice, 43, pp. 68–87. Jancsics, D. and Jávor, I. (2012) ‘Corrupt Governmental Networks’, International Public Management Journal, 15(1), pp. 62–99. Lambsdorff, J. G. (2002) ‘Making corrupt deals: Contracting in the shadow of the law’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 48(3), pp. 221–241. Lambsdorff, J. G. (2007) The institutional economics of corruption and reform: theory, evidence, and policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Leenders, R. (2012) Spoils of Truce: Corruption and State-Building in Postwar Lebanon. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Lessing, B. (2021) ‘Conceptualizing Criminal Governance’, Perspectives on Politics, 19(3), pp. 854– 873. Mahmalat, M. (2020) ‘Balancing Access to the State: How Lebanon’s System of Sectarian Governance Became too Costly to Sustain’, Lebanese Center for Policy Studies, (49). Mahmalat, M. and Atallah, S. (2019) ‘Recession without impact: why Lebanese elites delay reform’, Economic Research Forum, 8 October. Available at: https://theforum.erf.org.eg/2019/10/07/recession-without-impact-lebanese-elites-delay-reform/. Mahmalat, M., Atallah, S. and Maktabi, W. (2021) Public infrastructure procurement in post-conflict power-sharing arrangements: Evidence from Lebanon’s Council for Development and Reconstruction, International Growth Centre. F-20016-LBN-1. Available at: https://www.theigc.org/wp-content/uploads/2021/02/Mahmalat-et-al-2021-Final-Report.pdf. Mahmalat, M. and Zoughaib, S. (2021) ‘Breaking the Mold? Ministerial rotations, legislative production, and political strategies in Lebanon’, Governance, (forthcoming). Marquette, H. and Peiffer, C. (2018) ‘Grappling with the “real politics” of systemic corruption: Theoretical debates versus “real-world” functions’, Governance, 31(3), pp. 499–514. Della Porta, D. and Vannucci, A. (2012) The hidden order of corruption: An institutional approach. Surrey: Ashgate. Ravenda, D. et al. (2020) ‘The effects of mafia infiltration on public procurement performance’, European Journal of Political Economy, 64. Rijkers, B. et al. (2014) ‘Which firms create the most jobs in developing countries? Evidence from Tunisia’, Labour Economics, 31, pp. 840–102. Rijkers, B., Baghdadi, L. and Raballand, G. (2017) ‘Political Connections and Tariff Evasion - Evidence from Tunisia’, World Bank Economic Review, 31(2), pp. 459–482. Rizkallah, A. (2017) ‘The paradox of power-sharing: stability and fragility in postwar Lebanon’, Ethnic and Racial Studies. Taylor & Francis, 40(12), pp. 2058–2076. Salloukh, B. F. (2019) ‘Taif and the Lebanese State: The Political Economy of a Very Sectarian Public Sector’, Nationalism and Ethnic Politics. Routledge, 25(1), pp. 43–60. Sberna, S. (2014) Conceptualizing Organized Crime: A transaction cost approach to make-or-buy decision and corruption. Florence. 23 Schoenherr, D. (2019) ‘Political Connections and Allocative Distortions’, Journal of Finance, 74(2), pp. 543–586. Stokes, S. C. et al. (2013) Brokers, Voters, and Clientelism: The Puzzle Of Distributive Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ugur, M. and Dasgupta, N. (2011) Evidence on Economic Growth Impacts of Corruption in Low- Income Countries and Beyond. London. Available at: file:///C:/Users/franklyn/Downloads/LinkClick- final doc.pdf. World Bank (2015) Jobs or Privileges - Unleashing the Employment Potential of the Middle East and North Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank. 24